💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 5063.gmi captured on 2023-06-14 at 15:31:32. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2023-01-29)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Cartels - Just one more fix

2014-04-01 09:43:12

Trustbusters have got better at detecting cartels and bolder in punishing them.

But incentives to fix prices remain strong

Mar 29th 2014 | NEW YORK

THE International Cartel Workshop might sound like a coaching session for

would-be price-fixers. But the biennial event, run by the International Bar

Association, is in fact an opportunity for lawyers to learn how their clients

can avoid falling foul of the law, how to respond if they do and what is on the

minds of the competition officials who attend. The latest get-together, held in

Rome in February, featured a three-day-long hypothetical in which delegates

acted out a loosely scripted scenario featuring a fictional American

camera-maker that discovers its sales team has been colluding with European and

Japanese rivals, and tries to limit the damage by reporting the sin to the

authorities.

Grey suits, wooden acting and hour-long scenes about document discovery are not

everyone s idea of gripping drama. But cartel enforcement is a hot topic in

boardrooms. Fines and jail terms have shot up in recent years, greatly raising

the costs of collusion. Big firms such as GE and Bosch have assembled teams of

in-house lawyers that focus solely on the issue.

Even for the biggest companies, ensuring compliance is hard. On March 20th

Brazil s cartel office announced a probe into 18 firms involved in the

construction of train systems, including Siemens of Germany (which alerted

authorities to the alleged conspiracy) and Alstom of France. The 15 rail

contracts being investigated had a combined value of 9.4 billion reais ($4

billion); fines could be for a similar amount. This week prosecutors charged 30

executives from a dozen of the companies.

Collusion comes in many forms: agreements to raise, freeze or even lower

prices, to co-operate in tenders, not to compete in certain markets and so on.

Price-fixing can be horizontal (among competitors in a particular product) or

vertical (involving, say, a manufacturer and its dealers).

There is agreement on right and left (a few ber-libertarians apart) that

cartels are bad. They impose higher prices on customers, reduce incentives to

innovate and raise barriers to entry. One estimate suggests that overcharging

costs consumers in poor countries around the same as those countries get in

foreign aid. It s tempting to see it as victimless because each customer is

hurt only a little, says Mark Whitacre. But it s bank robbery without the

mask and gun. He should know. In 1992 he blew the whistle on a global

conspiracy to fix the price of lysine, an animal-feed additive. His story

inspired a 2009 film, The Informant , starring Matt Damon.

Cartels have historically tended to form in industries with standardised

products that inspire little customer loyalty, such as industrial components or

road-building. Studies suggest that two-thirds of cartels are in industries in

which the top four firms have 75% or more of the relevant market. Their median

duration is five years, but some last decades.

In recent years, however, international conspiracies have been bust in fields

as diverse as seat belts, seafood, air freight, computer monitors, lifts and

even candle wax. A growing number of cases are in digital commerce, such as

e-books, and in finance, most recently interest-rate and foreign-exchange

benchmarks. The financial-market version of a smoke-filled room is the online

chat room for traders.

Some of these cartels have involved a dizzying number of alleged conspirators.

According to court filings, representatives of 20 or more airlines met in

airports, restaurants and other places to discuss the pricing of international

air-cargo services. They were caught in 2006 and forced to pay penalties of

more than $3 billion.

Cartels often form in response to tectonic shifts in the competitive landscape,

such as falling trade barriers or the advent of disruptive technologies.

Manufacturers and retailers react to such pressures by squeezing their

suppliers. Squeeze too hard, though, and those suppliers might feel forced into

an existential response , says John Connor of Purdue University.

That appears to have happened in America in car parts, the subject of the

largest criminal investigation yet pursued by the antitrust unit of the

Department of Justice (DoJ), according to Brent Snyder, who heads its

criminal-enforcement efforts. Companies used code names, met in remote

locations to fix the prices of starter motors, seat belts, radiators and more,

and followed up with each other to make sure the collusive agreements were

being adhered to, the DoJ alleges. It began raiding the companies in 2010.

Twenty-six firms, many of them Japanese, have already pleaded guilty and agreed

to $2 billion in fines. Two dozen people have been charged. There is more pain

to come: cases brought so far involve 30 parts, but trustbusters believe the

prices of 100-150 may have been manipulated. Other cartel authorities are on

the case, too. On March 19th, the European Commission fined five makers of

automotive ball bearings 953m ($1.3 billion). Five days later the commission

said it was investigating several car-parts makers suspected of fixing prices

for exhaust systems.

The scale of the car-parts case owes something to the structure of the

industry. By approving just a few suppliers of each part, which erected

barriers to entry and encouraged supplier concentration, the direct victims,

carmakers, may have created fertile conditions for cartel activity. Some may

have been ripped off by firms they part-owned. Toyota owns 22% of Denso, which

allegedly swapped information with rivals on requests for quotation made by

Toyota for heater panels.

Only in the past quarter-century has price-fixing been treated as worse than a

misdemeanour. Before then, most companies saw it as like going 5mph over the

speed limit, says Roxann Henry of Morrison & Foerster, a law firm. Collusion

has been illegal in America since passage of the Sherman Act in 1890. But the

nation s enforcers started to get tough only when the brazenness of the lysine

conspiracy became apparent in the 1990s (members were recorded joking with each

other about the FBI infiltrating their meetings).

Since then, policing and penalties have grown harsher. The maximum corporate

fine in America has increased tenfold. The European Commission can fine

companies up to 10% of group turnover. Fines levied on both sides of the

Atlantic have jumped over the past decade (see chart). Europe s national cartel

offices are busier, too. This year Germany s has fined brewers 106m and sugar

distributors 280m.

America leads in putting price-fixers behind bars. The average jail term has

risen, from eight months in the 1990s to more than two years. The DoJ uses

Interpol red notices (arrest warrants) to put pressure on foreigners indicted

in cartel cases to submit to American jurisdiction. The European Commission can

only bring civil cases, but criminal penalties can be imposed in Ireland and

Britain, where they are being strengthened. Authorities in large emerging

markets are also getting tougher. In India, the worst that colluding firms

needed to fear before 2009 was a cease-and-desist order. Now they face heavy

fines.

A cartel-busting cartel

With a growing share of cartels being global in scope, competition authorities

are doing more of what those they police are not supposed to do: sharing

information and working in tandem. The Japanese Fair Trade Commission played an

important role in the American-led investigation into car parts. In the biggest

cases, offenders can be hit with suits in a dozen countries.

Japan s tougher stance matters because its companies have long had a lax

attitude to collusion. A lawyer tells of a meeting last year with an executive

at a Japanese manufacturer who claimed that collusion was a thing of the past;

the lawyer s next meeting at the firm was with a middle manager who said he had

been taken to meet several competitors soon after being hired. Asian firms

often treat employees convicted of price-fixing as a soldier who took a bullet

for the company , says Robert Lande of the University of Baltimore s law school

though this is not solely an eastern habit. When Mr Lande looked to see what

had become of dozens of price-fixers from various countries who had been jailed

between 1995 and 2010, he found that roughly half had been rehired by their old

employer or by another firm in the same industry.

Cartels are difficult to root out without help from insiders. To aid detection,

the DoJ developed a leniency programme that provides incentives for companies

to confess and snitch on rivals. This has become so successful that around 50

other countries have copied it. Most big cases today stem from such

confessions.

Under the American programme, the firm that spills the beans can avoid fines,

and its employees are spared prison. The second and third through the door can

secure lesser benefits, though no criminal immunity, if they provide useful

information. Under a policy known as amnesty plus , a co-operating firm that

exposes a separate conspiracy can secure partial immunity in that

investigation, too. Samsung, for instance, was the source for several probes

into computer monitors and television tubes. Leniency schemes are designed to

be trees that grow more and more branches as edgy companies, fearful that

rivals will squeal first, reveal hidden sins, says Ms Henry.

The flip side of leniency is that authorities take a particularly hard line

against firms that, when admitting to one conspiracy, do not confess to

participation in others. In 2011 Bridgestone paid a fine for colluding over

marine-hose prices. Because it failed to disclose that it was up to the same

tricks in car parts, it had to pay an elevated fine of $425m for the second

transgression.

Some countries are employing eggheads to search for suspicious price patterns

by screening markets. These statistical tests have proved most effective in

markets with lots of data, such as financial benchmarks and derivatives, though

they have also been useful in cement and fishing: they provided the first

evidence of manipulation of the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) in 2008

and, last year, of foreign-exchange rates.

Not everyone is convinced by screening. The DoJ ditched it after concluding

that it produced too many false positives. Grand-jury subpoenas can rock

companies, says Scott Hammond, a former DoJ cartel-enforcement chief, now with

Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher, another law firm. It is a mistake to unleash them

based on tests that have falsely pointed to wrongdoing.

Rosa Abrantes-Metz of New York University s Stern School of Business, whose

number-crunching helped expose the LIBOR affair, thinks the Americans are too

sceptical. She argues that market screening, like the medical sort, is useful

as an indicator that prompts further investigation.

Price-fixers also have to worry about the growth of civil litigation, which

almost always follows action by competition authorities, and in which

cartelists can face treble damages. Private suits in America generated awards

and settlements of $33 billion four times the level of official fines between

1990 and 2008.

Most suits are class actions brought by consumers or corporate customers, but

large companies are increasingly opting out of these to bring their own cases,

as Ford has done in car parts. In all, 28 car-parts suits have been filed in

American courts. Adding to the pain, state attorneys-general have become more

forceful in asserting claims on behalf of government purchasers and state

residents.

Class actions are less common but on the rise in Europe, with Britain, Germany

and the Netherlands leading the way. In some countries impediments remain, for

example rules that hamper document discovery. To remove these the European

Commission has proposed a directive that would harmonise laws and procedures.

The wages of sin

Despite more-severe punishments, cartels still form all the time. Messrs Connor

and Lande think they know why. In a joint paper, Cartels as Rational Business

Strategy: Crime Pays , they argue that deterrence is still too weak. They

studied 75 cartels and concluded that these could typically raise prices by

20%. That is double the estimate used by America s Sentencing Commission when

setting guidelines for fines and jail terms. Factor in the small chance of

being detected, which the authors put at one in five, and American cartel

sanctions are only 9-21% as large as they need to be to offer optimal

deterrence. A lawyer at the Rome conference recounted a recent meeting with an

executive from a large cement group: He said it s hard to stop fixing prices

when it s still so worthwhile.

The authors suggest increasing not only sanctions but also the chances of

detection by increasing enforcement budgets, which are tiny compared with the

fines levied: in 2012 the DoJ s antitrust arm took in 16 times more than it

cost to run. Presumably, the DoJ s Mr Snyder would not turn down an increased

appropriation, but he is less keen on quintupling penalties, which he fears

would bankrupt companies and thus crimp competition. We want [cartelists] to

feel adequate pain but we also want them to remain viable. We re not in the

business of reducing competition.

Despite evidence that penalties are still too small, defence lawyers complain

that the authorities cause alleged cartelists unnecessary pain by applying

antitrust laws extraterritorially. Each jurisdiction is meant to base its

penalties on the amount of business affected in its territory. But when

commerce crosses borders there is sometimes double-counting (known in the trade

as the bump ). Jurisdictions often co-ordinate their actions but they do not

have to take account of each other s fines, and do not always agree.

Some firms have fought back. After AU Optronics of Taiwan was indicted and

fined $500m by America for collusion in LCD panels, the company and two

executives challenged their convictions, arguing that much of the alleged

activity took place elsewhere. Last December a court ordered the executives to

be released, pending appeal, suggesting that the panel of judges had doubts

about the government s case. However, the state is usually hard to beat once a

case goes to trial: in 2003-12 it won 657 of the civil and criminal antitrust

cases it brought before American courts; just 28 were lost or dismissed.

The outcome of private actions is more even. Many cases are dismissed for lack

of evidence. Take the suit brought by grocers against America s three big

chocolate-makers, Hershey, Mars and Nestl , alleging co-ordinated price

increases in 2002-07. A judge recently sided with the defendants, stating that

their pricing decisions, while largely identical and effectively simultaneous,

were nonetheless timed and orchestrated in such a way to achieve whatever

momentary pricing advantage they could over their competitors.

Trials expose grey areas in cartel law.Emails that reveal overt price-fixing

make for a cut-and-dried case. But is it a conspiracy if a firm announces a

price increase and soon afterwards rivals raise their prices to the same level?

Has technology that allows rapid-fire price changes, such as the algorithms

used in online travel, blurred the meaning of agreement and made it difficult

to distinguish announcements from discussions among rivals?

One problem is that competitive and collusive markets can look very similar. If

firms are pricing at marginal cost, and costs (of commodity inputs, for

instance) are bouncing around, then prices shift together in a perfectly

competitive industry, just as they might in a cartel. Competition authorities

try to get around this problem by looking not only at pricing but at

profitability too; profits in collusive environments are higher than those in

competitive ones.

Trustbusters have worked hard to spell out where they consider the line between

right and wrong to be, says Brady Dugan of Squire Sanders, another law firm.

But their thinking is not uniform. The European Commission, for instance, often

treats an exchange of information as collusion, even if there is no agreement

to fix prices. The DoJ needs to see an agreement, though this does not have to

be in writing.

These ambiguities mean it can be difficult for firms accused of collusion to

decide whether to settle or fight. For cartelists that have not yet been

accused, the decision over whether to confess or sit tight can be a tough one,

too. Confession is usually the best option if the company is sure it is the

first in the cartel to step forward and it senses a growing risk of detection.

But for a firm that suspects others have already confessed, thus securing all

the available immunity slots or penalty discounts, it might make sense to keep

quiet, then litigate rather than capitulate when accused particularly in

jurisdictions where trustbusters wield civil penalties only.

The European Commission, for instance, has sometimes struggled to make its

case, especially when much of the conduct took place on other continents. Of

the 25 airlines it initially went after for fixing air-freight prices, 13 that

offered little or no co-operation avoided fines. Competition authorities want

all our clients to believe that coming clean is always the best option, says

an antitrust lawyer who represents large European companies. But from the

board s perspective that s sometimes simply irrational.