💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 3992.gmi captured on 2024-03-21 at 18:40:38. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
2012-05-22 10:04:27
Public companies have had a difficult decade, battered by scandals, tied up by
regulations and challenged by alternative corporate forms
May 19th 2012 | from the print edition
PUBLIC companies have been the locomotives of capitalism since they were
invented in the mid-19th century. They have installed themselves at the heart
of the world s largest economy, the United States. In the 1990s they looked as
if they would spread round the world, shunting aside older forms of corporate
organisation such as partnerships, and newer rivals such as state-owned
enterprises (SOEs). China s former president, Jiang Zemin, described NASDAQ as
the crown jewel of all that is great about America . Russia rejected five-year
plans in favour of stockmarket listings and Wall Street banks abandoned cosy
partnerships in favour of public equity: Goldman Sachs, the last big holdout,
went public as the decade came to an end.
Public companies triumphed because they provided three things that make for
durable success: limited liability, which encourages the public to invest,
professional management, which boosts productivity, and corporate personhood ,
which means businesses can survive the removal of a founder. In 1997 the number
of American companies reached an all-time high of 7,888 (see chart 1). Even
now, American listed companies are as profitable as than they have been for 60
years.
But during the past decade, the title of a 1989 essay, Eclipse of the Public
Corporation , by Michael Jensen of Harvard Business School, has turned out to
be prescient. In 2001-02 some of America s most prominent public companies
imploded. They included Enron, Tyco, WorldCom and Global Crossing, which,
before their demise, were admired. Six years later Lehman Brothers collapsed
and Citigroup and General Motors turned to the government for salvation.
Meanwhile, SOEs were growing in emerging markets, challenging the idea that
public companies are the biggest fishes in the sea. Private-equity firms
flourished in the West, challenging the idea that public companies are the best
managed. And the rise of the Asian economies, with their legions of
family-owned conglomerates, challenged the idea that they are best equipped to
advance capitalism s geographical frontier.
So, even though public companies are flush with cash (American firms are
sitting on $2.23 trillion, see Free Exchange) and even though the world s most
talked-about entrepreneur, Facebook s Mark Zuckerberg, is due to take his
company public on May 18th, the signs of health are misleading. Public
companies are in danger of becoming like a fading London club. Their membership
is falling. They spend their time fussing over club rules. And, as they peer
out of the window, they see the bright young things heading elsewhere.
The number of public companies has dropped dramatically in the Anglo-Saxon
world by 38% since 1997 in America and by 48% in Britain s main markets. The
number of initial public offerings (IPOs) in America dropped from an average of
311 a year in 1980-2000 to just 81 in 2011 (chart 2).
Going public no longer has the glamour it once had. Entrepreneurs have to wait
longer an average of ten years for companies backed by venture capital,
compared with four in 1985 and must jump through more hoops. Lawyers and
accountants are increasingly specialised and expensive; bankers are less
willing to take them public; qualified directors are harder to find, since even
non-execs can go to prison if they sign false accounts.
The great IPO famine
Even when their firms do go public, the most successful technology
entrepreneurs manage to preserve a lot of personal control. Google introduced a
third class of non-voting shares despite the fact that its three bosses, Eric
Schmidt, Sergey Brin and Larry Page owned 60% of voting shares. Mr Zuckerberg
put off taking Facebook public until he had little choice (you have to publish
quarterly accounts like a public company once you have more than 500 private
shareholders); he will control more than half of Facebook s voting stock.
The IPO crisis has coincided with a boom in other corporate life forms.
Familiar companies have started to put unfamiliar letters after their names:
Chrysler LLC and Sears Brands LLC. The University of Illinois s Larry Ribstein
called this the rise of the uncorporation .
Private-equity companies have taken some of the most familiar names on the high
street private, including Boots, J.Crew, Toys R Us, and Burger King. They
also bagged some of the biggest stockmarket beasts: in 2007 Blackstone bought
Hilton Hotels for $25.8 billion.
Partnerships, too, are thriving, reversing a decline that began in the era of
Charles Dickens s Dombey and Son (1848). Partnerships provided unlimited
liability to the partners but limited their number. This meant partners could
be ruined if their company failed (as Dombey was) but could not expand if it
boomed. Now, thanks to three decades of legal reforms, partnerships can offer
most of the benefits of listing, such as limited liability and tradable shares.
In America they also boast a big tax advantage: partnerships are liable for
only one lot of taxes, whereas companies must pay corporate taxes as well as
taxes on dividends.
The result has been a revolution: one-third of America s tax-reporting
businesses now classify themselves as partnerships. They have adopted exotic
forms of corporate organisation, such as Limited Liability Limited Partnerships
(LLLPs), Publicly Traded Partnerships (PTPs) and Real Estate Investment Trusts
(REITs). Private-equity firms are typically organised as private partnerships.
The individual funds through which they raise money are limited partnerships.
And they treat their managers more like partners than employees, rewarding them
accordingly. The former CEO of the Gap retail chain made $300m running J.Crew,
a clothing firm, on behalf of Texas Pacific.
Policymakers have embraced alternatives to the public company, too. Britain s
Conservative prime minister, David Cameron, is happier praising employee-owned
John Lewis than your average PLC (public limited company). American corporate
reformers regularly cite a private firm, W.L. Gore, as a model; the maker of
the eponymous Gore-Tex employs 9,500 associates and sponsors (not workers
and bosses). Such companies use shares to motivate their employees but shield
themselves from the capital markets. Employees become co-owners when they join
and may not sell their shares when they leave.
Governments have made it easier to create such alternative corporate
structures. Seven American states have passed laws to allow companies to
register as B corporations which explicitly subordinate profits to social
benefits. The British government has established a class of Community Interest
Companies which issue shares and dividends but exist to promote social
purposes. It has also handed over the management of hospitals to trusts
public-private hybrids.
The rise of new economic powers has further changed corporate organisation. In
the 1990s it seemed that emerging-market companies would take the Western
public company as their model. In fact they have embraced two slightly
different corporate forms: SOEs and family conglomerates. These companies list
on the stockmarket but do little to constrain the power of the state or of
family shareholders.
In June 2011 SOEs accounted for 80% of the value of China s market, 62% of
Russia s and 38% of Brazil s. They include some of the world s most important
concerns: the 13 largest oil companies, the biggest gas company (Gazprom), the
biggest mobile-phone company (China Mobile), the biggest ports operator (Dubai
Ports).
The most serious challenge to SOEs comes from family-controlled conglomerates.
Family businesses account for about half of listed companies in the
Asia-Pacific region and two-thirds in India. Families exercise tight control of
their empires and limit the power of other shareholders through a variety of
mechanisms such as family-controlled trusts (which have more power than
boards), appointing family members to managerial positions and attaching
different voting rights to different classes of stock. Diversified family firms
are good at taking a long-term view, diverting money from cash cows to new
industries that might take a long time to produce results. They are also good
at dealing with the government failures that plague emerging markets. It is
remarkable how fast even India s lumbering government can move if a Tata or an
Ambani calls.
Family companies of a different type have had a good decade in Europe. German
family firms have led the country s export boom by dominating niche markets
such as printing presses (Koenig & Bauer), licence plates (UTSCH) and fly
swatters (Aeroxon). These firms pride themselves on a professional approach to
management: Nicholas Bloom and John Van Reneen, of the London School of
Economics, point out that only 10% of German family firms choose their CEOs
through primogeniture compared with two-thirds of family-owned firms in Britain
and France. They also pride themselves on long-termism, investing heavily in
training and upgrading their machinery.
Getting better versus getting worse
Some of the reasons for the decline of public companies and the success of
alternatives may prove temporary. The fall in the number of listed firms owes
something to the dotcom bust, a one-off event. The private-equity boom was
fuelled by cheap debt. SOEs have been turbocharged by the rise in the price of
oil and other commodities. The next decade may not be as easy for the
emerging-world s family conglomerates as the past decade. But there is also
something more fundamental going on: these various corporate forms have all
learned how to manage their problems better than public companies have, while
continuing to exploit their advantages.
The biggest advantage of SOEs is political: ties with governments can protect
them from unwelcome competition. That, of course, is also their problem: they
can easily become bloated and lazy. So state-capitalist governments,
particularly the Chinese, have turned to overseas listings to force staid
monopolies to become nimbler, capable of responding to market demands, as well
as government fiat.
The big advantage for family firms is their capacity for long-termism. The
drawbacks are family feuds and a lack of professionalism in the second or third
generations. So, like state-capitalist governments, family companies are
turning to market mechanisms: professional managers, private-equity firms and
private markets such as SecondMarket and SharesPost, which allow private firms
to trade shares without public scrutiny.
In contrast, public companies have got worse at managing their problems, three
in particular. Mr Jensen argues that their biggest drawback is what economists
call the principal-agent problem: the split between the people who own the
company (principals) and those who run it (agents). Agents have a nasty habit
of trying to feather their own nests. Dennis Kozlowski, Tyco s former boss,
even spent company money throwing a $2.1m birthday bash for his wife that
featured a Manneken-Pis-like replica of Michelangelo s David dispensing vodka.
But, as the current shareholder spring attests, principals have been bad at
monitoring their agents.
Mr Jensen s solution was to give managers skin in the game that is, make
their pay reflect company performance so they act like owners. This has
backfired: some bosses manipulated their companies share prices to enrich
themselves and most have seen their pay outpace company performance. The total
remuneration of FTSE 100 chief executives rose by an annual average of 10% in
1999-2010, whereas returns on the FTSE 100 rose by an annual 1.9%.
The second problem is regulation. Public companies have always had to put up
with more regulation than private ones because they encourage ordinary people
to risk their capital. But the regulatory burden has become heavier, especially
after the 2007-08 financial crisis. America has introduced a raft of new rules,
from the 2002 Sarbanes-Oxley legislation on accounting to the Dodd-Frank
financial regulations of 2010. According to one calculation, Sarbanes-Oxley
increased the annual cost of complying with securities law from $1.1m per
company to roughly $2.8m. But that is nothing compared with the costs of
distraction. In 2007 Oaktree Capital Management, a hedge-fund advisory firm,
chose to raise $880m in a private placement rather than an IPO because, as the
founders put it, they were happy to sacrifice a little public market
liquidity, and even take a slightly lower valuation, in return for a less
onerous regulatory environment and the benefits of remaining private.
The third problem is growing short-termism. The capital markets have increased
their power dramatically with the rise of huge institutional investors and the
intensification of shareholder activism. Mutual funds count their money in
trillions rather than billions. Data providers such as Risk Metrics arm
shareholder activists with plenty of ammunition. And hedge funds are not afraid
to take on corporate Goliaths such as McDonald s and Time Warner if they think
they are failing. And as capital markets have flourished, corporate life has
become riskier. The average life expectancy of public companies shrank from 65
years in the 1920s to less than ten in the 1990s. So has the life expectancy of
CEOs. The average job tenure of the CEO fell from 8.1 years in 2000 to 6.3
years in 2009, according to Booz & Co, a consultancy. L o Apotheker lasted just
nine months as head of SAP and ten as head of Hewlett-Packard.
Sometimes, investors are right to kick out managers (they own the firm, after
all). Companies must strike a balance between the short and long term,
satisfying the market s demand for profits today, while planning for the
future. The worry is that regulators and owners both seem to be making it
harder for bosses to look beyond quarterly earnings. Boards are devoting less
time to strategy and more to enforcing regulations. Leo Strine, a judge with
expertise in corporate law, accuses institutional investors of gerbil-like
activity as they move money from one company to another. Standard Life
Investors complains that the noise generated by quarterly earnings has become
an unwelcome distraction from thinking about the long term.
Public company as public good
What should one make of the public company s travails? There is every reason to
celebrate the fact that businesses have more corporate forms to choose from.
Indeed, the menu should be lengthened by inventing new arrangements or
revisiting old ones. France s SCAs or Soci t s en Commandite par Actions have
two tiers of partners: general ones jointly and severally liable for a company
s debts, and limited partners who are ordinary shareholders with little power
and who can lose only what they invest. This might provide a model for
investment banks.
But there are reasons to worry that the downgrading might go too far. Can the
private-equity industry function properly if private investors cannot easily
cash out through IPOs? Can SOEs avoid stagnation if conventional multinationals
are struggling? Public companies are parts of an ecosystem of innovation and
job creation. IPOs give venture capitalists and entrepreneurs a chance to make
fortunes if they spot a game-changing idea. They also provide new companies
with capital. The Kauffman Foundation has shown that one reason America has
been better at generating jobs than Europe is its skill at creating innovative
companies such as Amazon, eBay and Google. These companies took off when they
went public.
William Draper, one of Silicon Valley s most successful investors, speaks for
many when he argues that this ecosystem may be drying up. Venture capitalists
are recouping their investment by selling new companies to established ones
rather than preparing them for independent life. In 2010 five large companies
gobbled up 134 start-ups more than the entire crop of American IPOs that year.
Two of the most talked-about start-ups of recent years Skype and Zappos chose
to sell themselves to giant firms (Microsoft and Amazon respectively). This may
not be good for the start-ups. Imagine if Microsoft or Apple had sold
themselves to IBM in the 1980s and you get a sense of the problem.
Public companies produce annual reports, hold shareholder meetings and explain
themselves to analysts. Private companies by comparison operate behind a veil
of secrecy. The danger is that regulators are creating a corporate version of
the dual labour market. By shining a spotlight on public companies, they are
encouraging businesses to take refuge in the shade of the private sector.
Public companies also foster popular capitalism. The 20th century saw
shareholding broadened thanks to privatisations in the 1980s and the rise of
mutual funds. Today shareholding is in danger of narrowing again. The reduction
in the number of IPOs is making it harder for ordinary people to put money into
a future Google. The rise of the private-equity industry and the proliferation
of private markets such as SecondMarket gives more power to a magic circle of
company founders and experienced investors.
Public companies have shown an extraordinary resilience. They have survived the
Depression, the fashion for nationalisation, and the buy-out revolution of the
1980s. But the challenge to them looks unusually strong at the moment, and the
auguries for the future grim.
from the print edition | Briefing