šŸ’¾ Archived View for library.inu.red ā€ŗ document ā€ŗ subversion-review-anarchist-economics captured on 2023-04-26 at 15:37:16. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

ā¬…ļø Previous capture (2023-03-20)

āž”ļø Next capture (2023-07-10)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Review: Anarchist Economics
Subtitle: Anarchist Economics: An Alternative for a World in Crisis ā€” The Economics of the Spanish Libertarian Collectives 1936ā€“39 by Abraham Guillen (distributed by AK Press)
Date: 2002
Source: Retrieved on March 24, 2016 from [[https://web.archive.org/web/20160324224507/http://nefac.net/node/178][web.archive.org]]
Notes: Reviewed by<em></em> Subversion. Published in <em>The Northeastern Anarchist</em> Issue #4, Spring/Summer 2002.
Authors: Subversion
Topics: Spanish Revolution, economics, book review, Northeastern Anarchist, Anarcho-Collectivism, AK Press
Published: 2021-10-16 18:00:48Z

This pamphlet adds another volume to the bulging library of anarchist publications which regard the setting up of the workersā€™ and peasantsā€™ collectives at the start of the Spanish civil war in 1936 as ā€œone of the most, if not the most, extensive and profound revolutions ever seenā€.

Abraham Guillenā€™s argument is that the Spanish collectives can serve as the model for a revolutionary alternative to both Western-style capitalism and Eastern-bloc ā€˜communismā€™. But Guillen picks out from the Spanish events some of the most negative features of that experience, so that in the end his ā€œalternative for a world in crisisā€ amounts to nothing more than a variation on the same lousy old capitalist theme.

Basically, Guillen promotes a vision of relatively autonomous and self-sufficient communes joined together by market relations (i.e. buying/selling or barter).

On the distribution of goods within each collective he mentions that some of the Spanish collectives ā€œfreely distributed among the collectivist landworkers that which was abundant but rationed that which was scarceā€.

This seems to us a reasonable way of tackling the problem of material scarcity which may very well temporarily confront us when capitalism is being overthrown, so long as any rationing system is based on the principle, ā€˜to each according to their needsā€™.

Guillen however proposes that each personā€™s consumption would be regulated ā€œin accordance with quality and quantity of work doneā€, with ā€œproduction cardsā€, on which ā€œthe value of work done by days is recordedā€, being used as a kind of ā€œcredit cardā€ or form of money.

The adoption of this principle, ā€˜to each according to their workā€™, would amount to the re-introduction (or rather continuation) of the wage system. And indeed to the extent that similar schemes were actually put into operation in Spain (there were numerous variations on the production card theme and hundreds of different local currencies) the overall thrust of the collectivization movement was towards the retention of essentially capitalist relations rather than in the direction of socialism/communism.

This can be seen even more clearly in the relations between collectives. As very few collectives were self-sufficient, central warehouses were set up where collectives exchanged their surplus produce among themselves for the goods they lacked. Here hard cash was often dispensed with, but the relative proportions in which the goods were bartered with were still determined by monetary values ā€” for example how many sacks of flour a collective could obtain in exchange for a ton of potatoes was worked out by calculating the value of both in monetary terms ā€” and no collective was allowed to withdraw a sum of goods worth more than those it had deposited.

Guillen wholeheartedly supports this system, describing approvingly how ā€œif local products could not satisfy the consumer, the collective, through its council or appropriate section, obtained, on an equal exchange basis, the goods and services neededā€, and how ā€œa self-managed system was thus formed, where goods, products and services were exchanged according to their real work-value relationshipā€.

He fails to comprehend how rapidly this system of relations among the collectives would lead to the main purpose of production becoming (or remaining) for exchange via the market rather than to directly meet peopleā€™s needs. And, once again, insofar as this is what did actually happen in Spain, the collectivization movementā€™s development was driven basically by capitalist dynamics.

Had the Spanish collectives been moving in a genuinely communist direction the tendency towards self-sufficiency and autonomy for each collective (which Guillen elevates to the level of a ā€œbiological principleā€) would have been reversed in favor of centralized planning by delegate bodies. The wealth produced by each collective would not be regarded as its own private property. Instead, in relations among the collectives the same attitude would prevail as existed within each collective: ā€œThe concept ā€˜yours and mineā€™ will no longer exist...Everything will belong to everyone.ā€ The role of the central planning bodies would essentially be simple technical ones, such as finding out what goods were needed where and arranging their transportation from one place to another.

In Guillenā€™s model there is central co-ordination but it is co-ordination of exchange relationships. Throughout the pamphlet great stress is laid on forms of organization ā€” direct democracy, federation, self-management, and so on ā€” but the content of these organizational forms remains in essence a market economy.

To sum up, the ā€œanarchist economicsā€ Guillen supports is simply the dead-end of self-managed capitalism, which is every bit as reactionary as private or state capitalism. The communist society we are fighting for can only be established by the complete destruction of ALL private property, money, wages and markets ā€” whatever their form.

Home