💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4408.gmi captured on 2023-06-16 at 18:50:05. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Micro stars, macro effects - Meet the economists who are making markets work

2012-11-27 05:59:58

rlp

Nov 24th 2012 | from the print edition

ON THE face of it, economics has had a dreadful decade: it offered no

prediction of the subprime or euro crises, and only bitter arguments over how

to solve them. But alongside these failures, a small group of the world s top

microeconomists are quietly revolutionising the discipline. Working for big

technology firms such as Google, Microsoft and eBay, they are changing the way

business decisions are made and markets work.

Take, for example, the challenge of keeping costs down. An important input for

a company like Yahoo! is internet bandwidth, which is bought at group level and

distributed via an internal market. Demand for bandwidth is quite lumpy, with

peaks and troughs at different times of the day. This creates a problem:

because spikes in demand must be met, firms run with costly spare capacity much

of the time.

This was one of the first questions that Preston McAfee, a former California

Institute of Technology professor, looked at when he arrived at Yahoo! in 2007.

Mr McAfee, who now works for Google, found that uses of bandwidth fall into two

categories: urgent (displaying a web page) and delayable (backups and

archiving). He showed how a two-part tariff (high prices when demand peaks, low

ones otherwise) could shift less time-sensitive tasks to night-time, allowing

Yahoo! to use costly bandwidth more efficiently.

The solution two types of task, two prices has intuitive appeal. But economists

ideas on how to design markets can seem puzzling at first. One example is the

question of how much detail an online car auctioneer should reveal about the

condition of the vehicles on offer. Common sense would suggest some information

a car s age and mileage is essential, but that total transparency about other

things (precise details on subpar paintwork) might deter buyers, lowering the

auctioneer s commissions. Academic theory suggests otherwise: in some types of

auction more information always raises revenues.

To test the idea, Steve Tadelis of the University of California at Berkeley

(now also working for eBay) and Florian Zettelmeyer of Northwestern University

set up a trial, randomly splitting 8,000 cars into two groups. The first group

were auctioned with standard information, including age and mileage. The second

had a detailed report on the car s paintwork. The results were striking: cars

in the second group had better chances of a sale and sold for higher prices.

This effect was most pronounced for cars in poorer condition: the probability

of a sale rose by 23%, with prices up by 5%. The extra information meant that

buyers were able to spot the type of car they wanted. Competition for cars

rose, even the scruffier ones.

But more information is not always better. Studies show that shoppers

overwhelmed by choice may simply walk away. Mr Tadelis tested whether it would

be better to tailor eBay s auctions to users experience level. The options for

new users were narrowed, by removing sellers who are more difficult to assess

(for example those who had less-than-perfect feedback on things like shipping

times). When new users had a simpler list of sellers to choose from, the number

of successful auctions rose and buyers were more likely to use eBay again.

Tailoring the market meant gains for buyers, sellers and eBay.

The desire to use theory to challenge conventional thinking is one reason

economists are valuable to firms, says Susan Athey, of Stanford University and

Microsoft. When Ms Athey arrived at the software giant in 2007 it faced what

was seen as an unavoidable trade-off: online advertising was good for revenues,

but too much would deter users. If advertisers gained, users would lose. But

economic theory challenges this, showing that if firms are dealing with two

groups (advertisers and users, say), making one better off often benefits the

other too.

Ms Athey and Microsoft s computer scientists put that theory to work. One idea

was to toughen the algorithm that determines whether an ad is shown. This means

ads are displayed fewer times, so advertisers lose out in the short-term. But

in the longer run, other forces come into play. More relevant ads improve the

user experience, so user numbers rise. And better-targeted ads mean more users

click on the advert, even if it is shown less often. Empirical evidence showed

that although advertisers would respond only after some time, the eventual gain

was worth the wait. Microsoft made the change.

Microeconomists have their sights on problems outside their home turf too. At

the moment the policies picked by central banks and finance ministries are

based on old news, since things like GDP, inflation and unemployment are

measured with long lags. A team at Google headed by its chief economist, Hal

Varian, is using search-engine data to provide more timely measures. Search

terms like job , benefits and solitaire are closely correlated with

unemployment claims (see chart). These types of relationship help construct new

indexes that offer a real-time picture of the economy. If policymakers start to

use these in a systematic way, their decisions could be based on how the

economy looked yesterday, rather than months ago.

from the print edition | Finance and economics