💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 5238.gmi captured on 2023-06-16 at 18:15:50. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Economists' roundtable on the euro zone - Target the SMEs

2014-11-11 07:09:47

Nov 9th 2014, 19:40 by Sony Kapoor | Re-Define

Rounding off our discussion of what the ECB can do to save the euro zone is

Sony Kapoor, managing director of the think-tank Re-Define.

The effectiveness of long-overdue quantitative easing by the ECB will depend on

the quantity and quality of the assets purchased and on the fiscal stance in

the euro zone.

The goal of ECB QE should clearly be to increase inflation and stimulate

growth. Importantly, both of these would also improve debt sustainability. QE

works through central-bank asset purchases that boost money supply; push

investors to reallocate portfolios to riskier assets; increase asset prices and

reduce bond yields. These should help increase investment and consumption,

which the euro zone desperately needs. It should also lead to a further

depreciation of the euro that will help boost exports. Given that the Fed is

exiting QE exactly when the ECB could start firing up, the effect might be

quite significant. The euro has been falling against the dollar in

anticipation.

Given the sharp divergence across euro-zone economies, the distribution of

asset purchases across countries is especially important. To be successful QE

will need to have a disproportionately large impact in France and the

peripheral economies compared to Germany and the Netherlands.

The discussion on how much QE is needed for success must first start with the

recognition that the ECB has messed up. It has shrunk its balance sheet by 1

trillion in the past two years, even as the Fed increased its own by $ 1

trillion. This happened despite the fact that the fiscal headwinds, structural

impediments, unemployment numbers, fragility of the banking system and credit

contraction (partly because of the ECB s own asset-quality review) were worse

in the euro zone. The ECB s recent decision to try to ramp up its balance sheet

back to 2012 levels is important but nowhere near enough.

Improving competitiveness in lagging euro-zone economies without making debt

unsustainable means holding nominal wages down and letting wages rise in the

rest of the euro zone. This puts a downward pressure on inflation in crisis

economies. To ease debt dynamics and prevent a debt-deflation trap, inflation

must be kept positive, ideally close to the ECB s target of 2%. For this to

happen the average inflation in the euro zone needs to be higher, perhaps

3%-4%. Perversely, the ECB has overseen a steady decline in euro-zone average

inflation from 2.7% in 2012 to around 0.3% now. Deflation has already taken

root in some economies and inflation expectations are also falling.

To reach optimal inflation the ECB will need much more than the 1 trillion of

balance-sheet expansion currently on offer. Expanding to the same ratio of GDP

as the Fed will necessitate 2.5 trillion of asset purchases; but given the

worse state of the economy the ECB may need to go further.

Three considerations drive which assets the ECB should buy. Ideally, the asset

class ought to be liquid (ie easy-to-purchase), efficient (ie deliver the

biggest bang for the buck on inflation and the real economy) and large enough

to be macroeconomically significant. Politics dictates that the programme

should be symmetrically designed (open to all countries) but economics calls

for an asymmetric impact in crisis countries. Unfortunately, no asset class

fulfills all criteria.

Large-scale purchases of government bonds will definitely help; but the biggest

impact on the real economy will come only if the fiscal space this provides is

actually used to borrow and invest. For this the provisions of the Stability

and Growth pact will need to be relaxed.

The recently agreed purchase of asset-backed securities (ABS) provides a more

direct channel to the real economy but the market is small compared to the size

of asset purchases necessary. Ongoing covered-bond purchases by the ECB are

useful, though perhaps less efficient than ABS. They are also limited in size

and the biggest issuance comes from Germany (though Spain, France and Italy

would also benefit). The purchase of EIB securities to fund an investment

programme, as suggested by Yanis Varoufakis, is efficient but not yet on the

cards and won t be big enough on its own.

The recently launched TLTRO, whilst not strictly QE, will also help. But its

effectiveness is hampered by a banking system that, despite passing the ECB s

asset-quality review and the latest stress tests, remains fragile.

To maximise impact, the ECB should offer to buy whole portfolios of SME loans

(and possibly other kinds of loans) off bank balance sheets at just below par

and cut the interest rate on these loans substantially. Buying below par will

mean that Spanish and Italian banks will sell but German banks won t. Lower

interest rates will pass through directly to the most employment-intensive part

of the real economy in crisis countries, short-circuiting a broken banking

system. While this goes beyond conventional QE, it may be necessary in the euro

zone s bank dominated system.

While this discussion on the quality and quantity of QE is critical, perhaps

the most determinant for successful QE will actually be a looser fiscal stance.