💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 3157.gmi captured on 2023-12-28 at 19:51:45. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

The euro crisis - A second wave

2011-06-21 09:31:36

The bail-out strategy that rescued Europe s peripheral economies is proving

insufficient. This threatens the whole project of European integration

EUROPE S year-long attempt to grapple with the sovereign-debt crisis is

becoming more nailbiting by the day. For weeks European leaders have been

feuding over what to do about Greece, which clearly needs more help with its

precarious public finances. But a second rescue, adding even more funding to

the original bail-out in May 2010, cannot work unless the Greeks push through

more painful reforms. These are now in doubt, sending tremors through financial

markets and causing stockmarkets to fall around the world.

From the nation that coined the word drama, there was plenty of it on June

15th. As a general strike took hold across the country, there were violent

protests in central Athens, where tens of thousands of people had rallied.

After failing to form a government of national unity, George Papandreou, the

prime minister, announced that he would reshuffle his cabinet and later call a

vote of confidence in parliament. The indignation of the protesters is widely

shared. A recent poll published by Kathimerini, a newspaper, found that 87% of

the public thought the country was heading in the wrong direction.

The same could be said for Europe s approach to the sovereign-debt crisis, as

it has spread relentlessly round the southern and western periphery of the euro

area. The single-currency zone as a whole is doing well, outgrowing both

America and Britain in the first three months of this year. The euro-wide

budget deficit also compares favourably with that of other big advanced

countries. But the debt crisis is proving intractable, partly because leading

policymakers disagree about the way forward and at times seem lost themselves.

Time is short. There is a summit of European leaders next week, and Greece must

soon pass an austerity budget.

The way it all began

With hindsight, it was no surprise that the debt crisis started in Greece,

which failed to join the euro area when it was set up in 1999 because it did

not meet the economic or fiscal criteria for membership. Revisions to its

budgetary figures showed that it shouldn t have been allowed in when it did

join, in 2001. When its debt crisis flared up last year European leaders hoped

to contain it at the Greek border, providing a bail-out worth 110 billion

($158 billion) over three years, of which 80 billion came from other euro-area

members and 30 billion from the IMF.

Explore our interactive guide to Europe's troubled economies

Any hope of containment was shattered when Ireland s banking difficulties

forced a second rescue last November. After that a third bail-out became

inevitable, for Portugal, as the cost of its government borrowing shot up and

Portuguese banks were shut off from normal funding, coming to rely on the

European Central Bank (ECB), based in Frankfurt. What caused consternation was

a new shock from Greece, again that the first package was insufficient and that

the country needed more money for longer.

This sent European policymakers into a frenzy. Their attempts to find a

solution have sometimes seemed to spring from the pages of an overwrought

thriller. A secret session in early May of some of the main negotiators in

Luxembourg leaked out amid official denials that it was even happening. Shortly

afterwards the IMF, which has been playing a crucial role, lost its managing

director when Dominique Strauss-Kahn had to resign after charges were brought

against him for attempted rape in New York. Blazing rows have erupted between

Jean-Claude Trichet, the usually unflappable French president of the ECB, and

Wolfgang Sch uble, Germany s redoubtable finance minister, over German demands

to inflict some of the pain on private holders of Greek bonds and the central

bank s resistance to anything that could be construed as a default.

Europe s heads of state will decide on the second Greek rescue package when

they meet in Brussels on June 23rd and 24th. Help will be forthcoming only if

the Greek parliament endorses the extra doses of austerity the country must

swallow, together with a big programme to privatise state assets worth 50

billion (20% of GDP). Assuming that Greece does buckle down despite the

commotion of this week, as it has promised, it can expect to get an additional

85 billion in bail-out funding that will now stretch to 2014.

How much of this will have to come from taxpayers? The answer hinges on how far

private creditors who have lent to the Greek government can be made to

participate , a euphemism for picking up some of the bill. The Germans have

been pressing hard for debt maturities to be extended; the ECB has been

adamantly opposed to such a policy, although it may accept a promise by

bondholders to buy new bonds when the existing ones mature. Worries about a

possible restructuring led Standard & Poor s to downgrade Greek government debt

this week from B to CCC, making it the credit-rating agency s lowest-rated

sovereign debt in the world.

Already the prolonged irresolution of European leaders about a second Greek

bail-out has increased uncertainty for investors and businesses. If they make a

false move, the repercussions will affect not just Europeans but Americans too,

and indeed the global economy. President Barack Obama recently said that

America s growth depends on a successful resolution of the Greek crisis; an

uncontrolled default (the first in an advanced country since 1948) would be

disastrous. The risk of contagion to other countries through banking losses,

which prompted the original rescue, remains acute, not least since the markets

would immediately fret about Ireland and Portugal falling in turn. Worries

would be rekindled, too, about Spain, which has so far managed to avoid needing

a bail-out.

But a still bigger issue is at stake. Even if the European Council manages to

cobble together a compromise that buys time for Greece, the fear is that Europe

s bold experiment creating a monetary union among diverse economies without

the underpinning of a fiscal union may have been too audacious. If it founders,

this would be an extraordinary setback for the larger cause of European

integration.

Charlemagne s coin

Europe s creation of a single currency remains both futuristic and weighted

with history. At a conference about the ECB on June 10th, Volker Wieland, an

economist at Goethe University in Frankfurt, said that the euro was the first

venture on such a scale in Europe since Charlemagne created a single currency

in his empire in 794. In more recent history central banks have capped

political unions as when the Reichsbank was founded in 1876 in the aftermath of

Bismarck s unification of Germany through blood and iron .

The ECB, by contrast, is a supranational institution, although it emerged from

an old-fashioned Franco-German deal. The French wanted to fetter German power

in particular the dominance of the German central bank in European monetary

policy after its second unification, in 1990, following the fall of the Berlin

Wall. The Germans believed the ECB could be their Bundesbank writ large. Along

with these political objectives, the single currency was expected to produce

economic gains by eliminating the nuisance and cost of having to change money

within Europe, removing exchange-rate uncertainty within the euro area and

enhancing price stability. The mantra of its proponents was one market, one

money . The single currency would reinforce the single market, emerging from

reforms in the late 1980s and the early 1990s to open national economies to

Europe-wide competition.

A stand-alone monetary union without the usual fiscal and political foundations

was conceived at the momentous Maastricht summit in December 1991. The treaty

set convergence criteria, such as low enough inflation and long-term interest

rates, to check whether countries were economically fit enough to join the

single currency. These also included fiscal criteria, notably ceilings for

budget deficits of 3% of GDP and for public debt of 60%. The treaty stipulated

that there would be no bail-out of a country that got into fiscal trouble.

But the rules were less strict than they appeared. Belgium and Italy were

allowed to join the euro at the outset, even though their debt exceeded not 60%

but 100% of GDP because that debt was falling. Economic convergence at one

point in time also proved misleading. What determines whether a country can

survive, let alone thrive, in a monetary union is flexibility in both labour

and product markets, since it can no longer realign its costs by devaluing.

As for the fiscal tests, what was to stop countries from misbehaving once they

had joined? The answer, tacked on in the late 1990s to the Maastricht criteria,

was a stability and growth pact to reinforce responsible public finances

within the euro area. But this too was watered down in 2005, largely at the

insistence of France and Germany, after they themselves faced possible

sanctions for breaching the budget-deficit limit.

None of this seemed to matter during the first few years of the monetary union.

While Germany went through a weak patch, the peripheral economies (Portugal

excepted) flourished, thanks to the low interest rates that euro membership

brought them. The elimination of exchange-rate risk unleashed cross-border

lending, which built up large exposures among the banks in the lending

countries while debt piled up in the borrowing countries.

The lending was on lax terms. Credit markets paid no heed to the risks that

were building up from sustained big current-account deficits, which would have

caused alarm in emerging economies (see chart 1). They smiled on Ireland s

property boom, overlooked Portugal s slack growth and forgave Greece its poor

public finances. Spain also benefited from dirt-cheap money even though it

shared many of the same weaknesses, notably a housing-market bubble and a huge

current-account deficit.

Weakness exposed

The flood of easy money disguised the hard truth that the competitiveness of

the peripheral economies, gauged by measures like unit labour costs, had

steadily worsened after joining the euro. This deterioration came from a poor

starting-point, for Greece in particular. As one senior negotiator in the

bail-out talks laments, Greece is part of the single-currency area even though

it has managed in effect to stay out of the single market. With the lowest

exports-to-GDP ratio in the euro area, membership became a way to import cheap

goods on the never-never rather than a means to foster higher productivity.

Ireland, with exports now roughly equal to GDP, is quite different, but

Portugal also has a lowish exports-to-GDP ratio for a small economy within a

single-currency zone and, like Greece, has insulated much of its economy from

the single market.

Once the credit machine went into reverse as the financial crisis broke in the

summer of 2007, the underlying weaknesses of the peripheral economies were

exposed. The debt that had piled up in the good years became oppressive once

lenders scented trouble. Spreads on government bonds over safe German Bunds,

which had earlier narrowed to wafer-thin margins, ballooned out (see chart 2).

Ireland had what looked like impeccable public finances, with government debt

as low as 25% of GDP in 2007, but these were flattered by swollen

property-market taxes and then swamped by the costs of propping up banks that

had gone on a bender, the bill for which is now reckoned at 42% of national

output. As a result, the debt burden will reach 112% this year, according to

the European Commission s May forecast. Portugal s, too, will vault above 100%

of GDP, while Greece s will rise to almost 160% (see chart 3).

Fundamentally, then, the crisis that has engulfed three countries is rooted in

a severe loss of competitiveness combined with levels of public debt that look

unsustainable in the case of Greece and worryingly close to that for Ireland

and Portugal. The rescue packages are accordingly trying to shake up the

sclerotic economies of Greece and Portugal through sweeping changes to

liberalise markets controlled by producer interests. The priority for Ireland s

more flexible economy, which has been regaining some of its lost competitive

ground, is to finish healing its banks. All three economies are having to push

through harsh austerity measures to create primary budget surpluses (ie, before

interest payments) that will stabilise debt. As long as the three live up to

their side of the bargain, the European creditor nations, led by Germany, have

been prepared to provide bridging finance.

Voter resistance

The bail-out strategy made some sense in May 2010, since banking systems were

still weak after the convulsions of 2008, exposures to Greek debt were not well

mapped out and private creditors had had little time to adjust their positions.

But it has lost credibility over the past year as Ireland and Portugal have

also succumbed, and as markets have concluded that a bail-out will fail to put

Greek debt, in particular, on a sustainable path.

Inherently, there are two conflicting economic tensions in the rescue packages.

The first is that the austerity programmes needed to cut deficits are killing

the growth needed to make debt bearable. If Greece had got into trouble outside

the euro, the drachma would have fallen, creating an external offsetting boost

to the economy by making exports cheaper and curbing imports. The other

inherent tension is that the steps needed to improve competitiveness within the

euro require prices and wages to be held down, making it even harder to cope

with debt.

There are also conflicting political forces within both the borrowing and

lending countries. The Greeks are not alone in feeling resentful about having

to pay so high a price for past misdemeanours. Many Irish now see themselves as

victims, paying a penalty for having done a favour to other European countries

by propping up their banks and thus preventing losses by foreign bondholders

that had lent to them. If the mood turns sourer, it may be harder for the new

Irish government led by Enda Kenny to push through the further austerity that

is needed.

Lender countries are also becoming restive. The recent general election in

Finland propelled a loan-refusenik party, the True Finns, to third place in the

polls. In Germany a majority of the public thinks that the original rescue of

Greece was a mistake. On June 10th the ZDF Politbarometer showed 60% rejecting

further assistance and only 33% backing it. A poll in April showed an

overwhelming majority fearful that more countries than Greece, Ireland and

Portugal will require help.

Protest art in Syntagma Square

This stroppiness means that one solution to the debt crisis is a non-starter.

Sharing budgetary resources, either through direct transfers or through the

issue of E-bonds underwritten by the euro area s taxpayers, is anathema in

Germany, where the notion of a transfer union in which the better-off

subsidise the worse-off is political poison, not least because of the vast

transfers from western to eastern Germany since reunification. Northern

taxpayers would also recoil from the idea of a future ministry of finance of

the union which Mr Trichet recently floated.

An alternative course would be to try to make a no bail-out model work. Jordi

Gal , an economist at Pompeu Fabra University in Barcelona, would ban

collective rescues and stop trying to patrol euro-area states through debt and

deficit limits. Instead he would leave the job of policing their public

finances to investors. This would require recapitalisation of European banks so

that they could withstand sovereign defaults, but that is not the only snag.

The pass has already been sold. Investors know that when a banking crisis

looms, European governments will flinch and extend taxpayer support.

Both these courses of action at least offer clear paths forward. By contrast,

the long-term reforms set out by European leaders in March fall short of the

comprehensive solution they purported to provide. Under a pact for the euro

there will be economic and fiscal workouts that will allow countries to cope

better with the rigours of monetary union including, for example, greater wage

flexibility. They will have to put into law their determination to get a grip

on public finances. The temporary support measures will be turned into a

permanent stability mechanism with an effective lending capacity of 500

billion that will be available to countries only if their debt is deemed

sustainable. Private bondholders are served notice that they will be at risk

from mid-2013 when the new regime comes into force.

In effect the reforms formalise the bail-out strategy, but try to ensure it

will not have to be used again and leave open the possibility of restructuring.

One objection is that the pressure remains on deficit countries within the euro

area to put their houses in order, whereas none is brought to bear on surplus

countries such as Germany. But the bigger worry is that the reforms will be

overtaken by events.

The European summit on June 24th seems unlikely to get on top of things. Even

if private bondholders can be made to share in some of the pain by rolling over

their debts, this will still leave Greek public indebtedness unsustainably

high. As long as that is so, markets will continue to bet on an eventual

default. The pre-summit wrangling has only served to underline the extreme

difficulty of reaching any solution that can be sold successfully to voters.

The Greek protests have forcibly made the point that debt sustainability is

ultimately a matter of political resolve.

At best, European leaders may buy more time. But the markets have a different

timetable from the politicians, and their scepticism may continue to undermine

the weaker economies by hurting their banks. Though the ministers will

doubtless go on talking, it is increasingly hard to see a safe way out of this

crisis.

pedrolx wrote:

Dec 6th 2010 12:30 GMT

Portuguese and Spanish exposure to the big four economies and the other way

around:

ortuguese and Spanish exposure to British, French, German, and Italian banks

(in millions of US$)

exp--------Brit-------Fran-------Germ----------Ital-------Spain------ Portugal

Port______22,400_____41,904______37,240____4,734______78.288______----

Spain_____110,845____162,439____181,648____25,552_____---______23,086

and now the other way round

exp--------Port---------Spain

Brit......7,718........386,370

Germ......3,925.........39,080

France....8,209.........26,261

Italy.....3,403.........32,635

and finally public finances:

public deficit:

Ireland: 32%

Britain: 12%

Portugal: 8%

Spain: 7%

public debt:

Ireland: 110%

Britain : 80%

Portugal:80%

Spain:40%

so can anyone please tell me WHERE THE HE** IS THE CRISIS IN IBERIA???????

This is just an attack on the euro. I think the likes of the IMF (which already

have a history in supporting dictatorships in Latin AMerica) and the rating's

agencies (which keep downgrading Portugal and Spain yet keep the Irish AA

rating when their bonds are definitely junk now after the bailout) role in this

crisis should be carefully examined by impartial journalists.

Thanks, and regards