💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › kevin-carson-castro-agonistes.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:44:08. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Castro Agonistes
Author: Kevin Carson
Date: April 20, 2006
Language: en
Topics: Cuba, US foreign interventions, state socialism
Source: Retrieved on 4th September 2021 from https://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/04/castro-agonistes.html

Kevin Carson

Castro Agonistes

Larry Gambone recently wrote on Any Time Now Discussion:

...Latin Americans are well aware that Castro-the-dictator is as much a

US production as a self-creation. US policy has always been what they

can’t overthrow from outside, they destroy from inside by driving a

progressive government in as authoritarian direction as possible.

I’ve long taken a favorable view of Hannah Arendt’s observation, in On

Revolution, that virtually every revolution has significant

decentralizing elements: attempts at worker self-management, local

organs of direct democracy, etc. A classic example is the soviets and

the workers committees in Russia, before Lenin either liquidated or

coopted them. And outside pressure on a revolutionary regime and foreign

support for counter-revolutionary forces (e.g., the Western states’

support for the White armies in Russia) tends to strengthen the forces

of consolidation and centralization, and to accelerate the suppression

of decentralist tendencies.

I recall Chomsky arguing somewhere that the NLF, despite definite

authoritarian aspects, at least was also engaged in grass-roots

activities of genuine benefit at the village level like building

irrigation systems, organizing peasant cooperatives, and the like. It

had more genuine attachments to the peasants of the South than did the

ruling party in Hanoi, at any rate. The main effect of the U.S. war

effort in the South was to atomize civil society in the countryside,

along with successfully decimating the NLF. The result was a

hollowed-out shell, the almost total supplanting of the guerrillas by

the NVA, and the filling of the void by the North Vietnamese state when

Saigon collapsed.

In the specific case of Cuba, I’m not sure how much of

Castro-the-dictator was just in there waiting for an opportunity to come

out, but the pressures of the Cold War--the U.S. economic embargo,

combined with increasing alignment with the USSR--certainly helped to

bring his authoritarianism out. Via Fruits of Our Labour, I found an

interesting account of the early post-revolutionary period in Cuba, a

chapter in Cuba, Castro and Socialism, by Peter Binns and Mike Gonzalez.

It appears that cooperative and “petty bourgeois” elements were heavily

represented, if not predominant, in Castro’s early economic policies.

The Cuban Communist Party, before the revolution, had had a checkered

history of on-again, off-again collaboration with Batista. The Communist

Party certainly had little use for the 26 July movement before it came

to power. Castro, on the other hand, came from a background of

nationalist opposition centered on what Binn and Gonzales call “petit

bourgeois” elements and a “fundamentally non-working class tradition”:

the “urban middle class” and “middle farmers, small peasants and

university students,” supplemented by “the semi-incorporation of the

organised working class.”

Indeed, if I recall correctly, Castro actually liquidated the CCP for

unacceptable competition with his own revolutionary movement after

coming to power. When he declared himself a “Marxist-Leninist” in the

early 1960s, he incorporated the remnants of the old CCP into his own

revolutionary party.

Binns and Gonzalez, with typical Marxist blinders, see Castro’s

increasingly statist economic policy as a response to “objective

conditions.” The land reforms and other curtailments of exploitation

left the laboring classes with more disposable income and greater demand

for consumer goods, which (non sequitur alert) could only be met by

nationalizing the economy:

So why then did Castro move towards the creation of a monolithic

statised economy? The major reason must be found in his long standing

commitment to diversify the economy, to end its dependency on the US and

the vagaries of the world sugar market, and to all-round economic

development. The question that came to be posed in the summer of 1959

was this: how were the reforms of the first part of the year to be paid

for? The rapid increase in wages, the fall in unemployment, the drastic

reduction in rents (up to 50%), the cheapening of electricity, telephone

and medicine charges; all put much more money into the workers’ pockets.

This automatically increased the demand for consumption goods – all of

which had to be imported – and food. The latter automatically put

pressure on the land available for sugar; and since this provided Cuba

with more than 80% of the exports from which the imports had to be paid,

this situation could not be allowed to persist indefinitely. Only

industrialisation and diversification could solve the problem. The

fantastic variability in the price of sugar, and Cuba’s almost total

dependency on it as a source of foreign earnings, meant that the level

of demand in the domestic economy was much too unpredictable for most

capitalists to want to take the risk of relying on it as a source of

income. And, without that, no advantage attached to investing productive

capital in Cuba. With a very small and highly unpredictable home market,

and with just about the highest wage levels in Latin America, there was

not the least chance of the situation changing if the bourgeoisie was

simply left to its own devices.

The matter was made more acute by land reform. Again this was a long

standing commitment of Castro’s from the mid-1950s: antipathy to the

latifundistas, the huge landowners, was the cornerstone of Castro’s

radical liberal programme. The May 1959 Land Reform Act has to be seen

in this light. It was in no way a socialist measure, nor one which led

to collectivisation in any other form. It abolished only the very

largest estates (those of more than 402 hectares; though even here there

were exceptions which allowed much bigger farms – up to 1,342 hectares –

that were efficient to continue), and it did not solve the problem of

the indebtedness of the small peasant. Indeed one prominent agronomist

sharply contrasted the 1959 reform with those in East Europe in the

early 1950s; and suggested strong parallels with those in Italy in

1949–50 instead. Yet for all that, something like 25% of the cultivable

land was covered by the Act, and was distributed to the poorer peasants.

The effect was to increase the proportion of land that was devoted to

immediate consumption rather than providing the country with an

exportable surplus, and this added considerably to Cuba’s problems.

Although it was also true that much of the land previously owned by the

latifundistas was poorly tended, the fact remained that to increase

productivity significantly would have required levels of investment and

skilled personnel that were just not available at the time.

The initial reforms were thus in no way reminiscent of the

state-capitalist “collectivisations” of Eastern Europe in the 1950s, nor

Cuba’s own 1963 reform; but what they did do was to create a situation

that only a state-capitalist programme could solve.

I’m not sure why this is. If the standard of living had increased so

much (rents cut in half, the highest wages in Latin America), why was it

so self-evidently beyond the producing classes to pool their own surplus

for investment? Why could peasants not have cooperatively invested in

labor-saving technology to increase their own productivity, and free up

labor for other forms of production? In any case, if the increased

prosperity of Cuban society created more purchasing power, and the

increased demand for consumer goods could be met by importation, why was

that a “problem” to be addressed through the state? Domestic industry

would expand at the point when native producers could supply consumer

goods more cheaply than the foreign manufacturers. And if anything, the

removal of hindrances on cooperative marketing would have made the sugar

industry less dependent on the vagaries of world commodity markets. In

the meantime, the domestic agricultural sector would have been

increasingly diversified with staple crops for domestic consumption, and

the peasantry would have been capable at least of feeding itself on its

own land, with a little surplus for buying a few luxuries from abroad: a

marked improvement over the Batista dictatorship, I’d say.

I’m guessing a lot of this stems from the affinity for blockbuster

industrialization projects and a religious faith in economies of scale

(faith, because they’re “things not seen” beyond relatively low levels

of output). It also probably owes something to an implicit assumption

that large-scale industrialization can only be carried out by some

far-seeing “progressive” class against the will of the producing

classes: either “primitive accumulation” on the model of the Western

enclosures and expropriations, or “socialist accumulation” on the

Stalinist model. Either way, the producing classes will just sit around

comfortably chewing their cud unless they’re driven like beasts into the

factories.

The hyper-mechanization of agriculture that was brought about under

influence of Russian aid was actually less efficient, as shown by the

increased standard of living produced by intensive farming on the

neighborhood scale since the post-Soviet collapse of Cuban mechanized

farming. During the years of Soviet support, Cuba was locked into a

neocolonial policy of growing sugar for the Soviet bloc on giant

agribusiness plantations (sorry, collective farms) in return for

consumer goods. Hmmm--sound familiar? Since the end of fraternal

assistance between progressive peoples, and all that,

....Cuba... learned to stop exporting sugar and instead started growing

its own food again, growing it on small private farms and thousands of

pocket-sized urban market gardens—and, lacking chemicals and

fertilizers, much of that food became de facto organic. Somehow, the

combination worked. Cubans have as much food as they did before the

Soviet Union collapsed. They’re still short of meat, and the milk supply

remains a real problem, but their caloric intake has returned to

normal....

In so doing they have created what may be the world’s largest working

model of a semi-sustainable agriculture, one that doesn’t rely nearly as

heavily as the rest of the world does on oil, on chemicals, on shipping

vast quantities of food back and forth.

Anyway, justified or not, Castro probably did see the cutoff of U.S. aid

following the land reform as forcing him into an increasingly statist

path of industrialization.

It was the 1959 land reform – limited though it was – which first

brought a reaction from the USA. Before that America and its

multinationals coexisted peaceably enough with the new regime. But after

it things were quite different. A substantial amount of US-owned land

was involved and Washington demanded full and immediate compensation for

lands seized in the 1959 Act; it refused financial support to the Cuban

regime, supported the most reactionary of the Batista followers who had

now become refugees in Miami, and even began to aid their piratical

attacks on Cuba itself.

From the Autumn of 1959 through 1960 events moved very rapidly. Faced

with the refusal of the USA to grant aid, and an economy that could not

survive in its old laissez-faire form without such aid, Castro was

forced to use the state in a much more activist way in the economy. In

September 1959 he announced that henceforth economic development would

have to take place under the auspices of the state. On the land the

property gained by Batista’s followers during his regime was confiscated

at the end of the year. About 400 cooperatives and 485 Peoples Stores

(designed to eliminate rural profiteers) were set up by the newly

established INRA (National Association of Agrarian Reform). But Castro

at this point still hung back from nationalisation measures.

The latter were adopted in response to more active economic warfare by

the U.S.

The next phase in Cuba’s attempt to break from the stranglehold of

dependence was connected with oil. The USSR agreed to supply a limited

amount of crude to Cuba in the summer of 1960 in exchange for sugar. But

the multinationals – Texaco, Shell and Esso – refused to refine it in

their Cuban refineries. The Cuban government reacted swiftly, seizing

the installations at the end of June 1960. Within a week, Eisenhower had

cancelled Cuba’s remaining quota of sugar imports to the USA. This was

followed immediately by the confiscation of about $800m of US

corporation property – in oil, sugar, electricity and mines. The USA

responded with a total trade embargo to and from Cuba – a devastating

economic blow given Cuba’s total dependence on the US connection.

Finally the Cuban regime completed its hold on industry in October 1960

with the nationalisation of the banks, hotels, cinemas and most of the

factories and shops.

In the face of sabre rattling by Kennedy and a genuine threat of

invasion, Cuba became increasingly totalitarian. One manifestation of

this was the so-called “Committees for the Defence of the Revolution”

(CDRs), which were “[o]rganised on a block-by-block basis, [for the

purpose of forming] small squads of vigilantes to observe and report on

possible fifth columnists amongst the erstwhile lackeys of Batista and

the US multinationals.”

Meanwhile, as Castro increasingly resorted to autarky under the U.S.

embargo, a major part of those engaged in commerce and the skilled

professions left the country. Binns and Gonzalez describe the middle

class exodus in a disparaging tone that I consider completely uncalled

for:

the social basis of support for the old order within Cuba itself was

being rapidly eliminated by the fundamental changes that the

nationalisation and land reform measures were producing. More than 1/2

million refugees left Cuba in the first 3 years of the Castro regime,

unable to make a living from The exploitation of others any more. First

to go were the beneficiaries of US tourism: the US banned its citizens

from travelling to Cuba, and this led to the 10,000 pimps, the 27,000

croupiers, and many other hangers-on leaving. Then followed the business

men, the Batista ex-officers, the pampered state officials, the elite

professions, the landowners and so on. However much the US might have

wanted to put the clock back, by 1961 the layers of Cuban society that

would have enabled them to “Cubanise” any return to the old order had

more or less disappeared. The Castro regime had quite effectively

removed opposition to its continued rule.

No kidding. But it seems to me he had to create the opposition before he

could remove it. During the early days of his regime, virtually the

entire opposition came from Batista’s officers and the latifundia owners

who’d been expropriated by a fully justified land reform. To demonize

the entire commercial middle class, putting it into the same category as

landlord and military oligarchs and corrupt state officials, is insane.

And rather than a gradual and peaceful path to industrialization, with

the increasingly prosperous laboring classes cooperatively pooling their

own surplus as capital, Castro and Che were left with the prospect of

imposing industrialization as a top-down on a virtually gutted society.

The very petty bourgeois classes who had been the backbone of Castro’s

revolution had fled the country.

But I get the distinct impression that American policy elites not only

helped all this to happen, but that they actually preferred a

totalitarian Cuba with a nationalized economy, over the path the country

appeared to have been taking after the initial land reform. If Jones

couldn’t be brought back, Orwell’s neighboring farmers preferred at

least that the pigs run Animal Farm into the ground, rather than that

the animals succeed in peacefully working it with their own labor. A

“petty bourgeois” Cuba of peasant proprietors and small tradesmen and

storekeepers, peacefully producing and trading without paying tribute to

an oligarchy of landlords and generals, would have been even more

distasteful to the proponents of “free enterprise” in the U.S. than to

Marxists like Binns and Gonzalez.

There is a Cuban revolution to be reclaimed by anti-statists--much like

the Russian revolution before the Congress of Soviets was purged and the

anti-Bolshevik Left liquidated, when the soviets were still genuine

organs of self-government and the workers’ committees still functioned

in the factories. Castro and the Miami reactionaries, likewise, are not

our only choices.