💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › noam-chomsky-voting-patterns-and-abstentions.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 13:00:53. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Voting Patterns and Abstentions
Author: Noam Chomsky
Date: February 2001
Language: en
Topics: voting, Elections, United States of America
Source: Retrieved on 23rd June 2021 from https://chomsky.info/200102__/
Notes: Published in Z Magazine.

Noam Chomsky

Voting Patterns and Abstentions

In commenting on the November 2000 elections (Z January), I only hinted

at important considerations that lend further insight into the

functioning of contemporary democracy: patterns of voting and

abstention. Useful information on these matters has since appeared;

particularly valuable is an analysis by Ruy Teixeira (American Prospect,

December 18), on which I rely for data.

As usual, almost half the electorate did not participate and voting

correlated with income. It remains true that “voter turnout is among the

lowest and most decisively class-skewed in the industrial world” (Thomas

Ferguson and Joel Rogers). This feature of so-called “American

exception- alism” has been plausibly attributed to “the total absence of

a socialist or laborite mass party as an organized competitor in the

electoral market” (Walter Dean Burnham).

Higher-income voters favor Republicans, but class-skewed voting does not

come close to accounting for the ability of the more openly pro-business

party to garner half the vote. The voting bloc that provided Bush with

his greatest electoral success provided the crucial contribution:

middle-to-lower income white working class, particularly men, but women

as well. By large margins they favored Gore on major policy issues, and

among voters concerned more with policy issues than “qualities” Gore won

handily. But the genius of the political system is to render policy

irrelevant. Voter attention is to be focused on style,

personality—anything but the issues that are of primary concern to the

concentrated private power centers that largely finance campaigns and

run the government. Their shared interests are off the agenda, in

conformity with Ferguson’s well-supported “investment theory of

politics.”

Crucially, questions of economic policy must not arise in the campaign.

These are of great concern both to the general population and to private

power and its political representatives, but with opposing preferences.

The business world, not surprisingly, is overwhelmingly in favor of

“neoliberal reforms,” corporate-led “globalization,” the investor-rights

agreements called “free trade agreements,” and other devices that

concentrate wealth and power. Also not surprisingly, the public is

generally opposed. It follows that such issues are not appropriate for

political campaigns.

For the public, the U.S. trade deficit had become the most important

economic issue facing the country by 1998, outranking taxes or the

budget deficit; people understand that it translates into loss of jobs,

for example, when U.S. corporations establish plants abroad that export

to the U.S. market. For the business world, a high priority is free

capital mobility: it increases profit and also provides a powerful

weapon to undermine labor organizing by threat of job

transfer—technically illegal, but highly effective, as Kate

Bronfenbrenner demonstrates in an important study extending her earlier

research (“Uneasy Terrain: The Impact of Capital Mobility on Workers,

Wages, and Union Organizing,” Cornell 2000). Such threats contribute to

the “growing worker insecurity” that has been hailed by Alan Green- span

and others as a significant factor in improving economic health by

limiting wages, benefits, and inflation that would be unwelcome to

financial interests. But such matters are not to intrude into the

electoral process: the general population is induced to vote (if at all)

on the basis of peripheral concerns.

This pattern too is familiar; I mentioned the example of 1984, when

Reagan won a “landslide victory” while voters opposed his legislative

program by a margin of 3–2. Such voting against interest is

understandable among people who feel powerless, taking for granted that

government is run by “a few big interests looking out for themselves”;

half the population in 1984, rising to over 80 percent a few years later

as the “neoliberal reforms” were more firmly instituted.

These “reforms” have the natural consequence of marginalizing the

majority of the population, as decision-making is transferred further to

unaccountable private power systems, while a “virtual Senate” of

investors and lenders can exercise “veto power” over government

decisions, thanks to financial liberalization. Regulation of capital

flow and exchange rates under the Bretton Woods system established by

the U.S. and Britain in the mid-1940s allowed for a form of “embedded

liberalism,” in which social democratic policies could be pursued within

a liberalized international economy. The dismantling of the system 30

years later was one important element of the campaign to reverse the

feared “excess of democracy” of the 1960s (to borrow the rhetoric of the

1975 Trilateral Commission report on “the crisis of democracy”), and to

restore the population to passivity and acquiescence, perhaps even

renewing the good old days when “Truman had been able to govern the

country with the cooperation of a relatively small number of Wall Street

lawyers and bankers,” as the American rapporteur, Samuel Huntington,

recalled with nostalgia.

The constitutional system was originally designed “to protect the

minority of the opulent against the majority,” in the words of the

leading framer, James Madison. Political power, he explained, must be in

the hands of “the wealth of the nation,” men who can be trusted to

“secure the permanent interests of the country”—the rights of the

propertied—and to defend these interests against the “leveling spirit”

of the general public. If the public were allowed to participate freely

in elections, Madison warned his colleagues, their “leveling spirit”

might lead to measures to improve the conditions of those who “labor

under all the hardships of life, and secretly sigh for a more equal

distribution of its blessings.” Agrarian reform was the primary threat

that Madison perceived; by now, it is much broader.

In a modern version, the general public are considered “ignorant and

meddlesome outsiders” who should be mere “spectators of action,” not

participants (Walter Lippmann); their role is only periodic choice among

the “responsible men,” who are to function in “technocratic insulation,”

in World Bank lingo, “securing the permanent interests.” The doctrine,

labeled “polyarchy” by democratic political theorist Robert Dahl, is

given firmer institutional grounds by the reduction of the public arena

under the “reforms.”

Democracy is to be construed as the right to choose among commodities.

Business leaders explain the need to impose on the population a

“philosophy of futility” and “lack of purpose in life,” to “concentrate

human attention on the more superficial things that comprise much of

fashionable consumption.” People may then accept and even welcome their

meaningless and subordinate lives, and forget ridiculous ideas about

managing their own affairs. They will abandon their fate to the

responsible people, the self-described “intelligent minorities” who

serve and administer power —which of course lies elsewhere, a hidden but

crucial premise.

From this perspective, conventional in elite opinion, the latest

elections do not reveal a flaw of American democracy, but rather its

triumph.