💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4151.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 06:17:40. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

🚧 View Differences

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

The mystery of Jackson Hole - Central bankers wonder why success eludes them

2012-09-13 09:00:28

Sep 8th 2012 | from the print edition

IMAGINE that the world s best specialists in a particular disease have convened

to study a serious and intractable case. They offer competing diagnoses and

treatments. Yet preying on their minds is a discomfiting fact: nothing they

have done has worked, and they don t know why. That sums up the atmosphere at

the annual economic symposium in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, convened by the Federal

Reserve Bank of Kansas City and attended by central bankers and economists from

around the world*. Near the end Donald Kohn, who retired in 2010 after 40 years

with the Fed, asked: What s holding the economy back [despite] such

accommodative monetary policy for so long? There was no lack of theories. But,

as Mr Kohn admitted, none is entirely satisfying.

His question could hardly be more timely. As The Economist went to press, the

European Central Bank (ECB) was meeting to discuss a resumption in purchases of

bonds of peripheral euro-zone members, in a bid to alleviate strains on the

single currency. Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Federal Reserve, suggested

in his speech in Jackson Hole that a third round of quantitative easing (QE),

the purchase of bonds with newly created money, would be on the table when the

Fed s policy committee meets on September 12th-13th. Mr Bernanke cited research

by the Fed that previous bouts of QE had lowered bond yields and boosted GDP by

as much as 3%. That is good, but not good enough. In America, Britain and the

euro zone, interest rates are at or near zero and central banks balance-sheets

have ballooned, yet unemployment remains high and growth sluggish (see chart).

One school of thought is that a high unemployment rate is structural and immune

to the stimulative effects of monetary policy. Edward Lazear of Stanford

University and James Spletzer of America s Census Bureau argue otherwise. In a

paper presented to the conference, they showed that those sectors and

demographic groups that contributed most to the rise in unemployment in 2007-09

also contributed most to its decline in 2009-12, which suggests that shifts in

relative demand for workers could not explain the high level of unemployment.

The mismatch between the skills of the unemployed and the skills employers

demand did rise during the recession. But by late 2011 the mismatch was back

down to pre-recession levels.

If most unemployment is cyclical, not structural, the Fed could theoretically

help by stimulating demand with easier monetary policy. But how? Michael

Woodford of Columbia University told the conference that with short-term rates

around zero, central banks have tried two broad strategies: forward guidance ,

or promising to keep the interest rate at zero for some time, or expanding

their balance-sheets through QE and the like. Mr Woodford acknowledged these

strategies had brought down expected short-term and actual long-term interest

rates, but was sceptical about their impact on economic output. In his paper he

recommended that the Fed commit to keeping policy easy until the economy

reaches a particular target, such as nominal GDP (ie, output unadjusted for

inflation) returning to its pre-recession path. The Fed is not about to do

that, although it might decide to link future policy action to progress on

unemployment.

Adam Posen, who recently left the Bank of England s monetary-policy committee,

had a different explanation for the apparent impotence of monetary policy.

Since many financial markets are dysfunctional, the monetary medicine isn t

getting into the economy s bloodstream. The solution is for central banks to

buy more assets in the markets that are most obviously impaired. That is what

the Bank of England is doing by providing subsidised credit to banks that lend

more, what the ECB is set to do when it resumes purchasing sovereign bonds, and

what the Fed could do by buying more mortgage-backed securities.

Sages or dinosaurs?

In another paper, Markus Brunnermeier and Yuliy Sannikov of Princeton

University provided theoretical justification for this approach. Monetary

easing usually works by encouraging businesses and households to move future

consumption and investment forward to today. But it also has redistributive

effects. For example, low short-term interest rates redistribute income from

depositors to banks, which allows them to rebuild capital and encourages them

to lend more. Similarly, purchases of ten-year government bonds enrich some

investors while hurting others, such as pension funds, that depend on bond

income to meet longer-dated liabilities. By tailoring their instruments to

sectors most in need of support, central banks can get more bang for their

buck.

One problem is identifying the areas where direct intervention will do the most

good. Amir Sufi of the University of Chicago told the conference that raising

banks profits has not done much to restart demand because the real problem is

that indebted households cannot or will not borrow. He presented evidence that

retail spending and car sales have been weaker in states that entered the

recession with higher household debt.

An even bigger issue is the political controversy that ensues when central

banks favour particular sectors. Fed officials are constantly told that zero

interest rates are hurting savers without helping businesses. ECB purchases of

peripheral countries bonds transfer risk from debtor to creditor states,

prompting opposition from the Bundesbank and voters in creditor countries. Mr

Posen decried the self-imposed taboos and prehistoric thinking that makes

central banks worry that targeted lending will distort the allocation of credit

or turn into politically motivated money-printing. This drew a retort from

Larry Lindsey, a former Fed governor: In a free society, individuals and

institutions don t do unusual things because if you do, and break custom and

happen to be wrong, you re betting the farm.

Economist.com/blogs/freeexchange

from the print edition | Finance and economics