💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4625.gmi captured on 2023-12-28 at 19:10:54. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Robocolleague - Robots are getting more powerful. That need not be bad news for

2013-03-07 07:49:55

rlp

Mar 2nd 2013 |From the print edition

WATSON, an IBM supercomputer, spectacularly beat its human rivals in a 2011

edition of Jeopardy! , an American quiz show. It has got smarter since then.

Its components have shrunk from room-size to briefcase-size; its processing

speed has more than tripled. The sleeker, faster Watson is now being put to

commercial use: its first application is suggesting treatments in cancer

clinics. Many people fear that Watson exemplifies a trend toward the

displacement of human workers by machines.

In a 2011 e-book called Race against the Machine , Erik Brynjolfsson and

Andrew McAfee of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) worried that

human workers would fail to adapt to the quickening pace of technological

change. The Lights in the Tunnel , a 2009 book by Martin Ford, a software

entrepreneur, painted a bleaker picture still. Mr Ford noted that about 40% of

Americans work in old-fashioned occupations as nurses, book-keepers and the

like. He argued that innovation will soon allow firms to eliminate millions of

jobs, like the 3m-plus cashiers whose positions are threatened by automated

cash registers, but will create few new opportunities for displaced workers.

But plenty of research suggests that innovation need not translate into a

shrinking role for human labour. In a new paper David Autor, also of MIT,

argues that the standard production functions used by economists to describe

how things get made need sprucing up. These functions treat labour and capital

like separate elements in a recipe: mix a tablespoon of skilled work with a

dose of capital to produce a helping of GDP. In the real world, however, the

distinction is blurred.

Mr Autor describes an alternative approach in which production is modelled as a

series of tasks. A firm s challenge is to decide how to allocate them between

capital and workers of varying skills, according to their respective

comparative advantages. Assignments evolve over time as costs and technologies

shift: an innovation may displace humans from some jobs, for instance, but make

them more productive in others.

As technology improves, Mr Autor writes, a pattern emerges. Machines take over

routine tasks like repeated number-crunching or the welding of car parts. Such

jobs can be programmed into machines using detailed, specific instructions.

Displaced human workers are then reassigned to do more improvisational or

intuitive work. At airline check-in counters, say, computers are displacing

employees from mundane tasks like printing boarding passes. That makes it

easier for the humans to respond to unexpected problems like cancelled flights

or changed itineraries.

Machines serve as both a substitute for, and a complement to, labour in other

industries. Watson is initially assisting doctors to make cancer-treatment

decisions, by providing options along with the associated degrees of

confidence; it may eventually replace doctors in some diagnostic work. In other

cases, robots may raise demand for doctors services. A recent article in the

Journal of the American Medical Association notes that though robotically

assisted surgeries do not necessarily bring better results than minimally

invasive human-only surgeries, it is much easier for doctors to learn and

master robotically assisted techniques. Robot-aided surgery could therefore

make some procedures cheaper and more widely available.

Historically, technological advances have been relatively benign for workers.

Labour-market trends through the 19th and 20th centuries show surprising

continuity, according to Lawrence Katz of Harvard University and Robert Margo

of Boston University. In recent decades, for example, computerisation and

automation have displaced middle-skilled workers at the same time as

employment among high- and low-skilled workers has increased. This hollowing

out is not new, Messrs Katz and Margo note. Early industrialisation had

similar effects. Middle-skilled artisans, like trained weavers, were put out of

work by industrial textile production, but the fortunes of less-skilled factory

workers and white-collar factory managers steadily improved. Mechanisation s

insatiable appetite for routine work of all types has yet to create mass

unemployment. Quite the opposite.

The worry is that technology now has its sights set on non-routine tasks as

well as mundane ones. Yet Mr Autor notes that just because a skilled job can be

automated does not mean it will be. The number of workers used to build Nissan

vehicles varies a lot between Japan, where labour is expensive, and India,

where it is abundant and cheap. The relative cost of different types of workers

matters for firms as they choose how to deploy new technologies.

The road to HAL

The incentives facing firms may also be changing, according to Daron Acemoglu

of MIT, Gino Gancia of the Centre de Recerca en Economia Internacional in

Barcelona and Fabrizio Zilibotti of the University of Zurich. They reckon that

rich-world firms reacted to globalisation by using cheap labour abroad and

investing in technologies that helped skilled workers at home. Apple, for

example, has used skilled American engineers to design its products and

low-cost foreign workers to make them.

Rising wages in emerging markets are now making it less attractive to send

unskilled work abroad. The authors suggest this could mean a sharp change in

the influence of innovation on labour markets. Firms may find it more

attractive to invest in technologies that boost the productivity of

less-skilled domestic labour, pushing up their wages. One day, clever robots

may change this. But as long as humans retain the edge on cognitive

flexibility, firms will keep putting willing workers to good use.

Sources

"Race Against the Machine: How the digital revolution is accelerating

innovation, driving productivity, and irreversibly transforming employment and

the economy", Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee, Digital Frontier Press, 2011

"The Lights in the Tunnel: Automation, accelerating technology, and the economy

of the future", Martin Ford, 2009

"The 'Task Approach' to Labor Markets: An overview", David Autor, NBER Working

Paper 18711, January 2013

"Technical Change and the Relative Demand for Skilled Labor: The United States

in historical perspective", Lawrence Katz and Robert Margo, NBER Working Paper

18752, February 2013

"Offshoring and Directed Technical Change", Daron Acemoglu, Gino Gancia, and

Fabrizio Zilibotti, NBER Working Paper 18585, December 2012

http://Economist.com/blogs/freeexchange