đŸ’Ÿ Archived View for library.inu.red â€ș file â€ș direct-unionists-direct-unionism.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 09:19:22. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

âžĄïž Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Direct Unionism
Author: Direct Unionists
Date: 2011
Language: en
Topics: Industrial Workers of the World, syndicalism, workers, Labor Union, unions, union organizing, revolutionary strategy, anarcho-syndicalism
Source: Retrieved on 2021-03-22 from http://libcom.org/library/direct-unionism-discussion-paper-09052011
Notes: A discussion paper put together by some members of the Industrial Workers of the World revolutionary syndicalist union, arguing for the organisation to build a network of militants rather than attempt to represent members. The paper was never fully finished. The early parts are finished but as the paper goes on it gets rougher and toward the end is more like notes.

Direct Unionists

Direct Unionism

Introduction: Process and Product

This paper, Direct Unionism, grew out of a few places. A group of us

became friends through working together on IWW projects. We had three

basic things in common — some experiences of local struggle and

organization in different places, participation in the IWW beyond our

immediate locations, and a common set of ideas which we had mostly

picked up through things we had read. Our experiences were and are

powerful and the memories of the past struggles remain powerful ones

that we will always carry in our hearts. The IWW is dear to us, we work

hard to build it, and we know it is not yet what it could and should be.

The ideas we’ve picked up are also dear to us, we don’t know how to

think without them, and yet their clarity is sometimes misleading. What

we’ve lived has been messier than what we’ve read, and things seem to

rarely move in straight lines in the way we have expected. None of this

added up together neatly, in part because we hadn’t done enough serious

reflection and put the effort in to make it all make sense. This paper

is an attempt to make all of those things fit together better. We don’t

get all the puzzle pieces in place, but we are clearer than we were. We

hope that this paper can help others similarly put pieces in place, and

we look forward to learning from others in discussion in response to it.

Process

This is a discussion paper that has been sitting for a while now. Over a

period of a year and a half or so several of us read drafts, suggested

revisions, and discusses many ideas that came up along the way. It was

an incredibly productive discussion that changed people’s minds and

helped us develop our ideas.

While several people had a hand in this, most of the actual words here

were written by one person. XX took up the challenge and took the time

to try to put clear words to a vision of union organizing. A lot of us

believe in this vision, but it’s vague. XX tried to make that vision

more concrete and the results had lots of benefits for everyone who was

part of the conversation. The process that this piece came out of was

very valuable and clarifying.

We’re putting this piece out now in the hope to create further

discussion. We hope people talk about this and write responses to it.

This is not because any of us want to be the center of attention, it’s

because we have gotten so much ourselves from this sort of discussion

and we think others might benefit from having similar conversations. We

would especially love if this sparked additional written responses.

Writing is hard, and it’s worth the challenge. More people should do it.

That’s another reason we put this out, because we think in general we

need more in-depth discussion through sustained reflections and

arguments — through writing, rather than just writing emails and

internet forum posts and so on. The early IWW had several publications

that regularly put out long pieces, sometimes serialized over multiple

issues. This helped the organization think. So in addition to the

contents of this paper, we offer this paper as an example of the kind of

thing we want to see more of.

Product

Enough about the process, let’s talk about the product for a moment.

Direct Unionism tries to give a clear and straightforward vision for

building unions in the workplace where the workers recognize themselves

as the union. There are some other terms for this — solidarity unionism

is one that we use a lot in the IWW. People should check out Staughton

Lynd’s book Solidarity Unionism and his book co-written with Daniel

Gross called Labor Law for the Rank and Filer; the pamphlet A Union On

Our Own Terms and the columns Minorty Report by Alexis Buss, and the

Workers Power column that runs regularly in the Industrial Worker

newspaper and online at forworkerspower.blogspot.com.

These pieces mentioned and some others have tried to lay out some of the

basic concepts and principles for this vision of unionism. Direct

Unionism does so as well. Direct Unionism tries to go further, though,

and lay out a more practical or imaginable vision. Sometimes discussions

of this vision of unionism only stay at the level of principle, or worse

sometimes they stay only at the level of rejection: “noncontractual”

unionism, for example, which defines itself entirely by what it is not

and what we want to void rather than offering a positive vision of what

we actually want to see.

Part of the problem with remaining at the level of principle is that

principles are hard to imagine. Principles matter a lot. We also need

stories, though. We need to be able describe in specific and concrete

detail what we want to do in response to our principles. We need to be

able to have detailed scenarios we can visualize — for actions, ways of

organizing ourselves, and above all for how we will spend our time

concretely in organizing day to day, week to week, and month to month.

We need models and plans. There is much more that could be said — as we

said, we would love to see more pieces of writing in response, this is

the start to a conversation rather than the last word — but we think

that what is here is worth engaging with.

We look forward to further discussions. You can contact us at

Directunionist@gmail.com

Yours for the revolution,

Direct Unionists

Part 1: Organizing the Direct Unionist Way

Part one of Direct Unionism will lay out one way the IWW can move

forward in our organizing and do so free of the restraints of labor law,

bureaucracy, and contractualism. As with the rest of the pamphlet, part

one is written in a ‘question and answer’ style that is designed to be

both thought-provoking and easily understandable. To achieve this, we’ve

attempted to avoid long boring sentences, academic language, and jargon

that may be unfamiliar to newer members.

Section 1: What would a direct unionist campaign look like?

In a nutshell, we are proposing that instead of focusing on contracts,

workplace elections, or legal procedures, IWW members should strive to

build networks of militants in whatever industry they are employed.

These militants will then agitate amongst their co-workers and lead

direct actions over specific grievances in their own workplaces. The

goal of such actions will not be union recognition from a single boss.

Instead, the goal of the actions is to build up leadership and

consciousness amongst other workers. Once a ‘critical mass’ of workers

have experience with, and an understanding of, direct action the focus

will be on large scale industrial actions that address issues of wages

and conditions across entire regions or even whole countries. It will be

from this base of power that the IWW will establish itself as a

legitimate workers’ organization.

Section 2: What sorts of techniques would be employed in a direct

unionist campaign?

When organizing without contracts — as direct unionist believe we should

be — it is of great importance the IWW is

any workplace or industry.

With this in mind, we turn to the first step of any campaign: the

workplace organizing committee. We won’t go into the details of setting

up your committee here, but we would like to emphasize that once a shop

committee is up and running, organizers should focus on agitating for

feasible direct actions.[1] While most of our readers are probably

familiar with the concept of direct action, we’d like to take a moment

to illustrate what we mean when we use the word. Direct action is when

workers — without the “help” of union bureaucrats, politicians, or

lawyers — take action to make their jobs better.

Sometimes this means making the boss change something about the job.

Perhaps you work in a coffee shop in a rough part of town and the boss

refuses to hire a security guard. You, your co-workers, family members,

and concerned community members can picket the shop demanding the boss

hire a security guard. At other times direct action means workers doing

what needs to be done without asking management for permission. Maybe

you work in a busy restaurant where managers don’t allow lunch breaks.

Instead of asking for breaks, the workers can create their own break

schedule.

Sometimes direct action can be defying what the boss says to do. In much

of the service sector, employees have trouble getting full-time hours.

Although a worker — let’s call her Jane — is scheduled for an eight-hour

shift, if sales are down she may be sent home after five hours. In

response, workers can refuse to go home in groups. When the boss says,

“Hey Jane, it’s a slow day, we’re going to need you to go home early,”

Jane and all her co-workers can walk into the boss’ office and say,

“Sorry boss, you’ve scheduled us for eight hours each and we’ll all be

working our full shifts. We’ll gladly go home if you want to pay us, but

no one here is leaving early without pay.” Like any other situation,

there’s a whole bunch more workers than bosses. As long as we stand

together, the bosses have to listen.

When organizing without contracts, it’s important that we organize

strategically and take ‘small steps’ to build up workplace power and

confidence. In the early stages of a campaign, militants should

encourage “direct action grievances.” In a direct action grievance,

workers will collectively confront whatever problem they may be having.

Instead of using labor law (Unfair Labor Practices, for example),

workers will strategize to come up with a response that involves as

large a percentage of the workforce as possible. The following list

offers some possible suggestions for direct actions. We remind our

readers that each workplace is different and offers unique challenges

and opportunities for action. As such, the following list is incomplete

and is intended only as guide:[2]

a group, consistently confront a manager on inappropriate

behaviour.Sometimes bosses treat us badly as part of company policy.

Other times, they just have ‘a chip on their shoulder’ and are taking it

out on those they supervise. In either case, workers can use a variety

of tactics to show their disapproval. This may involve workers only

speaking to their boss on matters directly related to work. If a manager

tries to spark up conversation, the response should be the same every

time: point out whatever injustice the workers are facing and describe

the desired solution. For example, workers at a restaurant may say,

“It’s not right that the company keeps our tips; we have bills to pay.

I’m not interested in speaking to someone who helps steal my money.

Perhaps we can talk when you stop asking for my tip money at the end of

my shift.”In another example, workers at a grocery store may be fed up

with getting yelled at on the floor. In response, every time the

offending manager comes around they may simply ask, “How would you feel

if you get yelled at in front of customers and co-workers? You need to

apologize to us and not ever do it again.” In both instances, it is

important that as many workers as possible confront the boss as many

times as possible and keep it up until conditions change.IWW member Nate

H. has written quite a bit about moral pressure. As he puts it:Sometimes

it is just a matter of saying, “What you’re doing is wrong” many times

by many people, making it hard for them to feel okay about what they’re

doing
 Of course not all bosses are movable this way, but it’s a useful

tactic.While recognizing that, on one hand, moral pressure is about

confronting injustice, it is also about power. In another article Nate

explains:Work is a headache for us, and to a lesser degree it’s headache

for our bosses. Generally it’s more of a headache for the boss the lower

they are on the food-chain. Emotional action [Nate’s term for moral

pressure] is when we offer our boss a choice: make work less of a

headache for us or we will make work more of a headache for the boss.

This is easier the lower the level of the boss. If the boss is a

supervisor we see every day, then they will care more about our opinions

and how we treat them.We realize that to some this may sound a bit

harsh, but all we are really suggesting is to use the boss’s tactics

against the boss. Management training courses encourage supervisors to

be aware of the emotional state of the staff. Shop-level managers are

told to “be a friend” to their employees. This way when workers disobey

a rule, not only are they breaking company policy, they are letting down

a friend. However, just as managers use emotional pressure to influence

their workers, workers can do the same to them. Managers (and even

owners) in small workplaces often work very closely with their

workforce. Because the connection is so close, local management is

easily affected when workers turn the tables and apply emotional

pressure on them.Remember that emotional tactics work best ‘low on the

food chain’ — primarily direct supervisors and assistant managers. There

is little point using emotional pressure on even a store or factory

manager, they’re too far removed from the workforce to be influenced by

such a technique. Finally, remember that moral pressure, like any other

tactic, should be tailored to individual circumstances. After all, we

don’t want to make IWW members seem like bullies. Be firm, but stress

the injustice that has made workers decide to take such a course of

action.

productivity and profit. The trick is to find them and work it to your

advantage. We’ll offer two examples here, but we’re sure you’ll be able

to find the weak spot at your place of employment and achieve the same

sorts of results.

workers in the commissioned departments led the union drive. One of the

main ways the store made profit was by having those very employees sell

extended warranties. In the course of the union drive, one of the

leaders was fired. The workers responded by going on a ‘warranty

strike.’ When customers purchased a new product, the salesperson

neglected to mention that an extended warranty was available. After

three weeks, the fired union member had his job back.

where they had to do a test run of a new customer satisfaction survey

for one of the call center’s major clients. They were placed in a

basement which was in the process of being renovated. The windows were

covered in plastic and one unfinished wall let in the cold winter air.

When the workers complained about this to their immediate supervisor she

called upstairs and was told to tell everyone to suck it up. Meanwhile,

the company was installing special recording equipment so the client

could listen in. In response to the unbearable working conditions, the

workers sent one member from their ranks upstairs to inform their

supervisor that everyone would walk out in the middle of calls while the

client was listening if they were not moved somewhere warmer. Ten

minutes later they were placed in a section upstairs.

given shop (or even just the shop committee) walk off the floor and into

the boss’ office to discuss grievances and demands.

bringing in other members of the working class to take part in a direct

action against a particular boss.In one very inspiring example, workers

in the Swedish syndicalist union, the SAC, were contacted by

undocumented workers who — as in much of the world — form the backbone

of the Stockholm restaurant industry. The bosses were exploiting the

workers’ undocumented status and were paying them below minimum wage

and/or refusing to hand over back pay. At this point the SAC had a

choice: (1) ‘go the legal route’ and try to make the bosses follow the

law, but risk exposing workers to deportation due to their lack of

papers or (2) try some creative direct action. Choosing the second

option, an SAC member called up the boss and stated, “One of the workers

in your shop belongs to our union. We’re not going to you who s/he is,

but if you don’t begin paying all your workers the minimum wage and/or

any back pay, we’re going to blockade your restaurant.” After a few

successful blockades, in most instances now all the SAC has to do is

call a restaurant owner and any pay discrepancies will be quickly

resolved.

from ‘playing favorites’ or not giving raises to workers who speak out —

workers can get together and compare paychecks. A photocopy of the

highest paid worker’s pay stub can be passed around the shop (or even

“accidentally” left in the break room). Then workers, as a group, go

into the boss’ office and demand that every worker receive the highest

rate of pay. If he or she refuses, a direct action campaign can be waged

until the boss agrees.

signs rally outside of their shop. Their presence not only puts pressure

on the boss, but also discourages customers and suppliers from coming

into the shop.While we do feel a picket can be an effective early(ish)

action, we remind our readers that they have drawbacks as well. If, for

example, only five workers out of twenty show up for a picket, the boss

has a very good idea of who the “trouble makers” are in the shop.

Finally, before undertaking any direct action, remember two very

important things. First: get trained up. The IWW offers trainings that

will prepare you and your co-workers for direct action. Unions grow by

experience and there is no better place than an organizer training for

workers to pass knowledge and experience to one another. The second

thing to remember is to be creative. No one knows your workplace better

than you and your co-workers. You know where the boss is most

vulnerable, so be smart, but don’t be afraid to go for it.

Using direct actions like the ones listed here will help build up

confidence amongst workers as well as achieve improvements in working

conditions. In the future, such actions will also build up the skills

and experience to pull off larger-scale ‘sexier’ actions like go-slows,

work-to-rules, and even strikes. We will discuss one possible use for

the power gained through sustained and successful direct action

grievance in section five, “What is the industrial strategy?.”

Section 3: Are we trying to build a “union”

In a broad sense, yes, because anytime two or more workers take

collective action, they are functioning as a union. However, in a more

narrow sense — and since direct unionism does not have recognition as an

immediate goal — we are operating outside what is traditionally

understood as a union. It is possible that after we’ve organized a large

percentage of a particular workforce we will seek to function as ‘the

vehicle of workplace struggle.’ In other words, instead of IWW members

contributing to workplace struggle as organized workers, we will force

the employer to recognize the IWW as the collective voice of the

workforce. However, in the short-term, and possibly for a very long time

(or even forever), the goal will be to involve as many workers as

possible the collective decision-making process, regardless of IWW

affiliation. In the early stages of a campaign, the organizing committee

will organize meetings of sympathetic workers to decide how grievances

will be addressed. In a more fully developed campaign, the goal will be

to arrange well-attended mass meetings that will decide upon strategy

and actions.

What about solidarity unionism?

Throughout the IWW’s history we’ve attempted ‘rebrand’ unionism to

reflect our ideals of direct democracy, militancy, and overt

anti-capitalism. One of the most inspiring examples of this is

“solidarity unionism.” Solidarity unionism is based on the idea that

workers only need solidarity to function effectively as a union — no

bureaucrats, officials, or lawyers required. Solidarity unionism rejects

the idea that a union needs recognition from the boss, or even a

majority presence, to successfully improve shopfloor conditions.

Simply put: effective agitation, intelligent organizing, and committed

militants held together by the bonds of solidarity — in a word,

solidarity unionism — has always been and will always be the backbone of

the labor movement. Although we whole-heartedly agree with the ideas and

ideals of solidarity unionism, we feel the net of solidarity unionism

has been a bit too widely cast (in contract campaigns, for example) to

fully capture how we feel a non-contractual organizing strategy should

function.

Why “direct unionism”?

Although we most certainly take inspiration from solidarity unionism,

minority unionism, and industrial unionism (and incorporate many of

their principles in to our strategy), we decided the term “direct

unionism” best fits how we believe the IWW should organize. Direct

unionism — at its very core — rejects contractualism and states that

workers should directly control their workplace organizations.

Accordingly, workers should reject any attempts to place a block between

them their struggle — including contracts, union “reps,” casework, and

full-time outside organizers.

How important is signing up workers into the IWW?

The authors of this pamphlet believe that informal participation in

workplace struggle, not formal membership in the IWW, should be the

first concern of a workplace organizer. However, we realize that both

participation and membership are important aspects of a successful

campaign.

Allow us to elaborate:

It helps sustain struggle — both in terms of finances and stability —

and encourages workers to step up into leadership positions.

‘something bigger than yourself’ and of being ‘plugged in’ to a

collective struggle. The IWW, with its open membership policies, combats

the ‘club mentality’ that often exists in any type of social movement.

it provides an extra way for them to hold organizers accountable.

Alternatively, if a shop militant steps up into a leadership positions,

his or her membership in the IWW provides another way for participants

in shop floor actions to hold her or him to account.

We also recognize that some workers may be reluctant join the IWW.

Perhaps they don’t plan on working in a particular shop for very long or

aren’t comfortable putting themselves ‘on the line’ as a union member

just yet. We feel an organizer’s time is much better spent encouraging

workplace actions instead of convincing co-workers to take out a red

card. In fact, there may be certain situations where it may be ‘safer,’

smarter, and more strategic that an organizer begins leading actions

before announcing he or she belongs to the IWW. (See the next section.)

After all, a successful action turns ‘regular’ workers into militants

faster than debate or pamphlet ever could. At the same time, even an

unsuccessful action — if properly orchestrated — makes clear the class

analysis that underpins the beliefs of the IWW.

Why do direct unionist believe we don’t always need to “fly the

union flag” to win the union’s battles?

Direct unionists recognize there are good tactical reasons to begin

fighting gripes in the workplace without letting the boss know a union

is involved. It can buy us time by building the union through struggle

before management goes on the attack. Often grievances appear like an

upswing in everyday resentment, and bosses are quick to dole out

concessions to go back to normal life. With a union however, the boss

may take drastic measures, even going so far as to close a business than

suffer the indignity of sharing power with organized workers. The

repression is much more easily dealt with after a period of exercising

collective power and inoculating against battles to come.

Organizing in such a manner allows organizers to think strategically

about how we make ourselves known, when we ask for membership, and when

(or even if) it is appropriate to build the IWW as the ‘vehicle of

struggle.’[3] The answers to these questions should help organizers

adapt to individual situations, while changing working conditions for

the better along the way.

Direct unionism, then, lowers the bar of initial activity, while

avoiding many of the problems of unions as outside organizations

(“service unionism”). This isn’t to say that we never come out as a

union early on, just that we should do so because there are no other

options and that no gains can be made without doing so (or more gains

can be made in the long run by doing so).

What is the difference between qualitative growth and quantitative

growth ?

As direct unionists we believe that the IWW needs to concentrate not on

simply growing numerically, but increasing the organizing capabilities

of our membership. Hence, we believe the union needs to focus on growing

in terms of quality — qualitatively — rather than simply believing we

build the union by numbers alone (i.e. quantitatively).

The union has already taken steps to do this very thing. The Organizer

Training Committee, with its twin goals of training Wobblies in the

concepts and practices of successful organizing, is one example of this.

However, we must build on such accomplishments. We need to find other

ways to train members to not only support the IWW in principle but to

begin agitating in their own workplaces. In fact, if every IWW member is

not actively organizing where they work, the union is not functioning as

effectively as it should. We believe the implementation of the

industrial strategy (to be discussed in part one, section five) will

help to facilitate workers becoming more active in their own workplaces

and, thus, help grow the union qualitatively.

There is one other very real reason to focus on qualitative growth: just

joining the IWW does not prepare one for struggle. We could sign up 100%

of a workplace, but without proper preparation, the organization is

nothing more than a paper tiger. Organization and struggle builds

membership, not the other way around.

When organizing new workers, we believe the direct unionist strategy

will encourage both quantitative and qualitative growth. Since workers

are included in workplace organizing regardless of membership,

co-workers get to see the IWW in action before ever committing to join

the union. Successful organizing, in turn, opens up a place to begin

discussions on topics such as class, capitalism, and the labor movement.

Once workers are committed to the IWW — both in principle and in

practice — then they can take out a red card. In such a way, direct

unionism combines the three Wobbly principles of “Agitate, Educate,

Organize” and exposes workers to them before they even fill out a

membership application.

We do we need to combat the assumption ‘join the IWW and the

struggle will come to you’?

Because of our history, professed militancy, and high ideals, the IWW

recruits many younger political activists who are attracted to our open

commitment to class struggle. However, the IWW is rife with stories of

new members who joined up, got their co-workers to do the same, and then

didn’t know where to go from there. It is situations like this that make

us emphasize, once again, the need to undertake the same types of direct

action grievances listed in section two. After all, struggle is a

process. It is created and certain elements of consciousness,

confidence, organization, and accountability must be present if we are

to make headway. These facts must be known by newer members if the IWW

hopes to effectively engage in workplace resistance. Worse yet, if we

don’t convey this information effectively we run the very real risk of

falling into service unionism, an idea that will be explored more in

part three, “Why organize without contracts?”

Section 4: The need for organization

We realize that our description of direct unionism could make it appear

we are “fetishizing” “informal workplace resistance groups.” (In other

words, advocating only for groups of pissed-off workers to concentrate

on fighting grievances in their own workplaces.) Such groups certainly

have a place and often provide the springboard for larger organizing

efforts. Yet for any struggle to become fully developed, formal

organization is eventually going to be necessary.

As our organizing experiences have taught us, overreliance on informal

work groups is a real risk. This can take the form of always expecting

the dedicated members we already have to step up to fulfil too many (or

even all) organizing tasks. This lends itself to accountability problems

and ‘clique-control.’ This can cripple even the most promising campaign.

What is needed, instead, is (1) formalized accountability from our

organizers and (2) for militants from different workplaces to link up

into industrial networks, a topic that will be covered in section five.

The need for organization begins in the workplace itself. Some of this

is quite simple: formal bylaws, scheduled meetings, regular reporting,

and votes on all important matters. Likewise, it is important to

maintain a record of struggle. If a campaign is public, newsletters

provide one way to do this. In an ‘under the radar’ campaign, militants

may want to write (or even record) ‘testimonials’ that highlight changes

that came as a result of direct action. Besides being a record of

successful (and not so successful) tactics, such testimonials can be

read by future workers to give them a sense of the history of the

campaign.

(Such testimonials, we should note, carry a very real danger. If they

fall into the hands of a boss, the can spell trouble for the workers who

created them. If a campaign decides to use testimonials, it may make

sense to have them typed up anonymously or, if they are recorded, to

have them re-read and re-recorded by a Fellow Worker who does not work

in that particular shop.)

The need for organization also has implications for bringing new workers

into a campaign. This can be a tricky process, but is also one that is

absolutely key if the IWW is to survive and grow as a shopfloor

presence. One way to accomplish this is for an ‘ambassador’ to reach out

to each employee who is not actively involved. For example, if a new

hire comes into the shop, a friendly member of the organizing committee

can strike up a conversation about something that has recently changed.

He or she might say, “They used to make us stay for an extra fifteen

minutes after we’d clocked out to clean up. They stopped, though, since

we let them know we weren’t going to put up with it. If they ask you to

stay late, come let me know and we’ll work out a response. Don’t worry,

workers here are willing to stand up for one another.” In this way, the

organizer has introduced the new hire into a culture of solidarity and

offered support in advance, but not scared off him or her by asking them

to join a union, pay dues, or ‘resist the tyranny of the boss class.’

Once the new employee is a bit more comfortable in their job (made so

through the support of members on the organizing committee) or has

mentioned a grievance, then s/he can be brought into the more formal

network of workplace resistance.

All of this confirms something that all IWWs should keep in mind:

organizing is about small steps and building relationships of trust.

This must always be our guiding principle when we organize.

A final note on organization: direct unionists want to build the form of

organization that makes the most sense for the workplace, the industry,

and the current level of class struggle in society as whole. We try not

to overemphasize formalism. In other words, we don’t judge a struggle

simply on its particular form — be it the union form, the workplace

assembly form, or a “workers council” form. No form is perfect and the

content and the goals of a struggle must be taken into account. In the

final analysis, the goal of direct unionism is to create ‘practiced

democracy, self-activity, and self-leadership’ within the context of a

‘participatory, collective, and class-conscious proletarian struggle.’

What this struggle may look like is going to vary from place to place

and time to time. The goal, however, never changes.[4]

How will non-contractual organizing maintain workplace gains?

This is no small question. Since the end goal is not the signing of a

contract (or, in many instances, even formal recognition from the boss)

it is up to IWW members to create a culture of resistance that will

continually defend gains. (In a sense, this is not much different than a

contract since bosses regularly violate a contract when they don’t think

workers are organized enough to offer a defense.) To describe how we

think this is best achieved we return to a concept developed by the IWW

close to one-hundred years ago: job conditioning. Job conditioning is

based on the idea that once experience, confidence, and solidarity is

built up through small job actions, workers can begin tackling larger

issues by ‘playing by their own rules.’

In many factories, including non-union ones, workers set the pace of

production by refusing to work faster than a given speed. If the workers

decide they will only make ten tables in an hour and they all stick to

it, there is nothing the boss can do to change it. The workers have

conditioned the boss through their solidarity and willingness to stand

together. Even some of the IWW’s greatest achievements were won through

job conditioning. In the early 1900’s when the IWW won the 8-hour day in

the timber and wheat fields it was through a combination of raw

industrial power (willingness to strike) and job conditioning: workers

simply walked off the job after eight hours.

We realize these examples may seem a bit long-sighted given where the

IWW is right now. What’s important is that they were only possible

because workers built up a culture that relied on solidarity and trust

to establish and maintain gains. As direct unionists move forward in our

organizing, we need to stress to our co-workers that solidarity and

solidarity alone is the only weapon workers can rely on to make and

cement gains in the workplace (not labor law, contracts, politicians, or

union bosses).

When discussing organization, it is important to understand that direct

unionism, like any form of unionism, poses problems of administration.

Struggle is going to ebb and flow. Because of this — and especially in

high-turnover industries — a direct unionist campaign may only lead to

certain percentage of a particular workforce being actively organized at

a given time. It’s important that our co-workers understand this and are

prepared for this potential outcome. Having the presence of an

organizing committee in a shop will improve conditions, but by rejecting

legalized notions of collective bargaining, sustaining a union presence

is going to have its ups and downs. We view it like this: preparing

workers for potential administrative difficulties is part of the

inoculation process that the Organizer Training 101 addresses and the

inoculation process all direct unionists should be taking their

co-workers through.

Finally, we’d like to note that direct unionism does not reject

recognition from the boss. It only rejects ‘official’ recognition and

the legalistic methods (contracts, labor board elections, union

registration) used to do so. However, we also recognize that even

non-contractual recognition carries risks and that in certain instances

it is just not a realistic goal.[5] The focus, at least in the

foreseeable future, should be the creation of industrial networks, a

topic we now turn to...

Section 5: What is the industrial strategy?

As direct unionists, we believe the IWW must pursue a non-contractual

“industrial strategy” if we are to grow as a working class force. In the

introductory paragraph to section one, we laid out very briefly how

industrial networks should function:

...The goal [of smaller-scale workplace] actions [are] to build up

leadership and consciousness amongst other workers. Once a ‘critical

mass’ of workers have experience with, and an understanding of, direct

action the focus will be on large scale industrial actions that address

issues of wages and conditions across entire regions or even whole

countries.

The goal of industrial networks, then, is threefold:

direct action grievances.

preferably through the formation of IUBs.

cement gains and standardize conditions across the industry.

As we see it, the industrial strategy must be a ‘two-pronged’ attack

that will differ depending on whether IWW members are organizing in a

union or non-union workplace. In workplaces with and without a

recognized union, the immediate goals will be the same: the creation of

a rank-and-file shop committee that will encourage and help organize

direct action grievances in much the way we’ve described in this

pamphlet.

In workplaces where IWWs are dual-carding, the organizing committee will

seek to encourage workers to ‘supersede’ (i.e. move ‘above and beyond’)

the trade-union form and push for mass assemblies as the only legitimate

voice of the workforce. Wobblies will encourage struggle to be organized

across trade unions (since many workplaces have more than one active

union, a fact bosses regularly uses to their advantage) and seek to

bring unorganized workers into the struggle as well. When mass actions

occur, Wobblies should make sure that workers remain in full control of

the struggle. This means democratic and open mass assemblies of workers

(as opposed the secretive “back rooms” inhabited by union officials)

must decide every aspect of the struggle. The final decision on what

actions to take and when to call them off must be decided by the workers

themselves.

When union-sanctioned struggle occurs, organized Wobblies should take a

leading role in laying the groundwork for successful industrial action.

Recently, Wobblies working at AT&T did this very thing. In summer 2009,

workers at AT&T were preparing for a nationwide strike since contract

negotiations had broken down between the Communication Workers of

America and company management. Recognizing that the CWA was woefully

unprepared for strike action, an IWW shop committee in an AT&T call

center began organizing actions (including a work-to-rule) to build

solidarity amongst their co-workers. They also discussed ways to ‘up the

ante’ should management not be responsive to the strike, including a

potential occupation of the office.

Of course, it goes without saying that we are not seeking to function as

a union pressure group, reform caucus, or trying to “capture” official

positions within the union (although IWW members may well decide to

serve as shop stewards, safety reps, or other ‘lay’ union positions). In

a union workplace, the IWW organizing committee must remain independent

of the recognized union at all times. In fact, all militant workers must

be prepared to clash with the union when we overstep the bounds of

‘acceptable industrial action’ or encourage our workmates to ignore

anti-worker labor laws.

How would the industrial strategy work in the long-term?

As direct unionist we recognize that all tactics have limitations. Given

that capitalism “cannot exist without constantly revolutionizing the

instruments of production, and thereby the relations of production,” the

job conditioning we advocate is primarily a medium-term solution. In

other words, since the bosses are always seeking to increase profit in

any way possible — undercutting the gains of workers, using new

technology, “outsourcing” jobs, etc. — simple job conditioning is not

going to be enough. As a long-term solution (and we cannot emphasize

enough that Organizing without Contracts focuses on the here and now),

the IWW and the working class must decide what to do with the power we

build through successful industrial networks. This is not something we

intend to decide right now. We recognize, however, that when the time

comes we will have to strike a balance between protecting

“bread-and-butter” gains and continuing down the path of revolutionary

unionism. In terms of bread-and-butter it may make sense to institute

hiring halls in industries and regions where the IWW exercises large

amounts of industrial might.

In the long-term, politically and socially, our goal should be changing

the way workers relate to one another, how they view their boss, and how

the working class understands the larger economic system. In a nutshell,

we need to be able to leverage the short-terms gains we make to not only

improves conditions, but to make workers understand that we won’t be

able to achieve long-term changes in society without a fundamental

confrontation with capital.[6] We don’t pretend to know what the demands

— revolutionary or not — will be when these large scale conflicts occur.

The demands will develop and be set by the working class in the process

of struggle. The long-term goal of the industrial strategy, then, is to

organize in a way that develops such consciousness and gives workers a

way to relate to one another that creates that very change within their

workplaces and within themselves.

Section 6: Non-Contractual Organizing in the IWW

Since, admittedly, the IWW is not involved in the sort of widespread

non-contractual campaign we’ve laid out in this pamphlet, this section

will focus on two things:

non-contractual campaign. In particular, we will concentrate on the

potential of the Industrial Delegate System while highlighting current

campaigns that have made successful use of direct action grievances.

Local 8 will be our prime case study.

In keeping with the renewed interest and growth the IWW has experienced

since the turn of the 21^(st) century, in 2009 the General Executive

Board passed a motion to create an Industrial Delegate for IU 530. The

premise for the Industrial Delegate System (IDS) is simple: workers in a

particular IU can choose to pay their dues directly to their IU’s

delegate. Their dues money will then be split between the Industrial

Organizing Committee and the general administration.

When the IU 530 Freight Truckers Organizing Committee proposed the IDS,

they did not do so in a specifically non-contractual context. However,

we feel that the structure of the IDS lends itself quite well to a

non-contractual campaign. As a precursor to an Industrial Union, it

creates the exact sort of industrial networks we’ve been talking about.

Workers create organizing committees both in their workplace and across

the industry. Those organizing committees then begin opening lines of

communication (conference calls, newsletters, listserves, conferences,

etc) in which workers can share experiences and plan actions.

Another example worth mentioning is the success of the Starbucks Workers

Union in employing direct action grievances. Through the use of simple

measures such as moral pressure workers have forced abusive managers to

resign. In a celebrated example, workers took matters of health and

safety into their own hands and forced Starbucks to install an

industrial-strength fan in an overheated workplace.

Historically, few examples demonstrate the potential of a

non-contractual organizing model more than Local 8 of the Marine

Transport Workers Industrial Union. Established in the nineteen-teens by

Philadelphia longshoremen, two things made Local 8 remarkable. The first

was that its leaders and membership were biracial. In an age where most

unions were openly racist, Local 8 organized black and white workers as

equals. The second thing that made Local 8 so special was the fact it

established ‘worker control’ on the Philadelphia docks while balancing

bread-and-butter concerns with radical, non-contractual principles. To

achieve this Philadelphia’s longshore workers would strike any pier in

which a shipper tried to bring in non-union labor to unload cargo. Or,

if a shipping agent tried to pay below the union rate or ignored union

work rules, workers struck and held mass pickets outside the ship. When

workers decided a raise was needed, a delegation would be sent to the

bosses with the demand. If the bosses refused, a direct action campaign

would be waged until the workers called it off. Although they did not

always receive the full amount requested (Local 8 was not opposed to

elected and accountable negotiating committees), such tactics saw

Philadelphia longshoremen win some of the highest wages of any pier in

the country.

To ensure that non-union workers would not bring down wage rates,

members of the Local 8 refused to work with non-union members or

individuals who were not caught up on dues. Such practices ensured IWW

members maintained steady work (no small feat in the shipping industry)

and that the IWW had de facto control of hiring practices. If a

potential co-worker did not meet the requirements of a dedicated class

warrior (by scabbing, for example), they would be denied a red card and,

thus, denied a job on the docks.

Section 7: Non-contractual organizing outside the IWW

The following examples are not necessarily direct unionist, but they do

point to ways that, historically and contemporarily, workers (many of

whom would not identify as ‘radical’) have organized in ways that

avoided getting bogged down by contractualism and legalized notions of

unionism. As such, they are worthy of examination and discussion by

direct unionists.

McDonald’s Workers’ Resistance: We are including the example of the MWR

not because we believe it is the ideal example of how the IWW ought to

move forward, but because it shows the manner in which a successful

network of ‘everyday workers’ can be built in the notoriously hard to

organize service sector. MWR began when workers in a Glasgow McDonalds

decided their jobs basically sucked. Instead being constantly exploited

at their “McJob,” they decided their lives would be much better if they

began sticking up for one another and sticking it to the boss. Much of

MWR’s organizing was just trying to make their jobs more liveable.

“Zines” were printed which told raunchy jokes about Ronald McDonald and

encouraged co-workers to slow down on the job, take longer breaks, or

refuse to do unsafe work.

Notably, very little of the MWR focused on issues of wages. As one of

the founders later recalled, the MWR lost much of its steam once they

began to tackle more ‘traditional’ labor issues. That being said, MWR

was not without its victories. It ran a successful website that

connected pissed off workers from around the world and in 2002, MWR

called for all McDonald’s workers to undertake a day of resistance.

Direct actions, including attempted work stoppages and go-slows, were

undertaken in England, Europe, Russia, and Australia. Besides giving the

MWR some serious publicity, such a day of actions encouraged solidarity

and consciousness amongst a massive, young, and unorganized workforce.

Of course, the faults of the MWR are many. Due to the secretive nature

of the organizing, communication was patchy at best. More importantly,

MWR’s lack of structure provided little room for accountability or

coordination. However, what’s important to take aware from MWR is the

notion of how to build networks. We shouldn’t be promising workers what

we can’t yet deliver, be it a raise or a revolutionary struggle.

Instead, IWWs should agitate around conditions to create a shared sense

of struggle and focus on linking up pissed-off workers across an

industry. By facilitating such dialog we not only increase the potential

for concerted activity, but spread our ideas to workers who may have

never considered themselves “unionists” or “militants” but are fed up

with their jobs and looking for a way to improve their working lives.

Gravel Truck Drivers and Taxi Workers in Edmonton:

Puerto Real Shipyards: The struggle in the Puerto Real began when the

Spanish government attempted to shut down the shipyard in the late

1980s. As is common in most Spanish workplaces, multiple unions were

operating in the yard including the anarcho-syndicalist CNT. From the

struggle’s inception, the CNT took a leading role in organizing

resistance to the government’s plans. While the struggle was ultimately

successful — the shipyard remained open and workers won a number of

concessions — it is the form of the struggle that most interests us.

When the CNT organizes, the goal is always to organize in such a manner

that the mass assembly of workers always has the final say. In Puerto

Real, such a method brought dramatic consequences.

When the CNT called assemblies they were open not only to CNT members,

but all shipyard workers, their families, and the entire working-class

community of Puerto Real. Such an arrangement brought a flowering of

resistance and encouraged widespread direct action. For example, every

Tuesday was dedicated to acts of solidarity and resistance. Barricades

were set up, offices occupied, and workers cut telephone service in an

effort to put pressure on the bosses and the government. Of course, such

assemblies showed the ability of everyday people to successfully control

their own struggles and do so in a way that relies only on solidarity,

direct action, and direct democracy to do so.

Before continuing we would like to remind our readers that, as addressed

in part one, section four, form is only one part of the struggle.[7] The

content (basically the long and short-term demands and practiced

democracy within the movement) and the leadership that comes from any

struggle are all keys toward creating the direct unionist movement we

desire. Form alone does not build consciousness, let alone the

revolutionary activity that direct unionism ultimately seeks. While the

form of the Puerto Real struggle is commendable, other forms (and new

forms!) may be better suited to other situations.

All that being said, we believe the CNT’s actions in Puerto Real show

how a successful direct unionist approach to organizing could operate.

As direct unionists we can relate to both their theoretical rejection of

contractualism and their practical implementation of mass struggle. As

the IWW moves forward this is a model and struggle that we can look

toward for inspiration.

Part 2: What are potential problems that the IWW may encounter during

a non-contractual campaign?

In part 2 we will be analyzing potential pitfalls that direct unionists

face when organizing. We recognize that anti-contractualism is not a

‘silver bullet.’ In many ways it actually makes successful organizing

harder, as it’s not willing to exchange militancy for stability (a

set-up that is to the advantage of both the bosses and the big unions).

Thus, direct unionism requires a higher level of commitment from both

workers and organizers.

We do apologize that language in part two is a bit more technical (and

will probably be a bit more technical in part three). While we’ve still

done our best to keep things as simple as possible, when dealing with

the in and outs of labor law and contract language, things are bound

things are bound to get slightly wordy. If a section is too confusing —

and we mean this in all seriousness — please feel free to email us at

directunionist@gmail.com with any questions.

Section 1: Will the direct unionist strategy lead to short-terms

gains as quickly as a contract campaign? How about in medium-term?

In the short-term we believe that, yes, it will. As even the business

union recognize, the chances of a successful organizing drive (which, in

their world, always means securing a contract) are dependent on having

an organized, activated workforce which is capable of actually

pressuring the boss. Despite their reformism, even mainstream unions

recognize that workplace elections alone do not result in a successful

campaign; they must be supported by organization on the ground. (Where

contractualists in the IWW would differ on this point is that unlike

‘big labor,’ they would not want to ‘turn of the valve of militancy’

once a contract is in effect.) In such a way, the content of a contract

is a reflection of the workers’ power to force change upon the boss.

This same dynamic will be at play in a non-contractual campaign: in the

initial time-period the IWW establishes itself at a particular shop, the

conditions will change according the how successful the workers are at

employing direct action (or the threat of direct action) to change shop

conditions.

As we mentioned in part one, direct unionists, taking lessons from years

of recent IWW campaigns, believe we can more effectively win gains

‘under-the-radar.’ In our organizing we’ve repeatedly seen that we’re

able to leverage more from a boss who doesn’t know the union is there

than from a boss who is pitted against a union drive. These covert

fights provide the ‘lessons of struggle’ that that will build the

foundation of the direct union to come. However this is not always a

viable strategy in all workplaces. While we may be able to win

grievances more quickly, it is also true that some bigger issues may

take longer with direct unionism. Contract negotiations contain some

[legally prescribed] bargaining items that the shop might not otherwise

have the strength to leverage through action alone. The reality, of

course, is that without that power said contract will be weak, but we

recognize that direct unionism may be slower on these issues.

In the medium-term, things get more complicated. Contracts do provide

stability. When workers come to a job, they know there’s a union —

there’s a contract to prove it. If the boss tries to break the contract,

the union can turn to the law for recourse. More broadly, contracts,

especially when under the control of a militant local, can breed a sense

of entitlement and even encourage militancy. (Unfortunately, in many

cases this militancy ends up coinciding with contract cycles — an idea

that will explored further in part three.)

In a non-contractual campaign, there is a constant need to organize each

new worker who comes into the shop. Since militancy is the only recourse

workers have, workers must be continually vigilant if they want to

ensure gains are protected. No doubt, such a state of affairs can lead

to burnout, and without a conscious creation of a culture of collective

action, the union may fade with the struggles. Likewise, if workers do

not pass on leadership skills to each ‘generation’ of new hires, the

loss of a shop floor militant can have dramatic and negative effect on

the union. However, when effective, a system that requires constant

renewal of militancy and leadership is a far better breeding ground for

‘workers self-activity’ and the class consciousness that accompanies it.

Section 2: What if workers “want” a contract?

The IWW has long been an organization that prides itself on an utmost

dedication to democracy and, along with it, local autonomy and

respecting worker initiative. In light of this, we come to another

dilemma: what happens when workers want a contract?

Let’s be direct here: many workers, when they have achieved a living

wage, decent benefits, and tolerable working conditions are

understandably concerned with ensuring those gains are protected.

Contracts provide one way to do this. By providing a ‘truce’ between

labor and management, contracts offer workers a way to gain some

well-deserved stability. Likewise, individuals are limited by what they

think is possible. Since the modus operandi for the mainstream of labor

(including ‘pro-labor’ politicians, liberal academics, and labor

reporters in the media) is a collective agreement, it’s entirely

understandable that workers will be enticed to follow such a route. It’s

what workers think is possible and, often, what they believe to be

ultimately desirable.

(We note here that in the countries where the IWW is most active — and

especially in the US — union density and active organizing has been on

the wane for decades. Ironically, this opens up a space for IWWs to

present our ideas of unionization to those who may have very little

understanding of what a union is and how they are ‘supposed’ to

function. In fact, in many instances, IWW organizers may inadvertently

give the impetus to a contract campaign by presenting the differences

between “us” as the IWW and “them,” the business unions. If IWW methods

falter, workers then look to other, contractual, options. This is not to

say that direct unionists should ever ‘withhold’ information from

co-workers, but that simple solidarity — the basis for both contractual

and non-contractual unionism — should always be the focus of any

organizing efforts.)

So what is to be done?

Before answering this question we should take this opportunity to

clarify our goals are as direct unionists. First, let it be said that by

encouraging a non-contractual organizing strategy we are, in many ways,

putting the building of class power before the protection of

bread-and-butter gains. As we alluded to in our discussion of

quantitative growth v. qualitative growth (part one, section three),

direct unionists are not only concerned with gaining new members or

recognition from a single boss, but believe these should only occur as a

byproduct of the development of working class leadership and

consciousness. It’s tempting to believe that once we have the numbers,

then we’ll begin pulling our weight. In reality, however, this has never

been and never will be the case. Our organizing must reflect our desire

to not only improve wages and conditions, but to become a successful

class-based, revolutionary organization

To begin answering the question, then, first and foremost we should be

open with our strategy from the very onset. Whether pursuing a

non-contractual course or not, there is no question the IWW is a union

unlike any other. This is something we explain to new members. We

explain our dedication to union democracy; our belief in direct action

and solidarity; the reason we reject dues check-off and refuse to cross

picket lines; and, finally, we explain the preamble and all that it

entails. It should be no different with non-contractual unionism. We

should upfront with what we believe, how we organize, and most

importantly, how we intend to do it.

We should be clear with ourselves, the larger union, and the workers

whom we’re organizing alongside: the way we organize will inevitably

affect the ‘character’ of any successful organizing (as in lasting

workplace organization) that results from those efforts. Labor law

individualizes and divides — both on a personal level and between

individual unions, campaigns, and workplaces. Direct action and

solidarity, on the other hand, build up a collective consciousness. But

it’s important to recognize what comes first: direct action and

solidarity. These must be the building blocks of not only successful

organization, but successful education. The advantage we have when

orchestrating non-contractual campaign is our ability to turn to the

wealth of testimonials that demonstrate the ineffectiveness of

contractualism. These range from first-hand IWW experience — for

example, the article “NLRB is No Friend in Portland (Neither are

Contracts)”[8] that appeared in July 2009 Industrial Worker — to the

classic work Punching Out by auto worker and scholar Marty Glaberman.[9]

Only through such a process of experience and dialog will we be able to

prove to ourselves and those we organize that despite its siren song,

the contract is a dead end to building true workers’ power.

However, what if, after all of this, workers still want to ‘go the

contractual route’? What if our co-workers vote in large majority to

pursue a contract with their employer; what does this mean for the

direct unionist organizer? First, it means our organizing has failed on

some level. Second, it then shifts how we will relate the organization

that results from the union effort. Let’s say, for example, that the

drive results in a contract. Since we intend that most direct unionist

organizing will be internal (i.e. IWW members organizing their immediate

co-workers), the dedicated direct unionist will approach the IWW

contract the same way he or she approaches any other contract.

Within the union there is a belief that IWW contracts will not be

affected by the same constraints as other unions (or alternatively,

we’ll ignore the labor laws governing contracts when it’s advantageous.)

As we’ll outline in much more thorough detail in part three, it’s not

the content of current IWW contracts that we reject to, per se, it’s the

structural (and social) limitations that contracts carry with them.

Accordingly, we believe that despite the truest of best intentions, even

IWW contracts will not save the working class from dangers of service

unionism and legalism.

Beyond contract clauses, de-democratization of the labor movement is

part-and-parcel of any labor-relations regime. The IWW should be — and

long has been — praised for its commitment to democratic unionism.

Contracts, and any other form of state-mediated labor relations, seek

not only to deal with centralized, hierarchical (in a word,

undemocratic) unions, but seek to de-democratize struggle itself. With

the above facts in mind (and once again, these topics will be covered in

much greater detail in the next part of Direct Unionism), we return to

the arguments we made in part 1, section five, regarding dual-carders.

Our goals, as direct unionists, then will be the same in IWW contract

shop as they would be in any other contract shop: to ensure that

struggle itself is democratized to as large an extent as possible.

Likewise, we’ll use our experience as direct unionists in IWW shops

(since one of us is already in this predicament) to expand our arguments

for the dangers of the IWW entering into contractual relationships with

the bosses.

It is also our hope that this document, and the ‘direct unionist

current’ that has formed around its writing, will lead to a more direct

unionist oriented IWW. It is our hope direct unionism will come to be

built into the organizing strategy of the union itself. Such

‘structural’ support for direct unionism will increase the likelihood

that direct unionist organizing drives succeed and that workers new to

the IWW will become easily integrated into the direct unionist model.

Section 3: What happens when we win? When we lose?

Common sense says that you win you win, and if you lose you lose.

Collectively, our experiences are much more complicated than this. For

example, during the early 2000s the Portland IWW experienced a flurry of

organizing. Some of these campaigns resulted in contracts, and others

were crushed by employer repression. The interesting thing is that after

the dust settled, nearly all of the committed organizers came from

campaigns that were lost, and successful campaigns produced few

long-term organizers. These experiences have since been seen throughout

the IWW and in our organizing in general.

There are a number of crucial points to understanding what organizing to

build class power involves. Generally when workers decide to take steps

and organize (as opposed to being agitated from the outside, or

organizers infiltrating and organizing within) it is around concrete

issues at work, changes, gripes, etc. People generally seek out

organizing when the shop is hottest as a last step or near-last step in

their aggravation. Either these problems are solved, or they aren’t. In

cases where we win — whether contractually or not — there is a natural

tendency for people to relax. Fights are nasty, unpleasant, and can in

some cases make things worse before getting better. When grievances are

solved even temporarily, people don’t want to go on fighting forever

(unless something has changed fundamentally
). With direct union

campaigns this means we often lose a shop with victories. In fact the

easier the fight, the quicker the shop cools down. This can provoke a

strange phenomenon where the boss who rolls over on the most, undermines

our ability to organize by depriving us of the collective action that

energizes and transforms people. We are able to gain organizers from

these struggles, but this paradox is a repeated occurrence which cannot

be ignored. This is part of the reason our practice developed the

concept of networks of organizers that keep the fight going across an

industry when shops cool down. We will return to this in a later

section.

In a contract shop, the same thing generally occurs. The comfort of a

contract gives an extra nudge to resting from the struggle with the

illusion of stability given by a contract. To take an example, we saw a

victory at a strike in social service at an SEIU shop in 2004 one of us

was involved in. The shop had been fundamentally unorganized, despite

having a contract. Building up to the strike, little support was

garnered. Miraculously, the strike itself flipped and transformed the

workers from largely taking what management was giving, to confronting

them directly on the picket line, offices, and homes. With the

resolution of the strike however, nearly three-quarters of the strikers

quit instantly, and the rest left within two years. The union had to

rebuild from scratch, and in fact never rebuilt completely and was

nearly eradicated during cuts a few years later.

In some instances failure produces the opposite effect. In Portland a

bike messenger shop was organized on a direct unionist basis, and was

able to fight and win some grievances against a tyrannical boss. The

campaign faltered though as the workers ran into objective limitations

in their organizing, and the inability to expand the campaign beyond

their organized base in the shop to take the fight higher against the

bosses escalating repression. Out of those struggles, the workers

launched a strike which crippled the business, but was unable to win the

gains the workers sought. Yet out of that campaign the IWW gained

committed organizers. The same thing was repeated time and time again.

What is happening is contrary to everything we hear about unions. We

hear that workers join unions to improve their material circumstances,

and join/stay with the union that best meets their needs. There is

supposedly a connection between the ability of unions to leverage

material gains and an increase in class power broadly. Ignoring the

problems of these popular ideas historically (whether unions check class

power or increase it), our practice and struggle have shown us that it

misunderstands fundamental things about class struggle. A concept we see

repeated constantly is that action often precedes consciousness. That is

to say that workers will often take collective action which is in

apparent contradiction to what they may say or think. Yet struggling

collectively against a boss is transformative. It changes the way we

relate to our coworkers and bosses, it changes the way we think about

work, society, class, the world, and ourselves, and it can change our

commitments. With this understanding, we can make sense of winning by

losing and losing by winning. The question isn’t whether we win in all

instances, or how to do damage control on our losses, but instead

through our organizing how can we facilitate the collective

transformation of workers in struggle so that we produce as many

committed worker revolutionaries as possible. This perspective leads to

a fundamental rethinking of unions, and an understanding of distinctions

between what is good for the class vs good for unions, what the role of

organizing is in building towards another society, and what role

grievances and workplace issues have in organizing.

Section 4: How would a Direct Unionist campaign relate to labor law?

As will be elaborated upon in part three, direct unionists do not

believe labor law can ever be a liberating force for workers. We limit

our use of labor law to the simple fact that a well-informed workforce

keeps the boss in line. Knowing the names of statutes and the dates of

court cases will keep managers — especially low-level managers — ‘on

their toes.’ However, like everything else that takes place on the

shopfloor, only the unified power of the workers can force employers to

follow even the limited labor regulations that exist.

Can even defensive use of labor law, ULPs for example, disempower

workers?

The authors of this pamphlet are not universally opposed to ULPs, but we

view them with a very skeptical eye. In a nutshell, our premise is this:

as a purely defensive measure, ULPs can be effective. We believe serious

problems arise when a campaign begins to use labor law offensively. When

we allow an entire organizing drive to be dependent on law we — no pun

intended — put the ball in the bosses’ court. We have to organize on our

own terms and in such a way the builds up the skills, resources,

experience, and confidence of our class.

To put in another way, ULPs and other forms of government-recognized

grievance procedures — even when successful — still removes power from

the worker’s hands. Knowing basic labor law and being able to ‘represent

oneself’ are worthwhile skills, but labor law always attempts to

individualize grievances, and thus lessen collective power and put up

walls to effective solidarity.

Part 3: Why Organize Without Contracts?

While we certainly feel the techniques we’ve outlined could be useful in

even a contractual campaign, in part 3 we’ll be addressing the reasons

we oppose contractualism. Before continuing we’d like to stress that

while we draw upon many historical and theoretical arguments, our

reasons for writing this discussion paper — and part 3 in particular —

are based on our union experiences, both within the IWW and in so-called

business unions.

Section 1: What are the pitfalls of contractualism?

General problems of contractualism

To begin to answer this question, we must examine how a contract

operates. A contract does a number of things. Most importantly, it

recognizes the union as the ‘bargaining agent’ for a particular

workplace. This means that management must negotiate with the union over

wages and conditions. Every year (or more likely, every couple of years)

the contract will expire and the union and the boss will negotiate a new

contract. If the union is democratic, the workers have a right to vote

on the new contract. If the contract is not to the workers’ liking, the

workers — theoretically — have the right to strike. In this way

contracts seem appealing as they often improve wages and make work a bit

more bearable.

However, alongside such benefits, workers have learned that contracts

trap workers as much as they liberate them. Workers have consistently

mentioned five distinct objections to contracts:

a “no strike clause.” No strike clauses state that during the life of a

contract workers may not engage in ‘work stoppages’ for any reason. If

workers strike while under contract it’s known as a “wildcat.” When

wildcats occur the union can be fined and the company can get a judge to

issue an “injunction” to force the strikers back to work. Under an

injunction, the government (most likely the police) forces striking

workers back onto the job. A few militant and powerful unions have

managed to keep no strike language out of contracts, but the courts have

very often determined that a union contract in and of itself functions

as a no-strike agreement.

nothing more than a “labor peace agreement.” The agreement works like

this: in exchange for better wages and conditions, workers will not

interfere with the process of production. Management rights clauses make

labor peace agreements official. Such clauses — which are present in

nearly every union contract — prohibit workers from taking part in

decisions of how to set up the shop, who to hire and fire, how and where

a company invests profits, and other such crucial business activities.

Under a management rights clause, workers are essentially told “Shut up,

we’ve given you as much as we’re going to give you. Don’t try and change

company policy or exert any control over the workplace.” And under a

management rights clause, workers are contractually obligated not to do

so.

grievance procedure. What this basically means is that if a union member

feels management has violated the contract, he or she has the right to

file a grievance. A union representative then takes the grievance up

with management in the hopes of ‘winning’ the grievance on behalf of the

worker. Once again, in theory, this sounds pretty good. However, for the

bosses, the purpose of such a system is to direct worker discontent into

management approved channels. For some perspective on how a binding

grievance procedure benefits the company, it is worthwhile to read the

words of auto worker and academic Marty Glaberman. As Marty tells it,

before the introduction of the binding grievance procedure,It was common

practice in the auto shops for negotiations on the shop level to consist

of the steward [elected by his fellow workers, not appointed by the

union], surrounded by all the men in the department, arguing with the

foreman. No one worked until the grievance was settled — and most of

them were settled in the workers’ favor without the red tape of a

bargaining procedure, appeals, and umpires.After binding grievance

clauses were introduced into the auto plants, it became the union’s job

to sort out grievances and ensure they were handled ‘properly.’ Having

worked in union auto plants, Marty could offer an honest view of how

binding grievances led to the union actually “policing” and “managing”

the workers’ grievances:The [union] committeeman usually considers it

his job to keep grievances from being written. At each stage of the

grievance procedure a majority of grievances are thrown out by the union

representatives. This is supposed to be in order to assure that only the

best grievances are appealed so that they can be won. But when the last

stage, the “impartial” umpire, is reached, half of the few grievances

remaining are lost anyway — that’s what impartiality is supposed to

be.When workers take power into their own hands it scares the bosses, so

they look for ways to control and manage the anger of their workers. One

of those ways is the binding grievance procedure. Worse yet, as part of

the bargain for “labor peace,” the union becomes responsible for helping

to enforce discipline in the shop. This includes enforcing the grievance

procedure. In this way, the union and the contract become part of the

management structure of the company. Workers naturally resent this and

lose faith in the union.

a contract, it becomes the job of the union to “service” the contract.

In other words, it becomes the union’s responsibility to make sure both

the company and the workers follow the contract. Through bargaining and

contract enforcement the union becomes removed from the workers — it

becomes a third party. Instead of the union being the collective voice

of the workers, the union becomes an organization which speaks on the

workers’ behalf.This is no small difference. Prior to the introduction

of contracts, the union had to organize every new worker hired onto the

job. The union had to have a shop floor presence. Older employees needed

to explain the benefits of organization to new hires if the union was to

survive and grow. Dues were collected on the shop floor, in the break

room, or in the union hall. The union was the workers. Contracts ended

that. The union became an agreement.The notion of the union as a third

party is reinforced through “payroll deductions” for dues. In most union

shops, dues are taken directly from the workers’ paychecks. Instead of

paying dues directly to a delegate or a steward — a real person — dues

are paid to “the union.” When this occurs, the union stops being “real,”

it’s merely an abstract organization workers fund through their

paychecks. Automatic dues deductions also make it less likely the union

will encourage workers to strike. If a shop strikes, the workers stop

getting paychecks and the money used to support the union bureaucracy

stops flowing in.

the job: As a result of the points mentioned above, workers have found

contracts to be a repressive force in the workplace. Workers who founded

unions through the use of direct action find that after a contract is

signed, their unions are contractually forced to stamp out direct action

when it occurs. When wildcats occur, the bosses are quick to call in

union representatives who order the workers back onto the job. It

doesn’t matter how badly management is treating a worker or what policy

the workers are being forced to endure, all the union can do is to tell

the workers to file a grievance or wait until the next contract comes

along. Maybe then the union will get around to fixing whatever problem

the workers are having
As a result of this, workers come to resent union

bureaucrats and even the union itself. Shop stewards and committeemen

only enforce the contract, they stop fighting for the workers they’re

supposed to represent. The union is just like a second boss. Management

has their rules and the union has its rules. In both instances, workers

feel powerless to change their conditions.Along these same lines, the

contract limits the ability of workers to engage in solidarity. Say the

shop down the road goes on strike. They’re demanding higher wages,

better conditions, and that 100 new positions be opened to lighten the

load for the current employees in the shop. It’s very simple to

understand that better conditions in the shop down the road (and the

other shop down the road and the other shop in the next state
) will

lead to better conditions across the industry. In the long run, that’ll

mean better conditions in your shop too. And even more than

self-interest, you know what it’s like to face pushy bosses, overwork,

low pay, and disrespect. You want to support your fellow workers. You

hope they’d do the same for you. You and your co-workers want to engage

in a solidarity strike to support the workers down the road, but the

contract contains a no-strike clause. Or say you and your co-workers are

sick of your sons and daughters be dragged off to fight in a rich man’s

war. You want a political strike demanding an end to whatever unjust war

the bosses have gotten us into this time. Can’t do that under a

no-strike clause, either.The other thing bosses will do is to have more

than one contract in a shop. Or, when a company runs more than one

plant, the bosses will make sure the contracts in each shop expire at

different times. The logic here is simple: management has used the

contract to ensure workers will not strike at the same time. Before

contracts, all workers in a shop or in a single company talked to one

another. If there was an issue affecting the shop, it made sense for all

workers to strike together.With contracts, the bosses got smart. Let’s

use the example of a meat packing company. In the meat industry, the

workers on the “killing floor” are very powerful. It’s a dangerous job

and without that particular group of workers, production stops. In this

particular company, there’s only one plant to slaughter cattle and

another plant to process and can the meat. Hoping to cut down on the

militancy of the killing floor workers, the company offers them better

wages if they accept a five year contract. The processing plant is only

offered a three year contract. When the three year contracts expire, the

processing workers want to strike, but they know that without the

killing floor workers going out, the company will just outsource

processing to an outside plant. So they settle for lower wages. Then,

when it comes time to negotiate a contract for the killing floor

workers, the boss tells them, “The processing workers have accepted

lower wages, you’ll have to as well.” And, of course, the processing

plant workers couldn’t strike even if they wanted to, but they feel

they’ve been abandoned by the killing floor workers in the first place.

In the end, the only person who has benefitted from the contract is the

boss.To put it simply: contracts limit the ability for workers to act a

class. Bosses know this. Contracts are used to keep workers divided and

as a way to destroy the natural bonds of solidarity that exist between

working people.

workplace, only the threat of worker action keeps the boss in line. The

same is true for contracts. Simply put: when contracts are in effect,

the bosses will try to break them if they think they can get away with

it. Only the militancy of workers can prevent this. But here’s the rub:

As we’ve outlined bove, contracts, by their nature, seek to repress

militancy and enforce a “labor peace.” When they succeed in doing this

(repressing the threat of direct action in the workplaces), the bosses

will (1) simply ignore or try to slyly undermine the contract or (2)

demand concessions when negotiations come around.The example of the US

auto industry illustrates this trend. In the 1930s a massive surge in

worker militancy led to the creation of a powerful union, the United

Auto Workers. The auto companies, recognizing the how quick their

workers were to take industrial action, negotiated very generous

contracts with the UAW. This continued for numerous decades. However, in

each contract, the bosses agreed to higher wages and better conditions,

but in return secured more and more guarantees from the union that the

workers would ‘stay in line.’ No-strike clauses and binding grievance

procedure were inserted into the contract. However, by putting the union

in charge of ensuring workers wouldn’t ‘act outside the contract,’ it

sapped the spirit of militancy from the workforce. The end result of

this was that by the 1970s, the union, by trading militancy for the

security of a contract, had weakened itself. The bosses realized this

and used any and every opportunity to secure concessions from the

workers. Since that time, the workers have lost ground in every single

contract the UAW has signed.

The point of all this being: while contracts do cement gains in the

medium and short-term, in the long-term the outlook is not so rosy.

IWW-specific failures of the contract model

While we’ve covered in great detail our objections to the manner in

which business unions employ contracts, we would like to spend a moment

on the specific issues that occur when the IWW signs contracts.

Contracts, by their very nature, remove struggle from the workplace

floor. This has a number of consequences. First, it creates a

specialized class of negotiators and contract enforcers. In the case of

the business unions we see the development of a paid bureaucracy who

“services” the contract. In the IWW, “super activists” step up to fill

these roles. In both cases, militants are taken off the floor and

elevated into a specialized status. This may at first appear to be a

smart choice by the union. After all, wouldn’t you want the most

outspoken, dedicated workers to be the ones who would deal with

management on a day-to-day basis? However, these ex-shopfloor militants

— who may have previously been leaders of direct actions — become

invested in protecting both the contract and framework of contractual

negotiation. All of this leads to a centralization of both knowledge and

power within the union. Predictably, this comes at the expense of

democracy, militancy, and rank-and-file control. In a word, workers

become alienated from the union.

We would like to emphasize that very often, and especially in the case

of the IWW, this is a very slow, subtle process. Steps taken in the

pursuit or legitimacy or “formalizing gains,” which may appear

advantageous in the short-term, can — in the medium and long-term —

force the union to abandon some of our most cherished principles. In the

IWW there is a widespread belief that our professed radicalism and/or

direct democracy will prevent us from being trapped in the framework of

labor law, service unionism, and bureaucracy. However by engaging these

very same means we are conditioning both our leadership and the

rank-and-file to accept a more “traditional” understanding of unionism.

As stated, the process is slow, subtle, and unintentional. As the old

proverb goes, “The path to hell is paved with good intentions.”

Although there is benefit to be found in theorizing on why the IWW falls

short when it comes to maintaining and servicing contract shops, our

beliefs should always be grounded in practical experience. One of the

contributors to this pamphlet works in an IWW contract shop and his

experience their highlights many of the issues this pamphlet seeks to

address. As he tells it, “Nobody working at the shelter when I was hired

(8 workers there) knew we were a union shop. Our contract had already

expired and none of us had heard a word from the union since we worked

there. There is a lot of turnover at the shelter which partially

explains it, but some of the longer term workers had been in the shop

while the contract was in effect and didn’t even know they were in a

union shop. 
I had started talking with one of my coworkers about how we

needed to unionize or try at least rabble rousing and we decided to

contact the IWW. Ironically, before we made contact we found our old and

expired contract behind some junk in the staff closet. 
 The last

contract we negotiated got us some significant gains, both bread and

butter gains in addition to more respect on the job and some more say in

the way it operates. With that being said, it burned out several of our

most militant workers and has left us in a bit of stagnation between

contracts. This last point especially hurts because we constantly have

new workers who aren’t inoculated and educated into the union

(especially during the year that I was gone and seemingly no delegates

kept contact with the shop, leading to the overwhelming majority of them

falling far out of good standing). Overall the IWW has had a mediocre

way of servicing the shop and it remains largely isolated from the

General Membership Branch (and other social service shops). 
 Even some

of the more self proclaimed militant people in my shop have wasted

several months over a wage re-opener that has gone absolutely nowhere.

They have stated that they want to exhaust the official process until we

“resort” to escalation. This is what contracts do. 
 Some of my

coworkers are still excited about the IWW. Some are stagnant and assume

there’s nothing to be done until the next negotiations. Unfortunately

some have either become (or say they feel) alienated from the union (as

a whole and even their own shop).

“The final court of appeals is [always] the picket line”

Section 2: What we do we oppose a “capture the shop” model of

organizing?

Section 3: Practically, what are the success rates of labor board

elections?

Section 4: How do contracts inhibit the revolutionary potential of

the IWW?

In the long term, only the industrial strategy provides the way to true,

unfettered industrial solidarity. As was alluded to in part 2, things

may get tricky in the medium-term, but it will our success in securing

those medium-term goals that will prepare us to really shift the

‘balance of class’ power and create a truly independent and militant

worker’s movement.

beyond simply signing contracts, there are other, more subtle ways, the

IWW has come moved away from it’s revolutionary potential. One, which

we’d like to address here, is the notion of “capturing a shop.” Whether

by Labor Board elections or direct actions, the IWW has employed a

“shop-by-shop” model of organizing to many of our campaigns. The premise

is simple: force the boss to recognize the IWW presence in a single

location and negotiate with the employees to improve conditions and pay.

Once again, on the face, this seems like a reasonable idea. We are a

union with limited resources: it seems logical to focus on one shop,

make gains, and build from there. Yet, the problem with such a model is

that it is constructed for an organization that works very differently

from how the IWW would like to see itself.

Let us elaborate: in the US there are two ways to win formal recognition

of a union at a shop level. A union can either (1) file for and win an

NLRB election or (2) force “voluntary recognition” through the use of

direct action. In either event, it takes a dedicated group of organizers

who are able to overcome the inertia of day-to-day grievances and help

focus struggle onto winning a union. As we all know too well, the boss

has more resources, time, and can fight us tooth and nail, with the

weight of the law on management’s side. The overwhelming majority of all

shop campaigns — business union or IWW — fail for these reasons.

Organizing is hard, the deck is stacked against us, and the system of

gaining recognition — voluntary or otherwise — is a trap.

Even if the IWW gains recognition, a whole new set of problems arise.

The first is simply an issue of power. In many of the industries where

the IWW is active, a single company’s shops can spread throughout a very

large geographic area. In many cases we deal with truly multinational

companies who can easily have thousands of individual shops. If the IWW

strikes one of these, we still hold very little power when 99% of that

company’s workforce is still on the clock. Likewise, if we gain

recognition at a single shop, our ability to make demands is limited by

the simple fact that the company can very easily close down that

particular outlet and still remain profitable. The easy answer to this

is to focus on an employer that only owns one shop. Yet, even this

premise contains many of the same problems. For one, and as the IWW

learned in the New York warehouse campaigns, some employers will

literally go bankrupt before recognizing the union. Two, without the

union spread throughout the entire industry — and the solidarity and

power that comes with it — were only able to make quite meager demands.

The other large problem with the shop-by-shop model is one that we’ve

already touched on, but it’s worth reinforcing. Because we are not a

service union and do employ a large bureaucracy, when we capture a

single shop — and if we want to have any hope of keeping it — the best

militants end up becoming administrative machinery (bureaucracy) of

keeping the shop together, dealing with the technical aspects, and

trying to constantly reorganize the shop to fend off attacks by the

boss. That leaves little room for developing new organizers to spread

the struggle, agitate across the industry or workforce, and to organize

around broader working class demands.

It sounds easier than it is. When we organize around grievances they

tend to be either short-term winnable gains, which organization rapidly

dissipates after the win, or longer-term problems that we lack the

strength to challenge. Over the past decade of direct unionist

struggles, the trajectory of these struggles is roughly this. Workers

get agitated around some issues. We develop organizers and build a

committee, the workers rally around the grievance and win or lose. The

committee falls apart with either concessions or the crackdown, but we

gain committed organizers (especially when the campaign fails!). Because

of this there is a strong pull to try and go for the whole shop and win

recognition, either by slipping into contractualism or hedging bets and

demanding the boss recognize us.

Without real power in the workplace, we lack the ability to effectively

challenge the boss, and make the changes necessary to keep workers

active in the struggle and the union. By trying to take the shop, we do

two things: we act before we’ve build real power, and we give a false

sense of reassurance that when we take the shop we’ll be able to get

what we want. Without years of struggle, the level of preparation,

unity, and solidarity necessary to keep a shop just isn’t there.

Campaigns tend to crumble when the boss drives a wedge into these

contradictions, and the workers weren’t prepared for it. If we do manage

to win, usually by elections notably, organization crumbles as everyone

expects the union to act for them no matter how much appeals to

democracy and “you are the union” there are. This is because the

shop-by-shop struggle pushes workers in these directions.

In some cases we’ve won shops and kept power. We did it because we had

tight committed organizers and workers who were in it to win come hell

or high water. These campaigns too tend to fail. Mostly the IWW

organizes in shops of less than 100 people. In these small shops, and in

the industries most people work in today, individual shops have very

little power. A strike in a restaurant for example is likely to have

little economic impact, and if we put an owner out of business the

workers are in a tough position. In large firms, capital has grown

globally to such strength that even extended strikes in isolated shops

will have little impact on the long term survival of these capitalists.

A large part of our power comes not just from our economic impact, but

our ability to mobilize the community around our demands, and threaten

to spread the struggle beyond our shops.

For example organizing at one hospital will never be able to gain the

leverage necessary to win healthcare for all.

The answer to this dilemma lies in going with what we do right, and

abandoning what we do poorly. In grievance struggles, we are good at

winning them and at building organizers out of the process. We are bad

at holding onto shops, organizing them, and extending our gains. The

alternative to the shop-by-shop model is to focus on developing a base

of organizers across industries, and building capacity before making

moves to win shops. Through engaging an industry, we can elevate the

level of struggle around winnable grievances under the radar of the

boss, and build organizers and class consciousness. We can patiently

innoculate and build unity that will be an antidote to bosses

favoritism, false gifts, and personal attacks. By not biting off more

than we can chew, we’ll end up having our fill at the collective table.

IWhat we intend to argue is that IWW should instead move toward an

industrial model that will win gains not in a single shop or even a

single large company, but across an entire industry.

Networks of militants who lead direct actions in their own workplaces

w/o seeking recognition while recruiting new members to the IWW. Once

we’ve reached a critical mass, begin to push for industry-wide changes.

Move away from GMBs to IUBs – industrial delegates

7) Industrial Strategy: Instead of hoping to “capture” a workplace, the

industrial strategy seeks to build a network of militants across an

industry. These militants will agitate amongst their co-workers and lead

direct actions over specific grievances in their own workplaces.

However, the goal will not be union recognition from a single boss.

Instead, the goal of the actions is to build up leadership and

consciousness amongst other workers. Once a ‘critical mass’ of workers

are experienced union members, the focus will be on large scale

industrial actions that address issues of wages and conditions across

entire regions or even whole countries.

Direct unionism, at its very core, rejects contractual organizing. In

our history the IWW has proposed many alternatives to contractualism —

minority unionism and solidarity unionism being two of the most notable

— but in practice even these anti-contractual concepts have been used in

contractual campaigns. It is our intent that direct unionism should not

suffer the same fate.

an argument against contracts that I think is more bread and butter: the

IWW sucks at administering contracts. We can and should criticize

service unionism, but there’s also an important distinction between the

service union model executed well (within/according to its limited

criteria) and that model executed badly. I think we’re pretty bad

executing this model. That’s a good thing over all, or the result of a

good thing – us being volunteer driven and not having professional staff

– but it’s an important fact

Part 3: Why organize without contracts?

contract model ¶ Although there is benefit to be found in theorizing on

why the IWW falls short when it comes to maintaining and servicing

contract shops, our beliefs should always be grounded in practical

experience. One of the contributors to this pamphlet works in an IWW

contract shop and his experience their highlights many of the issues

this pamphlet seeks to address. As he tells it, “Nobody working at the

shelter when I was hired (8 workers there) knew we were a union shop.

Our contract had already expired and none of us had heard a word from

the union since we worked there. There is a lot of turnover at the

shelter which partially explains it, but some of the longer term workers

had been in the shop while the contract was in effect and didn’t even

know they were in a union shop. 
I had started talking with one of my

coworkers about how we needed to unionize or try at least rabble rousing

and we decided to contact the IWW. Ironically, before we made contact we

found our old and expired contract behind some junk in the staff closet.


 The last contract we negotiated got us some significant gains, both

bread and butter gains in addition to more respect on the job and some

more say in the way it operates. With that being said, it burned out

several of our most militant workers and has left us in a bit of

stagnation between contracts. This last point especially hurts because

we constantly have new workers who aren’t inoculated and educated into

the union (especially during the year that I was gone and seemingly no

delegates kept contact with the shop, leading to the overwhelming

majority of them falling far out of good standing). Overall the IWW has

had a mediocre way of servicing the shop and it remains largely isolated

from the General Membership Branch (and other social service shops). 


Even some of the more self proclaimed militant people in my shop have

wasted several months over a wage re-opener that has gone absolutely

nowhere. They have stated that they want to exhaust the official process

until we “resort” to escalation. This is what contracts do. 
 Some of my

coworkers are still excited about the IWW. Some are stagnant and assume

there’s nothing to be done until the next negotiations. Unfortunately

some have either become (or say they feel) alienated from the union (as

a whole and even their own shop).“The final court of appeals is [always]

the picket line”

— potential for use of the union bug (part 1 e-mail discussion)

When contracts are in effect, the bosses will try to break them if they

think they can get away with it and it’s only the militancy of workers

that prevent this. But here’s the rub: contracts, by their nature, seek

to repress militancy and enforce a “labor peace.” When the succeed in

doing this, the bosses will ignore the contract or demand concessions

when negotiations come around. So while contracts do cement gains in the

medium and short-term, in the long-term the outlook is not so rosy.

In the long term, only the industrial strategy provides the way to true,

unfettered industrial solidarity. As was alluded to in part 2, things

may get tricky in the medium-term, but it will our success in securing

those medium-term goals that will prepare us to really shift the

‘balance of class’ power and create a truly independent and militant

worker’s movement.

Only through such a process of experience and dialog will we be able to

prove to ourselves and those we organize that despite the siren song of

the contract is a dead end to building true workers’ power.

“A CIO contract is guarantee against strikes”

Britain –

In Britain, workplaces which a union is recognized as a bargaining agent

of the workforce (since labor law does not allow for collective

contracts in the American sense of the word), face many of the same

obstacles as contracts shops in America. For one, any strikes have to be

balloted for in advance and the boss has a minimum of seven days notice

before industrial action can legally begin. If wildcats occur, workers

can be legally sacked. The union, for its part, has to “repudiate” the

strike and no union funds or support can be offered to workers. If the

union does not repudiate any unofficial strikes, the union’s funds can

be seized and its assets frozen. Officials can face jail time. This

doesn’t mean that wildcats don’t occur and that they may even be

encouraged by local officials. In fact, some of the most successful

strike in modern British history — the Visteon oil workers’ strike of

2009 to mention just one — have been wildcats. However, when the

aforementioned Visteon workers took such action, they received no

support from their national union.

When balloting does occur for industrial action, workers have ballots

sent to their houses. Even at this early stage, then, the struggle is

de-collectivized, individualized. Such a process also gives bosses space

for legalistic maneuvering. The Christmas 2009 British Airways dispute

contains all the classic aspects of company manipulation and is a

daunting reminder of the dangers of unions accepting a legalized

approach to strike action. Set off BA’s plans to unilaterally reduce

staffing levels, nine-tenths of cabin crew members voted to strike over

the Christmas holiday. British Airways sought, and received, an

injunction against the strike on the grounds balloting irregularities.

Had the workers been organizing the strike by votes of mass assemblies,

free from the constraints of labor-relations regulations, the strike

would have gone forward. The airline might have still sought an

injunction, but the workers would have already been operating outside

the bounds of labor law and would be in a much better position to

organize in an extra-legal manner to allow for a successful strike.

Instead, they belonged to a union that had gone through all the proper

steps of legal certification and had followed the legally prescribed

balloting procedure. Having bought into a legalized organizing process

and given certain ‘privileges’ for doing so (i.e. being allowed to

represent a particular workforce), the union was in no position to

encourage its membership to break the law and push forward with its

overwhelming wish: an all out strike against a drastic cuts to their

working conditions.

Of course, other similarities exist that we don’t have to go into here:

solidarity strikes are illegal; the severe division of workplaces into

(often competing) unions; legalized, individualized grievance

procedures; closed shops are illegal (much like in American

‘right-to-work’ states)

[1] If you’re unfamiliar with how the IWW organizes we recommend you

contact the IWW Organizing Department to schedule an organizer training.

During a training, IWW-certified trainers will come to your town to show

you how organize your workplace. In the US, the Organizing Department

can be reached at (970) 903–8721 (this number was current as of Summer

2009). You can also go to http://www.iww.org/en/organize to find out

more. If you live outside of the US, go to www.iww.org to find out how

to reach an IWW organizer in your country.

[2] A more complete list of direct action tactics will hopefully soon be

available in another pamphlet by the same authors.

[3] For an explanation of “vehicle of struggle” see the introduction to

part one, section three “Are we trying to build a union?”

[4] We apologize about all the complex annoying language in this

paragraph. We’ll try not to let it happen again.

[5] This pamphlets intentionally stresses the ‘here and now,’ but if we

reach a point where the IWW is a majority presence in a shop,

recognition won’t go much further than there being a recognized IWW

delegate who is management’s “first point of call” when it come to shop

conditions. The rep — who will always be a member of the staff — will be

limited by the fact all decisions must still be put to a vote of the

entire workforce (with the exception of scabs, management stools, etc).

[6] Once again, we apologize for the language in this paragraph. For

clarification, in this sentence, “capital” refers to all business owners

(capitalists) as a class.

[7] “We try not to overemphasize formalism. In other words, we don’t

judge a struggle simply on its particular form — be it the union form,

the workplace assembly form, or a “workers council” form. No form is

perfect and the content and the goals of a struggle must be taken into

account. In the final analysis, the goal of direct unionism is to create

‘practiced democracy, self-activity, and self-leadership’ within the

context of a ‘participatory, collective, and class-conscious proletarian

struggle.’ What this struggle may look like is going to vary from place

to place and time to time. The goal, however, never changes”

[8] http://www.iww.org/PDF/IndustrialWorker/IWJuly09.pdf

[9] Punching Out, a collection of Glaberman’s writings edited by

Staughton Lynd, and is available from Charles H. Kerr press:

http://www.charleshkerr.com/book/32/