💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 5344.gmi captured on 2023-09-08 at 17:44:35. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

How to Launch Your Digital Platform

2015-03-31 04:28:10

Benjamin Edelman

From the April 2015 Issue

For online platform businesses, customer mobilization challenges loom large.

The most successful platforms connect two or more types of users buyers and

sellers on a shopping portal, travelers and hotel operators on a booking

service and a strong launch usually requires convincing early users to join

even before the platform reaches scale.

Customers find Skype worth installing only if there are people on the platform

to talk to. Who would join PayPal if there were no one to pay? Every platform

starts out empty, making these worries particularly acute. For multisided

platforms, which need not only many users, but many users of different types,

the risk is even greater. It s not enough for a ride-sharing platform to have a

large base of customers who want to book taxis by smartphone. It also needs

drivers willing to accept those bookings.

Despite these challenges, the number of online platforms has spiked in recent

years. It s not hard to see why entrepreneurs are drawn to these businesses:

They create significant value by enabling communication and commerce that might

not otherwise occur. They have modest operating costs because they don t

usually manufacture tangible goods or hold inventory. And network effects

protect their position once established; users rarely leave a vibrant platform.

I have been studying the dynamics of platform businesses for 10 years, and,

with colleagues including Peter Coles, Chris Dixon, Tom Eisenmann, and Andrei

Hagiu, I have documented and analyzed case studies on dozens of platform sites

and products. In the following pages, I draw from this research to offer a

framework to help aspiring entrepreneurs make the right strategic decisions as

they build their own platforms. The framework involves asking five basic

questions:

Can I Attract a Large Group of Users at Once?

The first question entrepreneurs should ask is whether they can quickly attract

a large group of users. Getting a mass sign-up at the outset can almost

eliminate uncertainty about a platform s prospects because it effectively

builds critical scale into the platform s network from day one. But in my

experience, a new platform can do this only if at least one of two conditions

is true:

The company already has the users it needs on another platform.

Consider Google s 2003 launch of the AdSense contextual advertising service,

the now-ubiquitous Ads by Google that appear on myriad websites. At the

start, advertisers were hesitant to buy these placements. They worried that

website publishers might click ads on their own sites (increasing the site s

revenue but depleting advertisers budgets) and that their ads might be placed

on inappropriate sites (such as those with adult content).

But advertisers had already joined Google s popular AdWords platform, providing

advertisement text and payment details in order to obtain search engine

advertising. By enrolling these advertisers in AdSense, Google set the platform

up for a successful launch. With many advertisers, Google had relevant ads to

place on most publishers sites, ensuring high revenue to publishers. Of

course, this approach raised legal questions: Could Google provide advertisers

with a new service they hadn t asked for? The company had written its contract

to retain great discretion over where ads could be shown, and to date

advertisers have not succeeded in challenging unwanted Google ad placements.

User data is publicly available.

Consider Zillow s early efforts to present profile pages for most houses in the

United States, including Zestimate prices, information about neighborhoods

and school districts, and more. Zillow was able to gather this information from

government records, circumventing the impossible task of soliciting information

from property owners for a site that was, at the start, unproven. Zillow s

initial information was good enough to attract consumer interest, at which

point property owners happily contributed corrections, photos, and other

information. Indeed, real estate agents were soon willing to pay to show their

advertisements in and around Zillow s property listings.

Zillow s approach typifies a three-step process for launching an

advertising-supported platform: (1) Collect data from public sources, and

organize it to create a useful service that attracts consumers. (2) Encourage

users to submit improved data directly to the platform. (3) Charge companies

for preferred ad placement. Even Google s widely used search engine is grounded

in this approach. Initially, the company collected page contents by scraper;

then it accepted structured data feeds from sites; and now it charges

advertisers billions of dollars to appear adjacent to search results. It s a

proven path to success one that overcomes the mobilization barriers that

initially challenge so many platforms.

Can I Offer Stand-Alone Value?

If signing up large numbers of users is not feasible, platform businesses

should look for ways of providing value to individual users even if no one else

is on the platform. Consider the VCR in the 1980s. The challenge was that

owning a VCR was useful to viewers only if they could get enough videocassettes

to watch and content owners would bother to make the tapes only if enough

people had VCRs to watch them on. The problem was exacerbated by competition

among incompatible formats.

The VCR could have been a flop, but its recording capability came to the

rescue. The device could tape television broadcasts and this benefit didn t

require that anyone else own a VCR or that any studio offer content on

videocassette. Thanks to the wide popularity of the recording function (its

legality was confirmed in a 1984 Supreme Court decision), VCRs avoided the

mobilization problems that hinder many multisided platforms.

Creating stand-alone value can present difficulties, of course, especially when

extra features require costly hardware. But it s easy to add functionality to a

software program or an app. Suppose you find that your taxi-booking app is

unpopular with passengers because few drivers accept bookings through it.

Perhaps the app can provide train and bus schedules too, or give phone numbers

for traditional taxi dispatchers. With the right additional content, the app

could attract enough passengers to make the platform appealing to drivers, who

would then pay to be included.

As you try to figure out what kind of stand-alone value to offer and which

customers you should be offering it to, consider two strategies:

Start with an industry niche.

A good approach for many platforms is to target customers in a relatively

narrow market where the platform can more readily gain traction. The Yelp

review site now evaluates almost every small business in the U.S. (and many

international businesses too), but initially it focused on a much smaller

sector: ethnic food in San Francisco. With that base, the company attracted

dedicated reviewers and interested readers. Word of mouth and participants

travel facilitated growth first to covering other cities and then to reviewing

sectors other than restaurants. As it grew, Yelp naturally expanded from

reviews to other functions, such as accepting reservations, forwarding online

orders, and offering discounts.

In a world focused on getting big fast, it s all too easy to overreach. Having

built a general-purpose review platform, Yelp could have tried publishing

reviews of all businesses everywhere from the outset. Instead, it stayed

focused on a narrow sector until it had attracted devoted fans and

higher-quality content, which paved the way for subsequent success.

Find or build small social groups.

For some platforms, success comes through identifying and serving the social

needs of small groups. Two people can use Skype and immediately enjoy its free,

high-quality calls; they get these benefits even if no one else ever joins.

Skype spread exactly this way a student calling parents, far-flung friends

staying in touch with users often joining in pairs who call only each other. Of

course, Skype becomes even better when most people have accounts.

Skype expanded naturally because users were motivated to spread the word and

encourage others to join in order to get the most out of the platform. But not

all platforms are inherently social, so businesses may need to build that

capability into the value proposition. Computer and video games, for example,

are not necessarily a social activity; historically, gamers have played alone.

Zynga reimagined online games as games with friends. In running an imaginary

farm on Zynga, a player might run out of key supplies and need to borrow from a

real-life acquaintance playing the same game. Social features like this

accelerated Zynga s spread; having friends to call on helped people perform

better, giving them an incentive to recruit more friends to the platform.

Another approach to building in sociability is discounter LivingSocial s

offering of a free restaurant meal, spa visit, or other local service if a

customer can find three friends who will buy the same thing. The approach has

helped expand the service while reducing the high marketing expenses that have

strained competitors.

These strategic choices are all largely within the control of a platform

designer. As first envisioned, a platform might require thousands of diverse

users hundreds of taxi drivers in every city, or a full suite of movies

playable on a new device. But the right adjustment can make it attractive when

used by just a few people or even by a single person.

How Will I Build Credibility with Customers?

When there are competing platforms in your space, users need some reason to

believe that your platform will be worth joining, especially if doing so

involves a significant investment, as is the case with game consoles. To

attract initial users, a new platform must satisfy those concerns by building

credible expectations for its future success.

The basic strategy for credibility building is to attract a marquee platform

contributor. Gaming console makers, for example, need to demonstrate that

highly sought-after games will be available, so they often pay a well-known

game developer to provide a given game on the console. In some cases, console

makers have bought the developer outright: Once Microsoft acquired Halo, for

example, there was no doubt that its eponymous game would be available on Xbox.

For the greatest effect, the marquee contributor s participation should be

exclusive. That s why Microsoft pays some game developers a premium to provide

their content on Xbox only. If devoted gamers want those games, they have to

buy an Xbox console.

Exclusivity with a marquee user can drive growth; however, a platform must

compensate that user for the profit it could have made by joining other

platforms. The costs can be prohibitive, giving incumbents a big advantage.

While the high costs of attracting such users may tempt platform businesses to

build their own capabilities, there are downsides to relying too much on

in-house development: Prospective users may see it as competition. For example,

starting in 1984, Apple s hardware lineup included printers. Suddenly other

printer manufacturers thought twice about making them for Macs, figuring (not

unjustifiably) that Apple was bound to give its own devices some advantages.

After weighing the modest printer profits against the risk of losing key

partners, Apple exited the printer business in 1997.

How Should I Charge Users?

Building a vibrant network has always required making choices about how to

charge users and which users to charge. But the functionality of digital

platforms offers increased flexibility in making these choices, and platform

entrepreneurs have more scope to challenge industry norms. Let s look at how

successful platforms have worked two important pricing levers:

Pay-as-you-go.

Offering pay-as-you-go pricing is a powerful way to reduce the risks of a

platform for some types of users. Groupon, for example, could have sold

advertising to restaurants on a flat-fee basis, letting them reach all Groupon

consumers in a city at one low price. Like the familiar print-advertising

model, this would have yielded simple, predictable pricing. But it would also

have created significant risks for restaurants that Groupon s consumer sign-ups

would fall short of expectations and that those who did sign up would be

uninterested in a given restaurant s offer. Instead, Groupon charged

restaurants only when a consumer bought a voucher. This approach raised other

problems but protected restaurants against the risks of low user counts and

limited interest.

As the Groupon case illustrates, pay-as-you-go pricing is a feasible option in

more and more cases because technology can easily capture and record individual

transactions automatically. It would not have been feasible to equip an early

fax machine with a counter that recorded how many pages were sent and received.

Anyone renting a device with a by-the-page fee would have had a strong

incentive to turn back the dial to reduce fees, and a tamper-proof counter

would have added to the cost of an already-expensive device. But today,

platform operators have many ways to let users try the service before

committing in full, making pay-as-you-go a viable option for most platforms.

User subsidies.

Whether it s launching a cereal brand or opening a restaurant, marketers widely

use discounts and promotions to encourage consumers to try new offerings. For

platform businesses, subsidies play an even more important role, because low

usage at the outset often means that a platform s early benefits are not great

enough to outweigh the cost or hassle of joining.

Lyft, the ride-sharing service, is a case in point. To attract drivers, Lyft

could have offered them a higher fee per minute and per mile, but they probably

would have been reluctant; with few early passengers, drivers would have

worried that even at a higher rate, zero customers still equals zero dollars.

Instead, Lyft restructured compensation to early drivers: Rather than paying

them for minutes worked and miles driven, it sometimes paid them simply to be

on call in case passengers sought rides.

At the same time, Lyft stimulated passenger interest through generous

promotions in some cities, it offered five free rides to anyone who joined

early. Notably, the two promotions reinforced each other: Having already paid

drivers to be on call, Lyft could provide free rides to promote the service at

no additional cost. Subsidizing both sides of a platform like this implies

significant expenditures, which consume a platform s capital. But once a

platform gains scale, users desire to connect to others (for example, drivers

interest in reaching riders) should reduce the need for subsidies.

Even when they have scaled up, however, platforms often continue to subsidize

one type of user in order to attract more of that type, because the platform

can then charge higher fees to other, more lucrative types. Google, for

example, provides free services including search, e-mail, and maps in order to

attract more consumers, allowing it to charge higher fees for ad placements to

another side of the market: advertisers. (For details on perpetual one-sided

subsidies, see Thomas Eisenmann, Geoffrey Parker, and Marshall Van Alstyne,

Strategies for Two-Sided Markets, HBR, October 2006.)

Can I Make My Platform Compatible with Legacy Systems?

Few platforms create entirely new networks. Typically, users migrate to a new

platform from some prior system. Building in compatibility with legacy systems

is often key to a successful launch, though it may involve marrying yourself to

outdated technology.

Consider the launch of Paytrust, the online bill-payment service, in 1998.

Paytrust sought to let customers log on to a secure site, see their bills, and

click to authorize payment, thereby avoiding the need for paper, envelopes, or

stamps. As initially envisioned, Paytrust s strategy involved recruiting major

billers to send bills and receive payments electronically. This approach would

obviously have reduced billers costs for paper and postage, but it was

unrealistic to ask, say, Comcast or Verizon to connect its systems to an

unproven start-up that at the outset had no users.

Instead, Paytrust encouraged customers to update their billing addresses so

that their bills would be sent directly to Paytrust, which scanned each bill

and posted it to the corresponding person s account. Meanwhile, with

information about a customer s bank account, Paytrust could write checks on the

customer s behalf. Thus, Paytrust made itself compatible with billers legacy

systems, so the service was useful to consumers even before billers signed up.

With a viable product to attract consumers, Paytrust s pitch to billers was

much more appealing, and billers were soon able to justify digital data

transfers that eliminated paper and scanning.

Today, platforms typically rely on interoperability, data conversions, and

information synchronization to reduce the costs of switching. For example, a

new Gmail user often has an existing e-mail account that will continue to

receive messages. Google s MailFetcher feature pulls those messages into Gmail,

thereby reducing the barrier to switching.

Compatibility doesn t have to be perfect just good enough. Consider smartphone

apps. At its launch, in 2007, Apple s category-defining iPhone had no capacity

for users to install apps from third parties. (Apple added the App Store and

third-party apps more than a year later.) The company provided selected tools

through preinstalled apps, but initially users could not add programs from

anyone else.

However, the iPhone s web browser allowed users to access web-based

applications. Although those apps, designed for use on a desktop, did not fully

exploit the iPhone s capabilities, there was enough user interest to

demonstrate an opportunity. Rapid iPhone adoption soon motivated developers to

write native apps that took advantage of the device s full capabilities.

Many platforms now offer this kind of imperfect compatibility: It attracts new

users and then gives them an incentive to switch more fully to the platform.

Users can run DOS apps on Windows, but they lose key Windows benefits (such as

shared clipboard and device drivers). Blu-ray devices can play standard-quality

DVDs, but without the improved quality that is Blu-ray s main selling point. It

s a delicate balance: Platforms must offer enough compatibility to showcase

potential benefits, yet not so much that users delay switching to reap those

benefits.

Of course, not every business welcomes compatibility. If the owners of

incumbent systems feel threatened by a new entrant, they will attempt to block

compatibility. Consider RealNetworks 2004 launch of Harmony, a digital music

subscription service and player that would compete with Apple iTunes. As an

incentive to customers who had already bought iTunes files, Real provided a

converter that let iTunes files play on Real devices. It was a clever hack and

positioned Harmony to take off. But Apple quickly changed its file formats to

block Real s converter. Facing ongoing format changes and the threat of

litigation, Real was forced to withdraw efforts at compatibility. For this and

other reasons, Harmony ultimately flopped. (Antitrust litigation that

challenges Apple s tactics as unlawfully extending its dominance from devices

to media sales is ongoing.)

Google similarly sought to block data synchronization for its AdWords platform.

From 2006 to 2013, Google banned the creation of tools to help advertisers copy

their campaigns from AdWords into competing search engines like Microsoft Bing

and Yahoo. Only when competition regulators challenged the practice (after I

flagged it in 2008 testimony) did Google lift the restriction a move that now

enables one-click copying to other ad platforms.

For numerous online services and other platforms, launch is both the most

exciting moment and the most difficult. Platforms usually provide exceptional

value to multiple types of users if the platforms are widely adopted. Yet at

the outset they are not used at all, and every prospective user reasonably

fears wasting time and resources signing up for a service that may fail to gain

traction. At first the problem may seem as insurmountable as solving the

chicken and the egg puzzle. But by using these strategies, entrepreneurs can

improve their odds of a successful launch.

Benjamin Edelman is an associate professor at Harvard Business School. He also

advises numerous companies that rely on or compete with some of the platforms

mentioned in this article, including Google.

The Platform Builder's Checklist

Amass a large user base

- Leverage exist-ing user groups

- Use publicity available data as a substitute for one user group

Offer stand-alone value

- Add a service that is useful even if few others join the platform

Recruit marquee users

- Pay them to join

- Buy the marquee brand

Reduce users' risks

- Offer pay-as-you-go pricing subsidize early users

Ensure compatibility with legacy systems

- Offer just enough compatibility to attract new users

- Anticipate resistance from legacy systems