💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › the-first-work-of-the-revolution.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 14:17:13. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: The First Work of the Revolution
Date: August, 1887
Language: en
Source: Freedom: A Journal of Anarchist Socialism, Vol. 1, No. 11, online source http://www.revoltlib.com/?id=2992, retrieved on April 12, 2020.

The First Work of the Revolution

Whatever turn, pacific or warlike, events may take when the time has

come for a thorough modification of present conditions, those who will

take an active part in the movement will find two different courses open

to them; and upon their choice will depend the success or the failure of

the attempt.

Deeply imbued with the teachings of Political Economy, which has devoted

its chief attention to the best means of increasing the intensity of the

present capitalist production; accustomed to reason under the open or

unspoken presumption that the economical life of a Society cannot but be

organized on some kind of wage-system, –most social reformers have built

up their schemes of reform on the supposition that our endeavors must be

merely directed towards some improvement of the present system of

wage-payment, and it is usually supposed that this improvement would

result from the State, or the Municipality, taking industry under their

management, and eliminating the present owners of land and capital.

In the opinion of these persons the Social Revolution, after having

proclaimed the rights of the nation to its soil, mines, machinery, and

means of communication, and after having expropriated the present owners

of these necessities of production, ought to organize industry so as to

guarantee to the worker " the full value of his labor," and thus to

prevent anybody from pocketing for himself the surplus-value. added by

the laborer to the cotton and wool which he transforms into stuffs, to

the coal which he brings to the surface of the earth, or to the metals

he transforms into tools or machines. But, as far as we understand the

social reformers belonging to this school, they consider it quite

possible provisionally to maintain existing industry as it is, both as

to the kinds of produce it brings to market, and the territorial

distribution of the various workshops and manufactures. As to how the

very first needs of the producer–those of food, of shelter, of clothing,

and so on-should be satisfied, we must recognize that these grave

questions are rather driven into the back-ground in the schemes of all

social reformers of the Collectivist and previous schools.

Well, it seems to us Communist-Anarchists, that if the Social Revolution

should really follow this course, it would be doomed beforehand to be

defeated, and to be crushed in the blood of the working classes.

We have already said that the, abolition of private ownership of land,

mines, machinery, and productive capital altogether, surely will be the

distinctive feature of any movement worthy of the name of Socialist; and

we have said, moreover, that no Parliament, no Government can do this.

The expropriation can be carried out only by local initiative, by local

action, by being not only written on paper, but accomplished de facto.

But suppose it is done; that is, suppose the nation has loudly

proclaimed that the soil, the houses thereupon and the mines beneath,

the factories and railways, are the property of the nation, and suppose

that even the idea is so ripe that no serious objections are raised

against it –what next?

It is not enough to proclaim, "These factories are ours," and to put on

them the inscription, "National Property." They will become ours when we

really bring them into action, when we use them and set their machinery

at work. But how will that be done?

We are answered, "The State will do that, and it will pay wages, either

in money or in 'labor notes.' But it seems to us that those who answer

the question in this way, are merely paying a tribute to the false and

portentious pseudo-science which middle-class people have elaborated

under the name of Political Economy. Their point of view is altogether

wrong; because, instead of basing our reasonings on the present

production we ought to base them on consumption. Production is, for us,

the mere servant of consumption; it must mold itself on the wants of the

consumer, not dictate to him conditions.

Suppose we have entered a revolutionary period, with or without civil

war–it does not matter,–a period when old institutions are falling into

ruins and new ones are growing in their place. The movement may be

limited to one State, or spread over the world,–it will have

nevertheless the same consequence: an immediate slackening of individual

enterprise all over Europe. Capital will conceal itself, and hundreds of

capitalists will prefer to abandon their undertakings and go to

watering-places rather than to risk their unfixed capital in industrial

production. And we know how a restriction of production in any one

branch of industry affects many others, and these in their turn spread

wider and wider the area of depression.

Already, at this moment, millions of those who have created all riches

suffer from want of what must be considered as necessaries for the life

of a civilized man. Already hundreds of thousands are in want of even

food and shelter. Let the slightest commotion be felt in the industrial

world, and it will take the shape of a general stoppage of work. Let the

first attempt at expropriation be made, and the capitalist production of

our days will at once come to a stop, and millions and millions of

"unemployed" will join the ranks of those who are already unemployed

now.

More than that. Our production cannot continue to go on as it does. The

very first advance towards a Socialist society will imply a thorough

reorganization of industry as to what we have to produce. Socialism

implies, not only a reorganization as to the division of profits: its

economical meaning is much deeper. It implies also a transformation of

industry so that it may be adapted to the needs of the consumer, not to

those of the profit-maker. Many a branch of our present industry must

disappear, or limit its production; many a new one must develop. We are

now producing to a great extent for export. But the export trade will be

the first to be reduced as soon as attempts at Social Revolution are

made anywhere in Europe. The British weaver, for instance, does not

stand in direct exchange with the Hindu - there is between them a series

of middle-men both in this country and in India, and in a time of

industrial disturbance such middle-men would cease their orders. The

industry of this country being calculated for an immense export trade,

must undergo a deep modification to adjust it to the needs of the

inhabitants of these isles.

All that can be, and will be reorganized in time-not by the State, of

course (why, then, not say by Providence?), but by the workers

themselves. But, in the meantime, the worker, who has not even so much

wealth as will enable him to live for a fortnight, cannot wait for the

gradual reorganization of industry. Having no employment, he would

meanwhile lose even those wages which formerly permitted him to keep

body and soul together.

The great problem of how to supply the wants of the millions will thus

start up at once in all its immensity. And the necessity of finding an

immediate solution for it is the reason why we consider that a step in

the direction of communism will be imposed on the revolted society–not

in the future, but as soon as it applies its crowbar to the first stones

of the capitalist edifice.

It is because none of the three revolutions through which France has

passed during the last hundred years grasped this necessity that each of

them was crushed in the blood of its best defenders. By forgetting that

the workmen who can earn no wages during a revolutionary period, cannot

continue to be defenders of the revolution, the leaders of those

enterprises reduced the working classes to the most terrible raisery,

and finally compelled them to accept any dictator, any Emperor who

guaranteed them work and wages, whatever were the conditions of work and

however low the rate of wages.

Therefore we differ from all other Socialist schools in the manner in

which we look at the next social movements. We hold that the

satisfaction of the wants of all must be the first consideration of the

revolutionists; that in the very first twenty-four hours after a

Socialist movement has broken out in a city, there must not be one

single family in want of food; not one single man or woman reduced to

sleep under a bridge or in the meadows. Our first object must be to care

for providing this food and this shelter for those who are most in need

of them, for those precisely who have been the outcasts of the old

society.

Is it possible? Are we able immediately to provide everybody with food,

shelter, and clothes? None of those who know the richness of our modern

society will doubt the possibility. We have plenty; and we have plenty

of food in our stores to satisfy their first wants.

And if we thus consider the satisfaction of everybody's first wants as

the first duty of each social movement, we shall soon find out the best

means of reorganizing our production so as to supply everybody with, at

least, the first necessaries of life.

We shall return again and again to this subject in subsequent numbers of

Freedom; but the preliminary point upon which we wish especially to

insist is, that unless Socialists are prepared openly and avowedly to

profess that the satisfaction of the needs of each individual must lie

their very first aim; unless they have prepared public opinion to

establish itself firmly at this standpoint, the people in their next

attempt to free themselves will once more suffer a defeat.