💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4426.gmi captured on 2023-06-16 at 18:49:19. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Central banks power - The grey man s burden

2012-12-06 09:08:41

Politicians need to set clearer goals for central banks then leave them alone

Dec 1st 2012 | from the print edition

BEFORE the financial crisis, central bankers were backroom technocrats:

unelected, unexciting men in grey suits, who adjusted interest rates to keep

prices stable on the basis of widely agreed rules. There were a few stars (such

as Alan Greenspan) and a few controversies (whether to prick asset bubbles).

But most central bankers operated below the public s radar and above the

political fray. Politicians seldom questioned how they did their job, and

virtually never challenged the wisdom of their independence.

The suits are the same these days, but not much else is. Central bankers have

become the most powerful and daring players in the global economy. By providing

massive liquidity to the financial system, they saved the world from economic

collapse in 2008. They have propped up the recovery since, not least by buying

boatloads of government bonds; and they have rewritten the rules of global

banking. All this has brought rock-star status: witness the excitement over

this week s appointment of Mark Carney, the head of Canada s central bank, to

run the Bank of England (see article). But it also brings big risks. More power

for central bankers means less for politicians. Hardly surprising, then, that a

backlash is starting.

Central-bank independence is a big issue in Japan s election campaign. Shinzo

Abe, the leading opposition candidate, has attacked the Bank of Japan for

acting too timidly against deflation. He wants to force it to adopt a higher

inflation target and has flirted with the idea of making it buy more government

bonds. Some German lawmakers are furious that the European Central Bank has

promised unlimited purchases of government bonds from the euro zone s

peripheral economies. In America Republicans gripe that the Federal Reserve s

programme of quantitative easing buying Treasury bonds is a recipe for high

inflation. The squalls will get worse when central bankers start selling the

bonds on their balance-sheets or tightening lending rules to prevent a new

housing bubble. That is why central bankers autonomy needs rethinking.

Who will guard the guardians of the printing press?

Societies give unelected technocrats power over monetary policy because they

think they will do a better job than politicians with an eye on the next

election. Some countries with memories of painful inflation (notably Germany)

reached that conclusion decades ago. But in many places it is a more recent

idea. Generally, politicians set the goal (usually an inflation target).

Central bankers have wide latitude in how to achieve it, but the toolkit is

well known and has been well tested.

The sharp lines of that bargain have blurred since the financial crisis. Price

stability is now widely considered insufficient to ensure overall economic

stability. Central bankers have also been told to preserve financial stability

(ie, make sure there is not another crisis). Inflation is no longer seen by

all as the best target for monetary policy: many wonks argue that stabilising

nominal GDP growth would be better.

Setting the central banks goals is the politicians job. It is therefore

reasonable for Mr Abe to argue that the Bank of Japan should have a higher

inflation target. The decision over whether central banks should target

inflation or nominal GDP should be made by politicians, not central bankers

alone. It is not good enough for politicians to call vaguely for financial

stability : they need to give central bankers more concrete guidance, defined

in terms of avoiding asset bubbles, excessive borrowing and large

concentrations of risk.

But setting clear goals does not solve all the problems, because some of the

tools that central bankers are using are experimental. Plenty of clever people

fret that quantitative easing does more harm than good for instance (see

article).

Politicians should leave central bankers to choose their tools: it is, after

all, what the bankers are good at. So Mr Abe would be wrong to exhort the Bank

of Japan to buy specific bonds, and America s Republicans are wrong to carp at

quantitative easing when the Fed has, as instructed, kept inflation close to

its target. Politicians can intervene by changing either those goals or the

central bankers themselves (when their terms are up for renewal).

For their part, central bankers need to become more open to explain to

investors, politicians and voters the logic behind their actions and the

trade-offs between their goals. Transparency will help protect them from

political meddling.

Maintaining central-bank independence was a lot easier when monetary policy was

simpler. But that doesn t mean the effort should be abandoned. The more

important central banks become, the more important it is for politicians to

keep their noses out of the bankers business.

from the print edition | Leaders