đž Archived View for library.inu.red âş file âş kevin-doyle-parliament-or-democracy.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:50:48. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄď¸ Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Parliament or Democracy? Author: Kevin Doyle Date: 1998 Language: en Topics: Parliament, democracy, social democracy, Left Electoralism, history Source: Retrieved on 3rd June 2021 from http://struggle.ws/once/pd_intro.html
From the 1850s onwards, against a background of great new wealth in
society and a working class that was more independent and resourceful,
the âproblem of democracyâ became urgent for the rich and powerful. In
general wealth was rising throughout society, but so was the greed of
those who owned the new factories, mines and plantations. The key
question was: what was to be done about the general demand for
democracy, and about the incessant clamour for political rights which,
during the revolutions of 1848, had almost got completely out of hand?
Maintaining their privilege and wealth while generally conceding a
semblance of democracy was the principal aim of the ârich and
privilegedâ during the second half of the 19^(th) century. Parliament is
a means of diffusing democracy, of channelling real struggles into a
safe dead-end. Time and time again it has become a graveyard for the
workersâ movement.
The French Revolution of 1789 put an end to the idea that some people
were born to rule. In only a short number of years one of the oldest and
most powerful monarchies in Europe was swept away. In its place came the
idea of legal equality and individual rights as set out in the
âDeclaration of the Rights of Man and the Citizen.â
The basis of these new rights, established on foot of a great social
upheaval, was the real hallmark of the French Revolution since it was
accepted, from that point on, that laws and how they were made were the
expression of the âgeneral willâ. As such these laws could be made and
unmade as that âgeneral willâ was discerned. This was the real break
with the past.
At the time of the French Revolution the idea of the âgeneral willâ was
still new in politics. Even so the implications for the future were not
difficult to make out. Sixty years earlier, in England, during the Civil
War the very same issues had come to the fore. If the monarchy was to be
dispensed with, what type of society should replace it? What exactly
constituted the âgeneral willâ? And, as importantly, in whose service
was its rule to be applied?
During the Putney Debates, the anti-Royalist forces who had fought to
depose Charles II argued over these very issues. The principal leaders
of the anti-Royalist movement, men such as Oliver Cromwell and others,
were definite that the Kingâs arbitrary rule should end. But, equally,
they were clear that the running of society could not be left to just
anyone. The Kingâs right of power had rested on his birthright. Now that
this was gone, a new form of distinction was needed, they argued, lest
the rule of society fall into the hands of the common people. That new
distinction was to be property. As Cromwellâs general, Henry Ireton, put
it:
âI think that no person hath a right to an interest or share in
disposing of the affairs of the Kingdom... that have not a permanent
fixed interest in the Kingdom.â [1]
But this view was not shared by others who had also fought the King. The
Civil War had thrown up many groupings. Some, such as the Levellers,
were conscious of the social conditions of the day. Others still, the
Diggers, had seized un-worked land and declared it their own by virtue
of the plants they had put on it and the labour they had expended. Such
groupings were profoundly stirred by the struggle against the autocrat
Charles II. They were anti-authoritarian and viewed matters differently
from the likes of Cromwell. The well-known Leveller, Thomas
Rainsborough, countered Ireton with:
âI think that the poorest ... in England hath a life to live as the
greatest...and therefore ... every man that is to live under a
government ought first by his own consent to put himself under that
government.â [2]
But this idea that everyone, irrespective of individual wealth, was
entitled to a say in the running of society had dangerous implications.
Implications that directly threatened the interests of the âmen of
propertyâ and the rich. Ireton again:
âBy the same right of natureĂ by which you say a man hath an equal with
another of the choosing of him that govern him, by the same right of
nature he hath the same right in any goods he sees.â [3]
The central matter being âgoodsâ. English society in the era of the
Civil War was a much poorer society than it is today but, relative to
the population of the time, there was still an abundance of wealth. That
wealth was not shared equally. There was a massive disparity in who
owned what, a major source of grievance as the Digger, Winstanley,
noted:
âAnd this is the bondage that the poor complain of, that they are kept
poor by their brethren in a land where there is so much plenty for
everyone.â [4]
So, in the English Civil War, the abolition of the rule of the King had
raised almost immediately a more intractable problem. If full equality
was conceded wouldnât the privilege of the rich be brought to an end?
After all, it was Aristotle, thousands of years earlier, who had pointed
out the most glaring fact: âThe rich are few and the poor are many.â In
any straight forward count (or referendum) the interests of the rich
would be swamped alongside the priorities of the more numerous poor. So
was born the âproblem of democracyâ.
The immediate solution employed by the rich during the English Civil War
was, of course, force of arms. This was the fate suffered by democrats
such as the Diggers and the Levellers, both of which were dispersed
using military means. It was âpropertiedâ men such as Cromwell and
Ireton who benefited most. They ruled through a new Parliament, and had
greatly increased power, while the poor suffered on. As an observer
noted5 in his journey across England in 1660:
âThe island ... is ... governed by the influence of the sort of people
that live plentifully and at ease upon their rents extracted from the
toil of their tenants and servants ... each of whom within the bounds of
his own estate acts the prince; he is purely absolute, his servants and
labourers are in the nature of his vassals; his tenants indeed are free,
but in the nature of subjects.â [5]
Like the English Civil War, the French Revolution would have a limited
effect on how society was organised in the short term. Though the French
monarchy was fatally weakened and the ârule of lawâ was established, the
real beneficiaries were the emerging bourgeoisie. These, the merchants
and bankers of France, had been one of the motive forces in the fight
against the monarchy. They had provided the ideas and reasoning for the
Revolution. For too long they had suffered unjust taxes, levied on them
by a corrupt King. In the aftermath of the French Revolution, with their
hands on the reins of power, they remade the laws in their own interest,
to benefit trade and those who traded.
But the French Revolution was also crucially different â in a way that
would have important overall consequences. Firstly, it âwas alone of all
revolutions which preceded and followed it a mass social revolutionâ.[6]
The masses themselves had been one of the prime forces in its success.
At crucial periods in the struggle for power they had, by their very
presence, pushed events forward. This had struck a chord with the
downtrodden everywhere, but it also taught a crucial lesson: where
reform from above proved fruitless, revolution from below could work. In
part, as a reflection of this, political consciousness rose across
Europe.
The French Revolution was particularly important for a second reason. It
occurred as the very early stages of the industrial revolution were
getting underway. Overall, wealth in society was increasing. In France
and England it is estimated that societyâs wealth doubled in the 18^(th)
century. But, in the next fifty years, as machinery and labour were
harnessed, the rate of increase in wealth accelerated rapidly.
Beginning first in England, where conditions were most favourable,
industrialisation spread relatively quickly to the continent of Europe.
By the 1840s âthe actual industrial transformation of the non-English
speaking world was still modest ... a little more than one hundred miles
of railway line in the whole of Spain, Portugal, Scandinavia,
Switzerland and the entire Balkan peninsula...â [7] But, even so, âthe
actual rise in production and exports were giganticâ. [8]
What this meant for the ârich and privilegedâ was a vast increase in
their wealth. How vast is often not appreciated. The historian, Eric
Hobsbawm, gives one indication with his explanation for the dramatic
rise in railway construction that occurred at this time in Britain. In
just twenty years railway construction there jumped from just a few
dozen miles of line (in the 1820s) to 4,500 miles of line by 1840, to
23,550 miles by 1850. Where, he asks, did the money come from, for such
endeavours? His answer is instructive: âThe fundamental fact about
Britain in the first few generations of the Industrial Revolution was
that the comfortable and rich classes accumulated income so fast and in
such quantities as to exceed all available possibilities of spending and
investmentâ.[9] Hence, the âspeculative frenziesâ concentrating on
railway stock investments which hit England in 1835â7 and again in
1844â7, known with hindsight as ârailway maniaâ.
Yet, this enviable predicament contrasted sharply with the lot of the
multitude whose role it was to labour for such enterprises. For them
â...the transition to the new economy created misery and discontent...â
[10] Those without property â those who, in effect, became known as the
proletariat â didnât immediately take to the new order. âLabour had to
learn to work in a manner suited to industry... It also had to learn to
be responsive to monetary incentive...â [11] The early generations of
workers didnât find this easy, nor did they like it. There was
considerable resistance.
The solution, notes Hobsbawm, âwas found in a draconian labour
discipline, but above all in a practice where possible of paying labour
so little that it would have to work steadily all through the week in
order to make a minimum income...â [12] that it could survive on. This
often required the whole family to work. Between 1834 and 1839, in the
English cotton mills, of all workers, âone quarter were adult men, one
half women and girls and the balance boys below the age of
eighteen.â[13] By the 1840s, in Western Europe, âthe characteristic
social problems of industrialisation ... the horrors of breakneck
urbanisation ... were commonplace and of serious dimensionsâ.[14]
Small wonder then that Europe was convulsed by revolution in 1848.
Whilst liberals in Italy, France, Hungary and Germany pressed forward
against the continuing power of royalty in their own countries,
independent demands of a serious nature emerged from the âworkers in
Paris and other European citiesâ. Raising the cry for âsocial
revolution, for the Red republicâ their âdemands challenged both
property and the laws of the marketâ. [15]
From the 1850s onwards, against a background of great new wealth in
society and a working class that was more independent and resourceful,
the âproblem of democracyâ became urgent. In general, wealth was rising
throughout society, but so was the greed of those who owned the new
factories, mines and plantations. The key question was: what was to be
done about the general demand for democracy, and about the incessant
clamour for political rights which, during the revolutions of 1848, had
almost got completely out of hand?
This matter weighed heavily on the minds of the ârich and privilegedâ
during this era. Two main positions emerged. On the one hand, there were
people such as Thomas Babington Macaulay who believed that âthe higher
and middling orders are the natural representatives of the human
raceâ.[16] He was concerned about the issue of enfranchising the poor
and property-less. This issue had already come to the fore in Britain
with the rise of the Chartist movement in the 1830s. One of the leading
Chartists, Cobett, had made the important point that the people wanted
the vote âthat it might do some good, that it might better our
situation... and not for the gratification of any abstract ...
whimâ.[17] Macaulay attacked the idea of universal suffrage in this
context. He argued it would lead âto the rich being âpillagedâ ... which
in turn would lead to the destruction of civilisation and a reversion to
barbarism.â[18]
Others were not so obtuse. J.S. Mill, the well known 19^(th) century
liberal philosopher, was among these. He was well aware that times had
changed. He noted that the age had passed âwhen the uninstructed have
faith in the instructedâ[19] with the result that âthe multitude are
without a guide and society is exposed to all the errors and dangersâ.
[20] One of these dangers was social revolution. Mill was well aware
that something had to be done, but also that the clock could not go
backwards.
Not that he was under any illusions: âWe dreaded the ignorance and
especially the selfishness and brutality of the mass.â[21] The lower
orders were, in his eyes, âthe mass of brutish ignoranceâ, âthe common
herdâ or âthe uncultivated herdâ.[22] In contrast, he saw himself and
his ilk as âan endowed class, for the cultivation of learning, and for
diffusing its results among the communityâ.[23] The role of such a class
was clear, he said: âNo government by a democracy ... could rise above a
mediocrity except ... by the council and influence of a more highly
instructed one or few.â[24] The alternative, a meaningful say for the
âcommon herdâ, was inconceivable: âIt is not useful, but hurtful, that
the constitution of the country should declare ignorance to be entitled
to as much political power as knowledge.â[25] A suitable solution then,
in Millâs view, was this: âthe intellectual classes [should] lead the
government, and the government should lead the stupid classes.â[26]
What would, in time, become the modus operandi of parliamentary
democracy everywhere was not in the 1850s immediately practicable. The
natural disadvantage suffered by the âmiddling and higher ordersâ
alongside the âbrutish multitudeâ when it came to the numbers game (âthe
rich are few and the poor are manyâ) was only part of the problem. More
pressing was the different expectations that both sides, rich and poor,
brought to the particular subject of suffrage and its extension.
Mill, once again, was clear in this regard. Democracy was ânot that the
people govern themselves, but that they have the security for good
governmentâ. Such âgood governmentâ already existed in his eyes: this
was parliament. Hobsbawm notes the state of play in Europe in the middle
of the 19^(th) century: The âparliamentary tradition had been
established in virtually all European countries, with the exception of
Russia. In most cases, however, the power of the traditional elite
remained secure if not unchallenged, for parliaments had only nominal
power against the executive, and hence were at best weak influences on
state policy.â [27]
These bald facts about parliament and its irrelevance were widely known
at the time. Those who attended the various parliaments of Europe were,
for the most part, the appointees of the ruling elites throughout Europe
â the various sons of the landed classes and of businessmen, lawyers and
the other professions. This was hardly the democracy that the âstupid
classesâ had in mind. On the contrary, the perception was widespread
that ârule by the peopleâ must mean just that â hence the dangerous
connotations that the word democracy had throughout this period of
history.
Mill and others were very much aware of this difference of
âunderstandingâ between the rich and the poor. It was a major problem.
There was not, in a sense, a âtradition of governanceâ or, as it was
also put, âcommon ground between the rulers and the ruledâ in which both
sides knew their place and lot. Naturally, until such traditions were
established, the vote would have to be withheld or manipulated into
ineffectiveness.
The âqualified voteâ was the means by which this was done. Though not
before another idea â the âweighted voteâ â had been toyed with. This
idea, also developed by Mill, was nothing if not novel:
âIf every ordinary unskilled labourer had one vote, a skilled labourer
ought to have two. A foreman... whose occupation requires something more
of general culture, and some moral as well as intellectual qualities
should perhaps have three. A farmer, manufacturer, or trader... should
have three or four. A member of any profession, requiring... systematic
mental culture... ought to have five or six. A graduate of any
university at least as many.â [28]
In this way the numerical disadvantage of the rich could be mitigated
until such time as the poor had accepted their lot.
But, it was not to be. The qualified vote was far more practical. Using
any arbitrary difference â educational level, possession of property,
religion, race, skin colour, sex, age â access to the vote was
curtailed. Until such time as people showed appropriate âmaturityâ.
Gladstone, the British Prime-minister, spelled out what âmaturityâ
entailed during a debate in 1864 on whether the franchise should be
extended (from 4% to 8% of the population!) The voter, Gladstone said,
should be a person with âself-command, self control, respect for order,
patience under suffering, confidence in the law and regard for
superiors.â [29]
Between 1850 and 1950 then, a period of one hundred years, the main
modern parliamentary democracies emerged in western Europe, north
America, Australia and New Zealand. The situation in these countries
changed from one in which Parliament (or the Legislature as it was also
know) was elected by only 1â5% of the adult population to one in which
almost 100% were involved. This slow pace reflected the overall problems
associated with the building of âtraditions of governanceâ between the
rulers (the ârich and privilegedâ) and the ruled (the labouring
classes), given both the social problems of the era and the continuing
massive inequality. It was however, though slow, a broadly successful
process relying on two important developments apart from the usual
method â repression â for success. These were:
attendant to the interests and agenda of the ârich and privilegedâ.
Maintaining their privilege and wealth while generally conceding a
semblance of democracy was the principal aim of the ârich and
privilegedâ during the second half of the 19^(th) century. But patience
with this was thin on the ground, especially amongst the âmultitudeâ who
were, as always, âtruculent and overly concerned with who got whatâ.
This impatience broke out in full force in France, once again, with the
famous events of the Paris Commune (1871), which, even by todayâs
standard, remain a benchmark in the achievement of democratic practice.
The Commune, though short-lived, broke with the past in a number of
obvious and direct ways that met with the popular mood of revolution.
âThose elected to represent the people were to act as delegates, not as
parliamentary members ... Those elected were subject to recall by the
people, and it was the duty of those elected to report back and remain
in constant contact with the sources of popular sovereignty.â [30] This
was like nothing else that existed in the world at that time. âThe
police was at once stripped of its political attributes ... So were the
officials of all other branches of the Administration. From the members
of the Commune down, the public service had to be done at workmanâs
wages.â[31]
This was a system of administration that led the Commune to institute or
attempt to institute reforms of a very radical nature â worker
co-operatives were formed, plans were drawn up for workersâ control of
industry, special attention was paid to the provision of basic education
for all, to improve the position of women and to provide crèche
facilities for workers (near their place of work).[32] For the time it
was an enormous achievement.
But if the Commune highlighted anything â generally speaking as an
example of democracy it was vilified by the ârich and privilegedâ â it
was that the real threat in society to the continuance of privilege no
longer emanated from the âgeneral massesâ but rather from that more
specific quantity, the working-class. How to deal with this entity was
further complicated by the still small but growing influence of
anarchist and socialist ideas in its ranks. An influence that was
clearly evident in the events of the Commune.
Repression, the immediate solution to the Commune (approximately 25,000
Parisians were slaughtered [33]), would not do in the longer term,
especially given, even in this period, the evident capacity of workers
to articulate and defend their own interests. Indeed, this was perceived
to be the real danger of the emerging working-class â its independence
and autonomy which set it apart from all other producing classes in
society heretofore, most notably the peasantry.
For the ârich and privilegedâ then, containing this new found
independence of workers and, if possible, dispersing it would be crucial
aims in the general struggle against democracy. Unless this was done a
society more technologically based than ever before would, in time,
become dangerously vulnerable to its most important of constituents â
its workers. Even in the late 19^(th) century, the direction of economic
development was pointing to this worst of scenarios, where, irrespective
of the interests of the rich, workers might be powerful enough to
implement democracy anyway.
What was confirming a still small but growing number of workers in such
dangerous âdelusionsâ was the very process of industrial struggle itself
which became an important feature as the 19^(th) century continued on
into the 20^(th). In confronting the owners of industry, workers had,
right from the beginning, very little to rely upon. Against the brute
force and superior material resources of the wealthy, workers had only
organisation and solidarity to hold them together â this they used to
full effect.
By forming themselves into unions and syndicates (organisations that
were built systematically throughout this period) workers were able to
use their industrial power to full effect. But there was, most
importantly, an added bonus. Unions and syndicates were in their own
right âschools of democracyâ and political learning. Not only did
workers became politicised by getting involved, but also by being part
of a union, workers were given valuable lessons in democratic
administration. As if this was not bad enough, it was through such
involvement that workers were â when successful â confirmed in that most
dangerous of ideas: that by their own efforts and organisation they
could alleviate their exploitation. An idea which, if left unchecked,
could be the basis for far more substantial undertakings.
Industrial struggle then was a crucial means by which a revolutionary
consciousness was developing among the working-class. The practical
political experience being gained there was also influencing the wider
struggle for democratic reform. In a similar way, the wider struggle for
democracy was also influencing the demands in the workplace. A feature
that was clearly evident in the âproposalâ put forward by coal workers
in the Rhondda Valley of Wales in 1912:
âOur only concern is to see to it, that those who create the value
receive it ... Today the shareholders own and rule the coal fields. They
own and rule them mainly through paid officials. The men of the mines
are surely as competent to elect these, as shareholders who may never
have seen a colliery. To have a vote in determining who shall be your
fireman, manager, inspector, etc. is to have a vote in determining the
conditions which rule your working life. On that vote will depend in a
large measure your safety of life and limb, of your freedom from
repression by petty bosses, and would give you an intelligent interest
in and control over your conditions of work.â[34]
Such ideas were indeed dangerous. The notion that democracy should be a
part of work and the workplace as much as it should be a part of any
other aspect of life directly challenged the rule of the boss.
Particularly so when married to notions of industrial strength and union
solidarity which were developing at this time. In this context it was
crucial for the ârich and privilegedâ to divert the political
aspirations of workers away from the industrial arena and towards some
more benign institution. Parliament was custom built for this job.
Alone on the left, anarchists signalled the danger which the lure of the
Parliament would in time become. One the one hand there was the crucial
question: what could Parliament actually achieve or change given that it
had only ânominal powersâ? What would be the point in gaining control of
it, if this control could effect little real change?
Though these questions were very important, they were accompanied by a
more general debate about the nature of democracy and the role of the
State. The real division of the day was between two views. Between that
which saw âthe Stateâ as a beneficial agent in society and that (held by
anarchists and some marxists) which saw it, on the contrary, as an
impediment to social and economic progress of any substantial kind.
The burgeoning social reform movement of the era, which in time would be
dominated by the various Labour and Socialist parties of the world, was
the principal advocate of the idea that âthe Stateâ could be used to
benefit workers and the disenfranchised generally. Lassalle, the
founding father of the German Social Democratic Party (GSDP), held that
social improvement of any substantial kind could only come about from
State intervention. This was the âgreat prizeâ to be had if workers and
their representatives played the game of Parliament. Towards this end,
Lassalle urged the German workers âto look [neither] to the left nor to
the right and to be deaf to everything except universal franchise and
the secret ballotâ.[35]
Lassalle was no exception in holding this view. In Britain, the Fabians,
a formative force in the Labour Party, had a similar outlook, believing
that âthe State was fundamentally neutral ... It could be used to hinder
progress or ... to further the evolution of humanity towards its
collectivist goals. The problem was merely which class was in control of
its function...â[36] As they saw it, âthe state machine of army, police
and law courts âwill continue to be used against the people by [the
rich] classes until it is used by the people against the [the rich]
classes...â [37]
The anarchist view, however, was quite different, and, as time would
tell, more realistic. As the anarchists pointed out, âthe Stateâ, in
essence, was a chain of command. Democratic practices animated none of
its many segments and sections. The Parliament, moreover, was but a
minor part of any Government. And the Government was but a minor part of
a much wider body that also included the army, the police and judiciary.
All of which were authoritarian in terms of structure and ethos. How
could such bodies be used to benefit society at large?
The argument put by Lassalle and others was that if a more âenlightenedâ
or âcompassionateâ leadership took the helm, more beneficial ends could
be achieved. But the anarchist view rejected this. Not because they
doubted either the âcompassionâ or âenlightenmentâ of Lassalle, though
it was questionable, but because, as they argued, authoritarian
institutions could not be used to bring about democratic objectives
(i.e. policies that would lead to wealth distribution, the key issue,
could not be brought about by a minority, no matter how well
intentioned. Rather the active and democratic involvement of all of
society was required to achieve such an end.)
For anarchists then, the views and beliefs of reformers were not
decisive. What would determine the outcome was the political structures
used to bring about change. For the anarchists âthe Stateâ was not
neutral. It was authoritarian and undemocratic as befitted its purpose.
Lassalle, as the anarchists saw it, would not change the direction of
Government or âthe Stateâ if he was elected. Rather it would change him.
He would become authoritarian and self-serving as befitted the
institution he was being empowered to run.
Time would tell who was right.
Meanwhile, the real problem remained. The crucial issue for the ârich
and privilegedâ was how to concede a semblance of democracy while
keeping the mass of people as far removed from the levers of power as
was practically possible. In this way the business of making money could
be got on with, while the demands for a meaningful democracy were
diverted into a cul de sac.
Parliament, as stated above, was the method of choice. It had nominal
powers and concerned itself with the mundane. The real issues in society
â the accumulation of wealth by a few, the massive exploitation of
labour, the draconian rule of the boss in the workplace â hardly graced
its doorstep. Therein lay its beauty. But therein also lay its weakness.
The gap between the institutions of power â the State and Government â
and the huge numbers of people living in poverty was massive in the last
half of the 19^(th) century and early 20^(th). The prestige of
parliament was low. As an institution it was viewed with suspicion, and
as a plaything for the rich. How, it was asked, could such an
institution bring about fundamental reform? Or, for that matter, a major
redistribution of wealth?
Throughout the period this was an important limitation â in most
countries. In order to channel the broader demands for democracy and
political rights in a safer direction, it was necessary in the first
place to build up the perception that âParliamentâ was democracy in
action.
Similarly, while suffrage was gradually conceded, it was done so in a
reluctant and strategic way. Extensions of voting rights were met with
expressions of âgrave concern for the future of societyâ. In turn, the
âstupid classesâ, women or black people â anyone whose turn it was â
were chastised with: Were they capable of understanding political
issues? Could they be objective? Would it mean the end of society as it
was then known?
These questions were debated intensely during the era of reform
(1850â1950) that culminated in the establishment of the main modern
parliamentary democracies. But, from the very beginning, as a general
process reform proceeded furthest and with greatest speed in the
countries of the so-called âNew Worldâ. These states â the USA, Canada,
New Zealand and Australia â extended the popular franchise quickly, in
part because of their special circumstances. Being countries that were
built up on the theft of land (from their indigenous peoples) they
commanded greater loyalty from their (usually) white citizenry than was
possible in Europe itself. A loyalty that was, in effect, a further
safeguard to the economic interests of the ârich and privilegedâ.
The general process of extending suffrage to âthe massesâ was perceived
to be dangerous, and so it was. For this very reason it could not have
proceeded successfully without substantial participation from below.
This participation was provided by the emerging âparliamentary
socialistâ movement which, from early days, had a view of social change
and reform not radically different from that which was tolerable to the
ârich and privilegedâ.
There were two important and essential components to this. Firstly, as
was mentioned above, the âparliamentary socialistsâ saw the State and
its role as all important. Leaving aside the objections of the
anarchists and some marxists, they viewed âthe Stateâ with a degree of
respect that bordered on awe. In many respects the parliamentary
socialists were more attached to the idea of âthe Stateâ than the very
capitalists who had relied upon it, time and time again, as a means of
repression. They saw control of âthe Stateâ and its chain of command as
all important and a desirable goal in its own right.
Secondly, however, there was the question of the âmultitudeâ and what
role they should have in any future society. Were they to be
participants, citizens who were active in bringing about change or were
they to be simply people who were called upon to vote every few years â
with little other input? Which was it to be: active and participatory or
passive and in the background? Here the views of the ârich and
privilegedâ and the parliamentary socialists also coincided.
At one level there was disdain. Beatrice Webb, a member of the Fabians
and a founder member of the British Labour Party, âwas horrified at the
immorality and mental dullness of the lower orders. At the turn of the
century she noted, âTo us, public affairs seem gloomy; the middle
classes are materialistic, and the working classes stupid, and in large
sections sottish, with no interest except in racing odds.â [38]
At another level however there was doubt about the political capacity of
the working-class. The Fabians in general were influential in the
founding of the British Labour Party, but they could not imagine workers
originating political ideas of their own. âThe utmost function that can
be allotted to a mass meeting [of workers] in a democracy is the
ratification or rejection of a policy already prepared for it.â [39] A
view that was also held by Eduard Bernstein [40] , a key figure in the
GSPD, and also, interestingly, by the Russian revolutionary, Lenin, who
had noted that workers were only capable of âtrade union
consciousnessâ.[41]
Nevertheless, the growth of the âparliamentary socialistâ movement in
the latter part of the 19^(th) century and the beginning of the 20^(th)
was meteoric. Across Europe, in South America and in Australia socialist
parties were formed with the expressed aim of taking power.
Nowhere was the growth more impressive than in Germany. The GSPD
âincreased its vote from 125,000 in 1871 to 1.4 million in 1890 (20 per
cent of the total vote) and to 4.2 million in 1912 (35 per cent of the
total vote). Similar dramatic increases in the socialist vote occurred
elsewhere ... Social Democrats obtained 37 percent of the vote in
Finland in 1907, 40 per cent in Austria in 1919, 30 per cent in Belgium
in 1925 and 46 per cent in Denmark by 1935.â [42] In 1910 the first
elected socialist government in the world came to power in Australia.
These results were indeed dramatic, an indication no doubt of the desire
in this period for real and substantial change, or wealth distribution.
It seemed as if great things were in the offing, a view enthusiastically
voiced by Frederick Engels in 1895. Engels, co-author with Marx of the
âCommunist Manifestoâ, could only marvel at the growth of the German
SPD. He seemed to believe that all things would fall before the emerging
giant of âparliamentary socialismâ :
Its growth proceeds as spontaneously , as steadily, as irrepressibly,
and at times as tranquilly as a natural process. All Government
intervention has proved powerless against it ...If it continues in this
fashion, by the end of the century we shall ...grow into the decisive
power in the land, before which all powers will have to bow, whether
they like it or not.â[43]
Such a message was also carried faithfully to the working-class
electorate by the thousands of party activists who joined the various
socialist parties during this era, often to the neglect of the trade
union movement they left behind. Keir Hardie, a formative figure in the
Labour Party in Britain, was an early hero in this mould. Hardie
himself, in the personal sense, was no stranger to oppression. Born
illegitimate to a farm servant from Lanarkshire in Scotland, he
criss-crossed England, Scotland and Wales building support for the
parliamentary road to change. He was, in every respect, an eloquent
speaker with, it seemed, a radical vision. He described the type of
socialism he was fighting for as follows:
â...the ugliness and squalor which now meets you at every turn in some
of the most beautiful valleys in the world would disappear, the rivers
would run pure and clear as they did of yore ... and in the winter the
log would glow on the fire the while that the youths and the maidens
made glad the heart with mirth and song, and there would be beauty and
joy everywhere.â[44]
In his eyes the important thing was to participate in the electoral
process. Parliament was a good institution, with real power and the
potential to satisfy the democratic wishes of the people. The problem,
as he saw it, was that rich people kept getting elected to its hallowed
halls. If this could be changed, if people from a working-class
background, who knew what it was like to be poor were elected, then
things could be changed. As went the ditty, popularised among Australian
workers at the beginning of the 20^(th) century to win support for the
Australian Labour Party (ALP)[45]:
âThen keep your heads I say my boys; your comrades in the town.
Will help you get to win the vote and put your tyrant down.
The ballot is the thing, my boys, the ballot is the thing...â
The ballot, in other words, became everything. âUntil the First World
War, Social Democratic Parties worked mainly to obtain democratic
reforms such as the extension of the suffrage, first to males, then to
women, as well as seeking the secret ballot, equal constituencies and
âone man, one voteâ.â[46] Particularly in the northern European
countries this prioritising affected the whole social struggle. Labour
and socialist parties not only set the agenda but also they tended to
foist this agenda, with greater and lesser degrees of success, on the
wider trade union movement.
Thus the real threat posed by industrial based struggles was at first
moderated, then later dispersed. In many countries workers played a
militant part in winning an extension of the franchise. In Belgium,
Austria and Finland among others, general strikes ushered in more
extensive voting rights. But, at the end of the day, the workersâ role
was secondary. Once representation in Parliament was achieved the job of
building socialism fell into the âcapableâ hands of the parliamentary
socialists. A convenient outcome as it turned out.
For the âparliamentary socialistsâ the great prize had always been to
win control of the State. Through enlightened leadership, they argued,
the State could be used for the benefit of society at large. What
happened in reality?
From the earliest days divisions occurred. The demands of electoralism
were all important and, as early as 1890, Bernstein in Germany signalled
the importance of this issue. Declaring that democracy was âthe
high-school of compromiseâ he argued successfully in the German SDP for
a policy of moderation and alliance with forces that did not share in
the desire for fundamental wealth distribution. The eventual aim was
still socialism, he argued, but for the present the immediate goals must
take precedence:
âFor me the achievement of the most immediate demands is the main thing,
not only because they are of great propagandist value and serve to
enlist the masses, but also because, in my opinion, this gradual
process, this gradual socialisation, is the method strongly indicated
for a progressive transition.â [47]
A viewpoint that culminated in Bernsteinâs now classic re-formulation of
his priorities and those of the GSPD, when he stated: âthe movement
means everything... what was usually called the final aim of socialism
... nothingâ.[48]
On the other side of the world matters were not much different though
they were a mite more successful. The ALP had been formed after a series
of industrial defeats by Australian workers in the last decade of the
19^(th) century. From this bitter legacy âthere emerged a determination
to right the wrongs through committed parliamentary action.â[49] The ALP
achieved success early on, particularly at the regional state level.
This âearly progress of Australian Labor in politics attracted the
interests of the rest of the world...â [50] But, at home, doubts were
already setting in. During its first periods in power, at a regional
level, there was disappointment all around:
âLabor people commonly criticised their MPs for not being icy enough.
They saw Parliament as a comfortable club which seduced Labor members
with facilities way beyond the reach of the a typical toiler â higher
wages, comfortable leather chairs, billiard tables, dining rooms,
well-stocked library, free rail travel and invitations to lavish
functions. Close contact with Laborâs adversaries could be disarming
too. After lashing union bashers on the hustings it was different matter
altogether to confront them in relaxing surroundings and find they are
not bad blokes to share a drink with or a game of cards with. Many Labor
men âwere obliged to adjust and often did so without being aware of the
processâ.â [51]
And indeed, in power, Labor were moderate. The ALP formed its first
federal Australian government in 1910. The success âwas saluted as the
culmination of twenty years of arduous workâ.[52] True to form the ALP
âenacted far more legislation than any previous national
administrationâ. But the overall programme of legislation did not tackle
wealth or its distribution. Far from it. A policy of State arbitration
of wages and conditions already begun under the previous non-Labor
Government was extended. As was a tax imposed on large ranchers who
didnât improve land under their control. Finally, âa popular measure ...
the baby bonus, an allowance of five pounds payable at the birth of each
white Australian child.â [53] (As perhaps might be expected from a party
whose members regularly âsaid grace before meals and toasted the
monarchyâ. [54] )
Worse was to come. The Labour Party in Britain came to power,
unexpectedly, when it won 191 seats in the House of Commons in the
general election of December 1923. Unlike its Australian counterpart it
had, previous to this, adopted some definite policies on wealth
redistribution. As Keith Laybourn notes in his book, The Rise of Labour,
âthe party of hope and aspiration had come to office.â [55] It was to be
a bitter lesson for the workers of Britain.
Philip Snowden, the first Labour Chancellor of the Exchequer, introduced
a budget he claimed was a âvindication against no class and no
interestâ. [56] In fact, at the time, it was said to have had
âdevastating consequences for working-class living standardsâ.[57] In
any case, Snowdenâs first budget âreceived the general approval of all
sides of the House of Commons. It was praised by the Tories and Liberals
just as much as the Labour politicians.â [58] though a number of years
later (âlooking back on his lifeâ) Snowden was able to justify his
performance as follows:
âI have been active in political life for forty years, and my only
object has been to improve the lot of the toiling millions. That is
still my aim and my object, and, if I ask for some temporary suspension,
some temporary sacrifices, it is because that is necessary to make
future progress possible.â[59]
A disastrous result and a cause for dismay in Labour ranks? Far from it.
On falling from power at the end of 1924, the first Labour Party
prime-minister in British history, Ramsay McDonald, felt moved enough to
write to the King about the Labour Partyâs performance, impressing on
him as follows:
They [The Labour Party] have shown the country that they have the
capacity to govern in an equal degree with the other Parties in the
House ... and, considering their lack of experience, ... have acquitted
themselves with credit in the House of Commons. [...] The Labour
Government has also shown the country that patriotism is not the
monopoly of any single class or party..... They have in fact
demonstrated that they, no less than any other party, recognise their
duties and responsibilities, and have done much to dispel the fantastic
and extravagant belief which at one time found expression that they were
nothing but a band of irresponsible revolutionaries intent on wreckage
and destruction.[60]
Almost immediately, once some degree of success came their way, the
trend amongst the Labour and socialist parties of the world was away
from the working-class. In Australia, âParty militants... were
disillusioned by Laborâs orientation in office towards the whole
community rather than the working-class exclusively ...â [61] . This
reflected electoral concerns, principally the desire to appear moderate
and accommodating to the wider electorate â even to those sections whose
interests conflicted directly with the interests of workers.
This resulted in even more moderate policies as time progressed. A point
that was noted by commentators: âAlthough, during the inter-war period,
social democrats had won office in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland,
France, Germany, Great Britain, Norway and Sweden, âwith the exception
of the French armaments industry in 1936, not a single company was
nationalised.â â[62] Instead of opting for policies of public ownership
â previously advocated â the socialist and Labour parties âattempted to
mitigate the worst aspects of capitalism. They worked for social reforms
in housing, education, wage rates, unemployment protection and
pensions,â [63] expounding, in the end, âa welfarism that was often
little different from liberalism.â [64] A project that was eloquently
captured by Ben Chiftly, Labor Prime Minister in Australia from 1945â49,
when he said:
âWe have a great objective â the light on the hill â which we aim to
reach by working for the betterment of mankind not only here but
anywhere we may give a helping hand.â [65]
On occasions when workers resisted, expecting â well they might â that
Labor would be more sympathetic to their cause, the results were a
brutal eye-opener. A case in point being the 1946 railway strike in
Australia.
The ALP were in power just one year when this nation-wide dispute broke
out. The Labor minister in charge, Hanlon, himself a former strike
leader in the infamous Brisbane general strike of 1912, âexceeded his
own draconian response to the 1946 metalworkers strike ... he proclaimed
a state of emergency under the Transport Act, authorised the arrest of
strike leaders and the rank and file picketers, and portrayed the
dispute ... as a civil war.â The strike continued, however. So, âHanlon
rushed through parliament the Industrial Law Amendment Act which gave
the police even wider powers than the state of emergency. They could now
take action against anyone they considered might be prolonging the
strike; they could arrest without warrant, prohibit picketing, enter
union offices or meetings at any time, and use force when they
considered it necessary. On St. Patrickâs Day a small orderly
demonstration ... was brutally attacked without warning by a large
police contingent...â [66]
Summing up his impressions after being arrested, one Australian Railways
Union member said of the Labor Party, âIf ever there was a weak
collection of salary chasing opportunist humbugs devoid of any semblance
of working-class principles, it was members of the Labor Party.â [67] He
concluded that no anti-Labor government âcould have been more viciousâ.
---
The emergence of the parliamentary socialist movement, in the early part
of the 20^(th) century, played a key role in breaking large sections of
the working-class away from their own independent efforts at bringing
about change. As a result, a form of democracy that was both tokenistic
and insubstantial became the order of the day. This was a major
achievement for the ârich and privilegedâ.
The particular result, however, was not so much that social peace
prevailed but, rather, that other forms of democracy, more substantive
in content and less acceptable to the interests of the ârich and
privilegedâ, were smothered or, at the very least, curtailed. These
forms â ideas of direct action and direct democracy, democracy in the
workplace etc. â posed a real challenge to the social order in that they
brought the disenfranchised into the struggle for an improved society as
participants rather than as observers â a difference that mattered
enormously in the long run.
There would be one significant exception to this overall trend. This was
in Spain. Here the anarchist movement was strong enough from the
earliest days to set a political course independent of âparliamentary
socialismâ. At the core of the anarchist strategy was direct democracy
and direct action. Eschewing the parliamentary road and all its
trappings, anarchists advocated that instead the workers should reclaim
democracy at their place of power â at work and on the street. This
strategy was to be basis for the most important example of democratic
practice in the 20^(th) century â the workersâ collectives built during
the Spanish Revolution in 1936â37 (see Chap 9).
The arrival of the popular vote (universal suffrage) marked an important
transition in those societies that âgranted itâ. This was the change in
the political order from one in which the mass of the people were
excluded from having any say, to one in which they were nominally
included. Finally, and despite the delay, it was being recognised that
power in society derived from the people. For the present, it was
intended that this power would be carefully managed â through parliament
â and neutralised for the most part. But, even so, it was an important
concession. The arrival of the vote was a recognition that all people,
irrespective of title or wealth, were entitled to an equal say in the
running of society. This remains, for most people, an appealing idea.
Secondly, the vote gave people leverage, albeit of a very weak kind â a
situation that was most obvious at election time. Tripping over
themselves to get elected to parliament and âserve the peopleâ,
politicians were liable to promise anything. This raised expectations in
the electorate and, as was usually the case, indignation later. But,
even so, on some occasions, real concessions were achieved.
How was this new situation to be managed? On the one hand there were the
demands of the electorate; on the other hand there was the usual
business of government. These two interests did not necessarily go hand
in hand. Government, in its age old sense, was primarily concerned with
one major objective. This was overseeing the conditions in which
business could prosper. Enacting laws, ensuring that social peace
prevailed and bringing the forces of the State to bear on the unruly,
were the traditional roles of government. Over time these important,
primary tasks had not disappeared â far from it. As the 20^(th) century
progressed and the economy of the world grew, the instability of an
economic system that rested primarily on exploitation became more
apparent. Left to its own devices, capitalism undoubtedly created great
wealth for the ârich and privilegedâ. But, and this was its great
misfortune, it also created massive misery. Invariably, bust followed
boom and depression followed growth. A century that produced two world
wars and the âGreat Depressionâ, inevitably brought forward those
theories â Keynesism in particular â that argued for more State
intervention in societyâs affairs, and for greater management of the
economy.
To an extent this was a break with the past. But, less obvious at the
time, was the longer term shift in emphasis that occurred generally in
the more economically advanced countries. The State, previously the
agent of the ârich and privilegedâ, shifted from being a partisan player
in the struggle between the rich and the poor to the new and more benign
role of mediator. This required, in turn, a new type of political
operation â where consensus between the classes replaced confrontation
and, under the guise of parliamentary democracy, exploitation was
carried on as before.
This new state of affairs, a reflection in part of greater suffrage and
a reflection in part of new priorities among the ârich and privilegedâ
emerged across the world in a piecemeal fashion. In Europe, war and its
after effects (including revolution and economic depression) checked any
immediate shift away from the traditional method of repression. On the
contrary, progress was slow and it was only towards the end of the 1940s
that the modern parliamentary democracies emerged fully formed.
The USA, for reasons briefly mentioned above, was different. Already one
of the strongest economies by the end of WW1, it progressed unhindered
towards the modern model of parliamentary democracy from the beginning
of the century. Though it didnât concede full suffrage until 1961 â on
foot of the Civil Rights Movement â it already operated reasonably
smoothly and without major hiccup from the 1870s onwards.
It was here in conditions of economic stability and growth that the
influential American âdemocratâ, Walter Lippmann, examined the new
priorities and the new âproblems of democracyâ from the perspective of
the ârich and privilegedâ. Widely praised â for his progressive views,
it would appear â Lippmann provided the modern day reasoning for public
âthought controlâ. The masses, as he saw it, were the problem.
Technically, they had a role to play in the new âdemocraticâ order, but
this âout of necessityâ was passive. As he saw it the public âdoes not
reason, investigate, invent, persuade, bargain or settle.â [68] The
publicâs ability to understand the complex nature of society, the
important issues of the day or, for that matter, to evaluate the âcommon
interestâ was limited. The public, as he noted, was ill-informed:
âIn the absence of institutions and education by which the environment
is so successfully reported that the realities of public opinion stand
out very sharply against self-centred opinion, the common interests very
largely elude public opinion entirely and can be managed only by a
specialised class whose personal interests reach beyond the locality...â
[69]
In Lippmannâs eyes, then, two important roles formed the basis of the
new democratic order, that is modern parliamentary democracy. âFirstly,
there is the role assigned to the âspecialised classâ, the âinsidersâ,
the âresponsible menâ, who have access to information and understanding.
These âpublic menâ are responsible for âthe formation of a sound public
opinion ... They initiate, they administer, they settleâ, and should be
protected âfrom ignorant and troublesome outsiders...â
âThe second role is the âtask of the publicâ, which is much more
limited, Lippmann explains. It is not for the public to âpass
judgementâ, but merely to place âits forces at the disposalâ of one or
other of the âresponsible menâ ... âthe public acts only by aligning
itself as the partisan of someone in a position to act executivelyâ.â
[70]
Lippmann describes this new order of things as a ârevolutionâ in âthe
practice of democracyâ. The publicâs opinion must be shaped and formed
so that the important decisions can be made in their name. He describes
this process, honestly, as âthe manufacture of consentâ noting that âit
is a self-conscious art and a regular organ of popular government.â
These priorities, articulated by Lippmann and others, were not new. In
fact they were strikingly similar to earlier views, for example J.S.
Millâs advice that: âthe intellectual classes [should] lead the
government, and the government should lead the stupid classes.â But
other, newer developments had compounded the problem from the
perspective of the ârich and privilegedâ. During the inter-war years
(1918â39) newspaper readership rose steadily, as did cinema attendance
and radio listener-ship. The first television networks were on the air
in the late â40s.
This brought change in its own right. For the first time in history, the
technology, wealth and means existed to implement democracy on a mass
scale. Democracy, in its proper sense, had always consisted of two
aspects: The first of these was having the power to take decisions â
this was a right that was increasingly being won as the twentieth
century proceeded. But the second of these aspects was, to a point, more
difficult to achieve. This was providing people with the information
around which decisions could be based. This was especially important
with the emergence of national economies, and with the increasing
enlargement of society to include larger geographical areas. The mass
media was a potential solution to this need. Large sections of the
population, for the first time, had access to the media at low cost. In
this way they could keep informed and abreast of major political and
social events of the day from beginning through to end. Such was the
potential of the emerging newspaper and radio industry (and later on,
television). But it was not to be used for these democratic objectives.
The new era of parliamentary democracy was dominated by the idea of
âmanufacturing consentâ. Not surprisingly this process relied heavily on
the emergent mass media. The primary objective was not to âinvestigate
and informâ but to âreport and shapeâ. By virtue of what was or wasnât
reported the nature and basis of political debate could be set (and
altered). Certain viewpoints, conducive to the interests of the ârich
and privilegedâ, tended to dominate on the airwaves and in political
debate. Other viewpoints â âless friendlyâ â received less attention.
The general bias in the media has been best explained by Noam Chomsky
and Edward S. Herman [71] . In Manufacturing Consent they outlined how
the modern media operates its bias not through any one particular agent
but rather through a series of effects. None of these effects if taken
in isolation would constitute a dominant influence on what the news
media presents. But taken together they can and often do. These effects
they call âfiltersâ. Taken together these âfiltersâ alter the balance of
new coverage in favour of the current economic structure. In
Manufacturing Consent the following five are listed:
1. Ownership, size and profit orientation of the dominant mass media
firms: The modern media is largely âin private handsâ despite the
existence of many national radio and TV stations. Some of these news
networks â News International, Hearst, etc. â are multi-billion pound
businesses, with their own profit demands. Many news companies also
invest outside of the media â in mining, manufacturing etc. â giving
then a âvestedâ interest in the current (unequal) state of the world.
2. Advertising as the primary income source of the mass media: Most
radio, TV and newspapers depend heavily on advertising. There are two
aspects to this. Advertising revenue acts as a subsidy to production
costs, allowing âadvertiser friendlyâ media to undercut and expand
relative to their âadvertiser unfriendlyâ rivals. Secondly, as is
well-known, advertising is mainly funded by private business leading to
an in-built subsidy to âbusiness friendlyâ media and coverage. Media
that challenges the direct interests of the ârich and privilegedâ will
simply not get advertising revenues. Accordingly it may not survive, or
if it does, it will remain small and under-funded.
3. Media reliance on information provided by government, business and
âexpertsâ funded by same: The media news services rely on ârespectable
sourcesâ for news. In part this is to save on costs, but it also
reflects the need to get information from âofficial sourcesâ and ânot
just anyoneâ. The Government is often relied on because the âGovernment
is neutralâ. The results are predictable.
4. âFlakâ as a means of disciplining the media: The media is seen as an
important arena of debate in many parliamentary democratic societies.
For this reason, many âThink-Tanksâ target the media and monitor its
output. Think-Tanks are not cheap to set up or to run. Needless to say,
they are funded by and support those who have money and privilege. They
can play a vital role in altering the âfocusâ of the media on an issue.
5. âAnti-communismâ as a control mechanism: âAnti-Communism can mean the
traditional Cold War rhetoric that was powerful in the USA and in
Western Europe for much of the last fifty years. But it can also be the
âgeneral idea of socialismâ. Labelling a journalist âpro-communistâ or
the coverage of a strike as âpro-communistâ is often a subtle but
powerful way of putting pressure on a news feature to moderate its focus
(especially if the said coverage or journalist is anything but
âcommunistâ).
News coverage of parliamentary elections is a special application of the
above. Coverage is shaped by a number of key assumptions â many of which
are generalised within the media services to such an extent that they
are seen as being âbeyond questionâ. Yet these assumptions influence the
reporting, the evaluation and the assessments of elections â thereby
structuring the discussion and debate in society in a way that is
suitable to those who already have power and privilege. Some of these
assumptions are listed below â they can be easily seen.
quite different; they represented the full spectrum of political
options.
Fundamentally important issues relating to parliamentary elections are
never examined or pursued by the media â for clearly evident reasons. As
will be seen below, many elections repeat certain themes: âputting the
people firstâ, âinvesting in education and healthâ, âtackling crimeâ â
yet precious little ever happens or changes. So Does your vote actually
have any effect? Is there an actual (as opposed to a nominal) choice at
election time? Will a politician keep his/her word? These are important
questions and are central to the subject of democracy â yet they are
carefully avoided by a media attendant to the interests of the powerful
and privileged.
The idea of Parliament derives from the âadvisor groupsâ that were
appointed by the King in medieval times. The first parliaments (for
example those in England) were completely staffed with cronies of the
monarch â various Barons and Bishops and Earls who were seen as wise and
of âsound mindâ. Such persons were there to council the King on his
decisions â though it was understood that the King was not bound to
follow their advice. Since only the King was privy to all the
information, it was accepted that only the King should have âexecutiveâ
power â that is the power to make actual laws.
Modern government is still based on this old model. This can be seen in
number of ways. One surviving similarity is the idea of having two parts
to the decision-making system in government â an âExecutiveâ part and a
âParliamentaryâ part. In some countries the Parliament has the job of
âdiscussing and debatingâ (and is somewhat âadvisoryâ in its role)
whereas the Executive actually âproposes and implementsâ laws.
(Depending on the particular country, the Executive can be chosen in
different ways. In Ireland and the UK, for example, the Executive is
usually composed of a group drawn from the largest political party in
the Parliament, whereas in the USA the Executive is elected separately).
Either way, the great change with the past, we are told, is that we now
âchooseâ who will be in the Parliament and who will be in the Executive.
Because of this the decisions that are taken should âreflectâ what we
think.
True? The answer most definitely is NO.
A second similarity with the old medieval system makes sure of that.
This is the notion that only the Executive is privy to all the
information necessary to make decisions, and in essence is the only body
in society that can and should be allowed to make laws. So while
politicians do stand at election time for various policies and
positions, and the voters cast their ballots on the basis of these
policies, an elected politician is not bound by any law to follow these
previously proclaimed policies and positions. Indeed, once elected and a
member of Government, a politician is entirely within his or her rights
to jettison any promises s/he may have made at the election. The
politician in question is quite entitled (legally) to say: âHaving
examined the state of the public finances I have changed my mind about
what I previously said â I now think the opposite!â
It is through this notion that an elected parliament is able to discard
âthe wishesâ of the electorate, and to act as it sees fit. In actual
practice this is how your vote is discarded.
Though this idea (that a politician is not bound by your vote) may seem
like a minor technicality â it is not in practice. The idea that
Parliament and the Executive should retain âautonomyâ from those that
elect them was deliberately retained during the period of reform that
saw suffrage being extended to the mass of people in society. Though
people were gradually âgrantedâ the right to vote for who should make up
parliament, the crucial right of a direct input was withheld. As J. S.
Mill emphasised in a subtle but meaningful way: democracy is ânot that
the people govern themselves but that they have the security for good
governmentâ.
To see how effective Parliament is at âremaining independentâ of the
electorateâs wishes it is worth looking at a few examples. (These it
should be said have been chosen at random. There are hundreds of others
and each election throws up a new set. The following however do show the
scope of the problem.)
PERU: The elections in Peru in 1990 were fought against a backdrop of
increasing poverty and economic ruin. The Peruvian electorate was
offered a choice between the policies of Mario Vargas Llosa and those of
Aberto Fujimoro. Llosa, a writer and something of a novice in politics,
made his policies well known. He argued stridently for austerity and for
massive cuts to anti-poverty programmes in Peru (such as they existed)
as a means of curbing the Stateâs debt. Fujimoro, who was also somewhat
new to politics, said a lot less but campaigned openly as âan
alternative to Llosaâ. Not surprisingly, the election saw the wise
people of Peru vote against Llosa and his IMF sponsored polices;
Fujimoro won. Yet within months, Fujimoro adopted Llosaâs previously
stated policies and inaugurated unprecedented cutbacks and an attack on
the poor â a process that later came to be known as âFujishockâ! [72]
USA: Bill Clintonâs victory in 1992 came after twelve years of
âReaganomicsâ â policies that had led to a massive shift in wealth from
the poor to the rich (see later). Clinton made a number of important
promises â some directly economic and some related to âsocialâ issues.
Clintonâs campaign, and directly affected some 35 million US citizens.
Clinton âeventuallyâ abandoned the idea of a promised medical insurance
system in 1995. (It has not resurfaced.) In fact, there were more
Americans without medical insurance at the end of Clintonâs first term
of office than before it began!
had a certain ring to it after so many years of Reaganomics. Yet Clinton
quickly changed his mind once elected and adopted what later become
known as the âWall Street strategyâ. As one commentator said: âBut,
after the election, his economic team convinced him instead to
concentrate on reducing the deficitâ [73] A strategy that led Clinton to
abolish the âheating subsidyâ for over 5 million poor Americans and to
put a âtwo year limit on welfare paymentsâ after which time a person had
to take a job (no matter what the pay) or starve.
promised equality of service in the US armed forces as a reward â this
was abandoned within a year in favour of a âdonât ask, donât tellâ
policy.
Ireland: Before the 1987 general election, Fianna Fail flooded the
country with posters and billboards declaring âHealth Cuts hurt the old,
the sick and the handicappedâ. Within months of their being returned to
government they were implementing massive cutbacks in spending on
health.
Prior to the general election of 1982, Fine Gael took out newspaper
advertisements warning that if Fianna Fail were elected they would
impose a new local tax in the form of service charges. Fianna Fail,
meanwhile, warned in the same newspapers that if Fine Gael won, they
would impose service charges. The Labour Party made a âclear and
unambiguousâ statement that they were totally opposed to such charges.
Following the election, a Fine Gael-Labour government was formed and in
July 1983 the Local Government Provisions Act No. 2 was passed by them.
This empowered County Managers to charge for services. Fianna Fail
fought the subsequent 1985 local elections on an anti-service charge
ticket but immediately after the elections their councillors around the
country did a U-turn and voted for charges. Just before the general
election of 1987, Fianna Fail gave a written guarantee to the National
Association of Tenants Organisations (NATO) that if returned to
government they would scrap local charges. They were and they didnât. In
fact charges continued to be levied for the next decade until a massive
campaign of people power led to their abolition. Over that ten-year
period several TDs were elected to Dail Eireann on anti-charges tickets.
Eamonn Gilmore, Kathleen Lynch (both Democratic Left) and Emmett Stagg
(Labour) were all initially involved in anti-charges campaigns and were
actively calling on people not to pay the charges. Yet all ended up in a
government which was dragging people before the courts for exactly that.
Australia: The 1993 general election in Australia was a close run
affair. Eventually it did end with a win for the ALP(Australian Labor
Party) who partly secured their victory by promising some âpopular
reformsâ aimed at improving hospital waiting lists and helping the
âmiddle rangeâ of people financially (through tax reform). These
promised reforms played an important part in the election since the gap
between the rich and poor in Australia had widened considerably during
the 1980s. Yet by August of 1993, just three months after the election,
the ALP had ditched five specific promises it had made at the election:
to cut waiting lists)
France: During the Presidential election in 1995, Chirac made an
important (in the eyes of the electorate) promise not to âraise taxes.â
He also promised to create jobs by increased spending. A few months
after his election, during the notoriously âquietâ summer period in
French politics, Chiracâs Prime-Minster Alan JuppĂŠ presented a
âsupplementary budget to raise an extra $6 billion in taxes by the end
of the yearâ [74] which interestingly (noted the Economist) âhit the
poor hardestâ [75] Not that this sufficed. In a later twist, JuppĂŠ and
Chirac having promised to create 700,000 jobs by the end of 1996, ended
up increasing unemployment by announcing spending cuts of $5 billion to
âmeet the Maastricht criteriaâ!
Brazil: The seasoned politician Fernando Cardoso used a thoughtful ploy
on his âcampaign trailâ that saw him win the 1994 election. Before the
crowds he would hold up this hand and begin ticking off each of his main
priorities â health, education, housing, infrastructure and employment â
one for each finger. [76] It was obviously effective in a country
notorious for its levels of inequality. (One percent of the population
of Brazil received 15% of the income in 1994 alone) [77] . Yet Cardoso
seemed to have forgotten all of this less than one year later when,
noted the Economist, âIn Congress, Mr Cardoso and his team have been
busy with a package of market-freeing constitutional reforms, needed
both to keep inflation down and ensure growthâ [78] A set of priorities
that made him âveto the minimum wage riseâ and introduce a âtall orderâ
in legislation, of such magnitude in fact that âBritainâs Conservatives
... have not achieved it in 16 yearsâ. [79]
The important issues in politics are as plainly obvious in India as
anywhere else in the world â if not more so. The country that is often
called âthe largest democracyâ in the world is also one of the most
unequal. Some 36% of the population are estimated [80] to be living in
âabsolute povertyâ (a condition defined by the UN as âmalnutrition,
illiteracy, disease, high infant mortality or low life expectancyâ).
Alongside this, the top 10% of Indian society absorbed nearly 35% of the
income of the nation in 1985 alone, skewing the wealth distribution into
even more unequal figures.
These are startling statistics. But in a society in which âthe people
ruleâ this situation â one would predict â should be quickly changed.
Plain âself-interestâ should see to that. After all with so many poor
people in such a majority, it would seem to be just a case of simple
mathematics to right the wrong. One election is all it should take. Yet
what has happened? In fact the opposite has occurred. Despite some 40
years of parliamentary democracy and âuniversal suffrageâ, Indiaâs
inequality has remained impervious to change for the better. In the last
decade or so, the gap has actually been growing again.
The reasons why are not difficult to discover â nor are they
particularly Indian in content. Indian politics has been dominated
almost since independence by the Congress party, a political movement
that is seen by many, interestingly, to be on the left and to even have
âsocialistâ ideas. The other significant party is the BJP. Besides the
BJP there is a host of smaller parties (some on the left, others on the
right). However none of these ever dent the arena of national politics
so the practical choice is between only two parties â Congress and the
BJP.
Asked to clarify the differences between these two political parties in
1993, an Indian business journalist [81] saw none in practice. Both
parties, he concluded, were âtravelling down the one road.â The only
point of difference between the BJP and Congress, he pointed out, was
the âspeedâ of the journey and the âside of the road they [the parties]
were travelling onâ. So while the electorate in India does have a choice
at election time, both parties on the roster have â in effect â the same
overall policies. What are these?
Politics in India has been dominated since its foundation by the broad
idea of âreformâ. More recently however, these âreformsâ have had a more
focused target. According to the Indian Prime-Minister, PV Rao of the
Congress Party, they âhad to do with changes in the companies act ...
capital acquisition tax and the financial sector reformsâ and also
âintroducing value added taxâ [82] . Noting the effect of these
âreformsâ, the Economist recorded a familiar picture. It reported that
âAmong unskilled Indians, real wages dropped in the first 18 months of
economic reforms.â Not that this was the entire picture â far from it.
Though grain production in India was enlarging under the new reforms
(ânot many people know it but India is sitting on a mountain of 30
million tonnes of grainâ), the Economist went on to point out that âthe
poor could no longer afford to buyâ.[83] Indeed even Prime-Mister Rao,
the architect of the reforms, was appalled at this. And lashed out that
it was âscandalous that grain should be exported when so many Indians
still go hungryâ. Though in a speech to the Federation of the Indian
Chambers of Commerce, two years earlier, in a more sober mood, he had
said (about the reforms) âthe difficult part lies ahead. We have a long
way to go. The journey is bound to be long and difficultâ. [84] And
returning to that all important question, that of speed, he said âthe
pace of reform would be governed by the ability of the system to absorb
changes âwithout collapsing.â Such are the realities of âthe largest
democracyâ in the world.
Providing no effective choice to the electorate amid the colour, pomp
and drama of âGeneral Election Feverâ is the stuff of parliamentary
democracy. In this game the media play a valuable and vital role. The
1993 parliamentary election in Australia being a case in point.
It was described by the one of the main national papers as âThe most
important election since WW2.â Yet when asked to point out the
differences between the two options being âofferedâ to the electorate,
four different financial commentators saw no âreal differencesâ that
mattered in the long run. Why this was so is quite easy to see. The
Australian Labor Party had been in power throughout the â80s in
Australia and had presided over a âhistoric drop in wagesâ [85] and a
variety of âlabour market reformsâ that had âborne fruitâ [86] .
Challenging the ALP were the traditional parties of big business and big
farmers â an alliance of the Liberal and the Country Party (whose
central election policy was the introduction of VAT â a tax that
invariably effects the poor more than the well off!).
The ALP eventually won the election after issuing a slew of promises
(quickly forgotten â see above). Though when he addressed a large âgroup
of business leadersâ shortly afterwards, the ALP leader, Paul Keating,
was less forgetful. In his speech Keating âforeshadowed a historic
deregulation of the labour marketâ though he stressed (being a man who
had not âforgotten his rootsâ) that âeconomic reform should be moderated
by a concern for the disadvantaged.â Not that this âshould put the
Government and business at odds,â he added, âThe success of economic
policy depends on the success of businessâ [87]
We can look anywhere else in the globe and see a similar process. The
Presidential elections in Honduras in 1989 were hailed âas a milestoneâ
though the effective choice between the two candidates left a lot to be
desired: âThe elections were effectively restricted to two candidates,
one from a family of wealthy industrialists, the other from a family of
large landowners.â Even top advisors to both camps acknowledged that
âthere is little substantive difference between the two and the policies
they would follow as president.â. Not that a lacklustre campaign
resulted. The candidates, noted Central America Report, ârelied on
insults and accusations to entertain the crowds at campaign rallies and
political functionsâ. As US president Bush pointed out about the victor,
Rafael Callejas: He is âan inspiring example of the democratic promise
that is spreading throughout the Americas.â [88]
In Eastern Europe the experience of parliamentary democracy is somewhat
new, but it is not that much different. âPainful shock therapyâ was used
on many of the countries in this region after the fall of State
Capitalism and Soviet Power. This âfree-market madnessâ provoked a
backlash in the population (are we surprised?) with the result that
âreformed communists have come back into power on waves of discontentâ
(the Economist noted) [89] . In Poland this saw a victory for the
Democratic Left Alliance (DLA) in 1993 (in the Parliamentary election)
and again in 1995 (in the Presidential election). âThe once despised
ex-communists gained votes by acknowledging the suffering of ordinary
peopleĂâ [90]
What did this sensitivity translate into? The Economist (no friend of
the DLAâs) pointed out that the situation was ânot as bad as it lookedâ.
The DLA, it went on, is led by âyoung urbane politicians who claim to be
social democrats and preach free-market reforms and privatisation.â
Assessing the impact of the election, they concluded âIt is possible
that the new Government can be a little kinder to those in need without
seriously jeopardising the reform programme.â [91] Which seems to be
quite accurate, in hindsight. The gap between the rich and the poor is
continuing to sky-rocket in Poland and throughout most of the former
Eastern Europe. As one piece of astute Polish graffiti pointed out: âWe
wanted democracy, but we ended up with the bond marketâ. [92]
Providing no effective choice is the reality in the vast majority of
parliamentary democracies. Parties vie for power at election time â the
campaigns are often âhard-foughtâ and âtoughâ but the only difference
lies in the faces that make up the next parliament, not in the policies.
To all intents and purposes these policies continue as before, unabated.
This is the case in the majority of countries that are called
parliamentary democracies. But it is not the case in all, and this most
be borne in mind. Indeed parliamentary democracy is often most
successful as a form of political control (as opposed to a form of
democracy) because of its apparent âopennessâ and because of the fact
that âpopular constituenciesâ are often encouraged to participate in it.
Many like to believe that âif we got elected, we would be differentâ â
despite the mounting evidence to the contrary.
The history of parliamentary democracy is littered with examples of
this: parties and individuals who âbecome identified with the massesâ
and carry for them âtheir hopes and dreamsâ. As was noted earlier with
the examples of parliamentary socialism, the anger of the poor is often
channelled into parliament and away from the workplace and the street
where it can be particularly powerful. Once in Parliament it gradually
gets âlost and forgotten aboutâ.
A recent example of this dynamic is the case of Brazilâs Luiz Inacio
Lula da Silva (known as Lula), the former âlathe operator turned
politicianâ. Indeed Lulaâs popularity is legendary with the poor of
Brazil. And well it might be. In Brazil the power of business and the
wealthy is only matched by the brutality of the military and the large
land-owners who have come to dominate. Though phenomenally wealthy,
Brazil has been steadily getting worse in terms of the gap between the
rich and the poor â a fact that has played no small part in Lulaâs rise
to fame. Brazil is a country where, in that timeworn phrase, âthe poor
appear to have no voice.â As chairman of the Workers Party of Brazil,
Lula quickly became such a voice, and in fact he very nearly won the
1989 Presidential election, so large was the genuine affection that was
felt for him and his âanti-povertyâ policies.
Lula narrowly lost the 1989 Presidential election. Why is still a
subject for debate. What is clear however is that Lula ran a very
âradical campaignâ in 1989 â in particular he refused to compromise on
his economic views. As a result he maximised his vote with the very
numerous poor of Brazil.
Defeat however led to reassessment with the result that the Lula who ran
again in 1994 was âimportantly differentâ. As the Economist noted, Lula
âmay still rail against capitalism. But at round tables and in the
auditorium, he takes care to turn down the volumeâ. Indeed the
politician who boasted âIâd never wear a coat and tieâ went out of his
way to present a different impression in 1994. âIn Washington ... 700
bankers and the like crowded into a hall to hear him speak.â This was
when he was 40% ahead in the polls.
So great was the change in Lula, in fact, that some wondered about âwho
the real Lula wasâ. Though others were less bothered. Jose Sobrinho,
chairman of Banco Pontual in San Paulo, observed, âLula attacks the
banks for earning too much, but these days he also says the financial
sector is a necessary evilâ. A view underscored by another business man
, Emerson Kapaz, who âlavishes praise on his rivalâ noting that Lula
âunderstands that he cannot govern alone. These meetings with
businessmen are not just for formâs sake. He is looking for an alliance
that will make it possibleâ . [93]
This example of Lulaâs turnabout is not unusual â it is quite typical
and happens again and again. It was most notable with the rise to power
of the various socialist and Labour parties of the world (see earlier),
but it continues to apply in any situation where a large grassroots
movement seeks âa voice in parliamentâ. On the electoral road to power,
political parties of the left (in particular) go through a process of
âadaptationâ and ârealismâ. Their radicalism is gradually diluted away
so as to âsend the right messageâ. The important constraints of
electoralism â to build alliances, to retain âa positive media imageâ â
all take their toll. Radical politics is the inevitable casualty.
Occasionally it does happen that individuals and parties get into power
with the intention of making a few changes and/or âfulfilling their
popular mandateâ. This is rare, but when it does happen, other important
constraints are brought to bear âon the situationâ in order to prevent
an âun-welcomed outcomeâ. These are the financial markets and the
âthreat of a coupâ.
The âfinancial marketsâ more than any other single factor are playing an
increasingly important role in constraining âyour voteâ. Though the
effect of the âmarketsâ is somewhat dependent on the size and relative
economic independence of the particular country involved, it is
nevertheless becoming an important factor almost everywhere with time.
The effect of the âfinancial marketsâ can be in a number of different
ways:
âconflictsâ with the overall interests of business the prospect of
âflight of capital can be brought into playâ as a means of disciplining
that Government. This happened in the very notable case of France in
1981 after the victory of the French Socialist Party. âInitial hostility
on the part of business was manifested in manoeuvres to avoid
nationalisation and a flight of capital abroadâ. [94] This was evident
in the French media where âBusinessmen made a show of studied pessimism,
painting reality in excessively dark colours and discouraging hiring and
investmentâ. France entered âa crisisâ. And in due course, after the
balance of power within the French Socialist Party shifted back towards
a more moderate programme, French business once again âbecame prepared
to play its role with a certain amount of loyaltyâ.[95]
South Africa. Here the source of âfinancial constraintâ is non-national
â unlike in the case of France above. The actual achievement of popular
suffrage in S. Africa after a long and bitter struggle against the
apartheid system fuelled real expectations that substantial change would
occur in the aftermath of the vote in April 1994 â in particular with
regard to wealth distribution. This did not occur. The Irish Timesâ
correspondent in SA, Edward OâLoughlin, noted in December 1994 (7 months
after Government formation) that the ANCâs key problem âis growing
discontent among its black constituency, which believes the ANC has done
little to improve their lot since taking powerâ. [96] However, despite
this, in March 1995 the same correspondent reported that âSouth Africaâs
second post apartheid budget ... has once again demonstrated the
commitment of the countryâs new rulers to fiscal discipline and
free-market reformsâ. [97] Noting that the ANCâs programme had been
âtempered by realityâ OâLoughlin reported that the âbudget messageâ was
overshadowed âby the ongoing crisis over exchange rates and exchange
controlsâ. Indeed the Randâs (South Africaâs currency) fall from grace
(its value slumped against the US dollar) was as a result of ârumoursâ
and âperceptionsâ. Though the London based Financial Times, was less
circumspect in assessing the impact of this. It noted that Trevor
Manual, the ANCâs minister of finance, had âmoved a long way towards
embracing free market policies. The challenge now is to persuade the
rest of the ANC and in particular its union and communist allies to
catch-up.â Emphasising the âdisciplinary effectâ of the currency
problem, the Financial Times continued: âThe value of the Rand in the
months ahead is likely to provide an accurate reflection of the progress
of that political struggleâ. [98]
how little parliamentary democracy can mean in todayâs world. With the
âfinancial marketsâ skewed towards the rich and powerful countries in
the First World, more âdependentâ economies are increasingly cut adrift
by decisions made in say Washington, London or Tokyo. A classic example
being the 1979 decision by the Chairman of the US Federal Reserves, Paul
Volcker, to âraise the rate of interest and thereby also to raise the
value of the dollarâ. [99] According to the economist, Andre Frank, this
decision âwas the single most important cause of the debt crisis and
consequently the depression and âlost decadeâ of the 80sâ. [100] Indeed
in Latin America and Africa the cost of this depression remains untold,
though of huge dimension. Perhaps tens of thousands of lives were lost
as a result of this âfinancial decision.â Frank also notes,
interestingly, that even in the specific context of parliamentary
democracy neither the American electorate nor the Congress nor the
President had any âright to intervene in such a decision of the Federal
Reserveâ. A timely reminder of âthe limitsâ of parliamentary democracy â
if such a reminder is still needed.[101]
In contrast to the remoteness and âsubtletyâ of the financial markets,
the âthreat of a coupâ is an entirely different matter, though no less
unreal if we are to judge by even relatively recent examples e.g. Haiti
(1991), Algeria (1992), Nigeria (1993) to name just a few.
It is often assumed that such coups occur in situations where âradicalâ
polices are involved but this, surprisingly enough, is not the case.
Coups in parliamentary democracies often occur against relatively
âreasonableâ Governments â a fact that supports the theory that it is
often the broader social movement that is the real target of the
military. An important example being the coup against the Allende
government in Chile in 1973. It is often not recognised that the reforms
being introduced by the popularly elected government of Salvador Allende
were for the most part quite benign, involving âland reformâ of large
estates (with compensation) and nationalisation of copper mines (with
compensation).
However Allendeâs period in office was also accompanied by the emergence
of âassemblies of workers in factories, Peopleâs Supply Committees in
the publaciones ... Peasant Councils in rural areasâ. These groups began
to play a more and more important role as Allendeâs Government stalled
on implementing its promised polices. âBasic demands emerged from these
popular organisations. The Government was supposed to represent the
people, in that case it should put into operation the policies the
people were demanding.â [102] Indeed this popular movement became
increasingly confident and impatient as time went on, and in some areas
began to supplant the State. Food distribution was taken over by
community organisations; workers became more belligerent and occupied
their places of work ejecting managers; in the countryside land was
occupied.
The subsequent coup in Chile led to the loss of thousands of lives and
the âliquidation of the leftâ.
Politics Is About Who Gets What,
Especially As A Result Of Government Action
George F. Will, 1988
Conservative Commentator
Governments change but policies donât. This, for the most part, is an
adequate description of how parliamentary democracy operates. It
probably sounds like something an anarchist would say â yet the figures
bear it out. Take the case of the United States â often regarded as the
âhome of democracyâ or even âthe most democratic state in the worldâ.
Despite the various changes in Government that have occurred in the US
over the last twenty to thirty years, there has hardly been a hiccup in
the most obvious result of Government policy â that rich people have got
dramatically richer.
During the period of time covered by this survey of incomes (1954â84)
there have been eight Presidential elections in the US. The outcome of
these elections has led to a steady exchange â between Republicans and
Democrats. The following âadministrationsâ have been in power:
Republican (1956â60), Democratic (1960â64), Democratic (1964â68),
Republican (1968â72) Republican (1972â76), Democratic (1976â80),
Republican (1980â84).
Yet it is clearly evident that âuniversal suffrageâ has had only a
marginal effect, if any, on the policies that have been pursued. The
income of the top 40% of US society (the 4 and 5^(th) quintiles) has
steadily increased in comparison with the bottom 60%. The real
beneficiaries have been the so-called âsuper-richâ â the top 5% of the
population. As can also be seen, the very rich have been holding steady
in terms of their percentage holding of wealth in US society throughout
the entire period. (Interestingly enough, the one point where their
wealth holding dropped by a significant amount, between 1972 and 1976,
was due to the onset of recession and the âoil crisisâ and not due to
any Government policy!)
In fact, to the extent that things have changed at all, in any
significant way, from election to election, they have mostly changed for
the worse. The policies implemented by Reagan, Bush and Clinton
(Republican, Republican and Democrat) have had a dramatic impact on the
distribution of income and wealth in the USA. Kevin Phillipsâ mainstream
study, The Politics Of Rich And Poor, described the worsening situation
as follows:
âBy the middle of Reaganâs second term, official data had begun to show
that Americaâs broadly defined ârichâ â the top half of 1% of the US
population â had never been richer. Federal policy favoured the
accumulation of wealth and rewarded financial assets, and the
concentration of income that began in the mid-1970s was accelerating. In
1988, approximately 1.3 million individual Americans were millionaires
by assets, up from 574,000 in 1980, 180,000 in 1972, 90,000 in 1964, and
just 27,000 in 1953. Even adjusted for inflation the number of
millionaires had doubled between the late seventies and the late
eighties. Meanwhile the number of billionaires, according to Forbes
magazine, went from a handful in 1981 to 26 in 1986 and 49 in 1987. As
of late 1988, Forbes put that yearâs number at 52 billionaires.â[103]
This âphenomenal riseâ in the wealth of the rich occurred at the expense
of those who work, it would seem.
Phillips continues:
âMost of the Reagan decade, to put it mildly, was a heyday for unearned
income as rents, dividends, capital gains and interest gained relative
to wages and salaries as a source of wealth, increasing economic
inequality.â[104]
A situation that was put down (quite rightly) to Reaganomics. Yet when
Reagan and his successor, Bush, were finally removed from office in 1992
on foot of Clintonâs âput people first campaignâ, the super-accumulation
of wealth merely continued. Assessing Clintonâs impact (after his first
term in office) in 1996, the Economist reported that âreal wages are
slightly lower than they were 20 years agoâ. [105] Inequality had never
been higher as we can see.
If we look at another flagship of âdemocracyâ â Britain â the picture is
more complex but broadly similar. Even so what is interesting about
Britain is the presence of the Labour Party â a party that until quite
recently was committed âto public ownershipâ of industry (Clause 4)
among other things. Indeed, on face value, the British electorate would
appear to have a âreasonableâ choice at election time (within the
confines of very narrow limits admittedly). Face value is a deceptive
thing, of course.
In Wealth, Income and Equality, A.B. Atkinson gives this assessment:
âThe overall impression from the figures is a reduction in inequality
but, if the decline in the share of the top 1% is ignored, the shape of
the distribution of income is not greatly different in 1976â77 from what
it was in 1949. The major part of the fall in the share of the top 1 per
cent is balanced by an increase in the shares of the other groups in the
top half of the distribution. The income distribution shows a remarkable
stability from year to yearâ[106]
And of course, it normally follows that if income distribution fails to
change, wealth (fixed asset) distribution doesnât either.
The Labour Party was in power for considerable periods during this time:
between 1945 and â51 under Atlee, between 1964 and â70 under Wilson, and
â traumatically â from 1975-â79 under Wilson and Callaghan (apart from
the brief Liberal-Labour pact, 1977â78). Indeed Labourâs period at the
helm coincided with the creation of the âWelfare Stateâ â regarded as
the high-point of achievement. So much so that the influential Labour
MP, Anthony Crossland, was able to state in The Future Of Socialism in
1956 that,â almost all the basic features of traditional pre-1914
Capitalism have either been greatly modified or completely transformed.â
[107] Indeed Crossland was so carried away with the success of Labour in
power that he began to wonder if they hadnât gone too far (the heady
height of power, one imagines!). He said: âIâm sure that a definite
limit exists to the degree of equality which is desirable. We do not
want complete equality of incomes, since responsibility and exceptional
talent requires and deserves a differential awardâ. [108]
Those who remained outside the corridors of power saw a different and
depressingly familiar picture. Richard Titmuss, in his study, was one of
the first to conclude that âthe Welfare State in Britain after WW2 has
not led to any significant re-distribution of wealth in favour of the
poor classes.â [109] An assessment that is backed up by Padgett and
Paterson in their authoritative study, A History of Social Democracy in
Post-war Europe. They note, âBritain in the immediate post-war period
saw a reduction in pre-tax incomes of the highest earners, but the
beneficiaries were those in the upper-middle income bracket ... The
share of pre-tax and post-tax income accruing to the bottom third of the
income ladder remained steady from 1945 to the mid-1970s.â [110] Wealth
distribution, in fact, was hardly affected until the late 1970s when, on
foot of Thatcherâs rise to power, the situation dramatically
disimproved. So much so that Britain became âthe most unequal country in
the Western Worldâ by 1996. It could proudly claim that âthe richest
fifth of Britainâs population enjoy, on average, incomes 10 times as
high as the poorest fifthâ. [111]
The âWelfare Stateâ was an important development in the post-war period
to the extent that it lifted the standard of living of society in
general â though it did not markedly affect wealth distribution. This
should not actually surprise us since, as commentators have noted,
âSocial Democrats have often regarded the welfare state possessively as
âtheir ownâ property, looking to it as a vehicle for this egalitarian
philosophy. However the origins of the welfare state predate government
social democracy, and it is a common feature of all capitalist societies
irrespective of their experience of party government.â [112]
Nevertheless, as the 1980s proceeded, and the balance of power shifted
significantly in favour of the ârich and privilegedâ â especially in the
workplace under the aegis of high âmanaged unemploymentâ â it became
possible in many countries to consider âending the welfare state as we
know itâ. This broad objective was achieved in a number of countries in
a number of ways. In Britain it was âThatcherismâ, in the USA it was the
Reagan and Clinton administrations. In a host of other countries however
â especially in Europe and in Australia â the various Labour and
socialist parties did the bidding.
Indeed the period between 1980 and 1995 is remarkable for the large
numbers of socialist and Labour parties that came to power â in France,
Spain, Portugal, Greece, Ireland (in coalition), Italy, Belgium,
Denmark, Australia and New Zealand, to name just some. We can of course
speculate on why: was it a âcry for helpâ by the working-class and the
poor? If so, it went unheard.
Speaking about the situation in Spain, Portugal and Greece, Padgett and
Paterson note that âThe hallmark of governmental social democracy ...
was its pragmatism, most marked in economic policy.â This meant that in
Spain and Portugal, for example, Socialist Governments âintroduced
austerity programmes immediately upon taking office.â In Portugal this
âbitter pillâ meant âcutting subsidies on basic commodities, inevitably
driving up basic food prices. At the same time there was a freeze on
wages and a clamp-down on public spending.â In Portugal, the purchasing
power of its workforce fell by 10% under âSocialistâ rule. [113] A
situation that was broadly repeated in Spain, Italy, Greece, and France,
to again name just a few. (France incidentally shot up the âinequalityâ
ladder after nearly a decade of âSocialist Party ruleâ).
A performance that was repeated on the other side of the world, in
Australia, where the ALP was in power under Hawke and Keating for almost
all of the 1980s. Here âmany ALP supporters accepted that a degree of
compromise was inevitable when a Labor Government was in office during
difficult economic times. Yet many felt frustrated that the Hawke
government seemed inclined to ... implement changes in the financial
sphere ... often in line with views of conservative economistsâ.[114]
Which led one Labor âstalwartâ to note: âThere has been in Australia a
move towards the philosophy that whatever is spent on the poor causes a
deficit, whatever is spent on the rich encourages investmentâ.[115]
Indeed this role of the various Labour and socialist parties of the
world in attacking âtheir ownâ is often the basis for a wider decline.
Rank and file party activists often suffer demoralisation and confusion
in its aftermath, as does the (working-class) electorate, which as usual
votes in good faith for such parties. This demoralisation is fertile
ground for âright-wingâ politics. It is noteworthy that in a host of
countries, where this has happened, the electorate has often returned a
âConservativeâ government in the aftermath of a period of âsocialist
ruleâ (France, Spain, Australia, to name just three.) Not surprisingly,
the returned âConservativeâ alternative persists with polices that
further attack the standard of living of the working-class. A complete
circle, as they say.
The recent direction of economic policy in Ireland is a good example of
one other tendency in parliamentary democracy: the people voted, but so
what. In Ireland the proportion of the GDP that is allocated to âsocial
spendingâ has been declining since 1985. However this policy has never
actually been voted on by the electorate, despite a number of elections
in this time-span. Since the âpublicâ in Ireland and elsewhere cannot be
persuaded to vote for such cut-backs, the various Governments have
instead resorted to what is called by the Economist âReform ... by
stealthâ. In a survey entitled the âChanging Face Of The Welfare Stateâ
[116] , the same magazine speculates that this reform by stealth âmight
yet transform the welfare stateâ.
âReform By Stealthâ, it notes, has three distinct parts. Firstly,
restrict claims by attaching conditions to benefits. Secondly, âprovide
universal basic welfare coverage, but ... redefine âbasicâ downwards.â
Thirdly, introduce âmeans-testingâ. In Ireland, despite numerous changes
in the Government. â Fianna Fail/ PD, Fianna Fail/ Labour and Fine
Gael/Labour/Democratic Left â this policy has been ongoing since 1985.
It has been quite successful, the articles notes, and has led to âa
nibble here, and a nibble thereâ. The result is an ever familiar
picture: poverty has risen [117] as a percentage of the Irish population
during the period under review even though all the parties are committed
to âtackling povertyâ.
In his well-known study of the democratic idea, C. B. Macpherson, notes
the changing fortunes of the âidea of democracyâ among the elite of the
world. It has been a rocky road:
Democracy used to be a bad word. Everyone who was anybody knew that
democracy, in its original sense of rule by people ...would be a bad
thing â fatal to all the graces of civilised living. That was the
position taken by pretty nearly all men of intelligence from the
earliest time down to about one hundred years ago. Then, within fifty
years, democracy became a good thing. Its full acceptance into the ranks
of respectability was apparent by the time of the First World War...
Since then, in the last fifty years democracy has remained a good
thing... so much so that everyone claims to have it.â[118]
It could not be put more plainly. Parliamentary democracy is a good
thing (in fact it is one of the best thing around) if you wish to
preserves the current unequal order â as the rich do. It delivers the
essential result every time we vote: the rich get richer and the poor
get poorer.
Throughout history there has been an alternative idea of democracy â
this is the idea of direct democracy. It surfaced during the Paris
Commune (in 1871), it surfaced in Russia during the early part of the
revolution there, and it was put into large-scale practice in Spain
between 1936â37. It is the method often used by workers in a strike; it
is the method that often arises âspontaneouslyâ when people confront the
State or the bosses. Direct democracy is the democracy that anarchists
advocate.
Direct democracy is different to parliamentary democracy in a number of
important ways:
1.Direct democracy is about âoriginatingâ ideas as much as it is about
âapprovingâ them. In parliamentary democracy, people are never asked for
their own ideas â they are only asked to âapproveâ or âdisapproveâ of
ideas already prepared for them. Direct democracy is radically different
in that way. Direct democracy is based on the realistic notion that
âpeople know best how to look after their own situationâ. We donât need
specialists to tell us how to run our places of work or our communities.
Anarchists argue that we are quite capable of doing this ourselves. All
we need are the resources and the right to do this. Direct democracy is
the method.
2.Direct democracy is based on delegation not representation. The
crucial difference between delegation and representation is that
delegates are only elected to implement specific decisions. Delegates do
not have the right (like TDs or MPs) to change a decision previously
made by an assembly of people. Delegates (unlike representatives) can be
immediately recalled and dismissed from their mandate if they donât
carry out the specific function allotted to them.
3.Direct democracy is as much about the workplace as it is about the
community. In parliamentary democracy, the workplace is âimmuneâ to
democracy (save what rights workers have won through their unions). In
direct democracy, the operation of a factory or a plant or an office
will be via a general assembly of all workers. This body will decide on
conditions of work, will elect re-callable managers, and will organise
how work is done. It will also elect people (as delegates) who will
co-ordinate with the other places of work and with the broader
community. Regional organisation will be managed through a federation of
workplaces using a delegate structure.
Could such a form of democracy work and what would it be like? As
mentioned earlier, Spain provides one of the best examples of how far we
can go in organising a new type of society. The collectives that were
built by the workers of Spain between 1936â37 were highly democratic
[119] . But they also showed the massive potential that we have if freed
from the constraints of capitalism. It seems obvious (though it is
impossible under capitalism) that we should all have a say over the work
we do, how we do it, when and in what way. When we do have these rights,
the quality and nature of our work changes enormously â and this is one
of the things that was achieved in Spain. Democracy and work should
always go together â and it is one of the singular failures of
parliamentary democracy that this has never occurred â nor is it ever
likely to occur because of the threat it poses to capitalism and the
rule of the boss.
The Spanish Revolution began in 1936 and was strongly influenced by
anarchist ideas. It was a large-scale revolution and was without any
doubt the most extensive workersâ revolution in the 20^(th) century â
especially to the extent that Spanish society was transformed.
The Spanish Revolution was also particularly democratic â this was in
part a reflection of the natural tendencies of popular revolutions, but
it was also an expression of the wide influence of anarchist ideas which
prioritised participation and mass assemblies in the struggle against
Spanish capitalism.
Anarchist ideas are founded around the principle of âmeans and endsâ. We
believe that the means we use will condition the ends we achieve.
Anarchists want to build a free and democratic workersâ society. As a
result anarchists use methods that will build this within the struggle
for change. Partly as a result of anarchist activity, the workersâ
movement in Spain was strongly influenced by the practice of democracy â
this was a deliberate goal.
Anarchist methods of struggle set out to increase the self-activity and
self-confidence of the working-class. For this reason anarchists oppose
any involvement with the âparliamentary road to socialismâ.
Parliamentary activity and âelectioneeringâ â in Spain as elsewhere â
increases the passivity of workers and encourages people to believe that
âsomeone elseâ will bring socialism. Anarchists fundamentally oppose
this notion. We know â and history seems to vindicate the view â that
âthe emancipation of the workers can only be carried out by the workers
themselvesâ.
The methods used by anarchists in Spain were conscious and thought-out.
They are as relevant now as they were then. The main ones were as
follows.
Government and the bosses. Anarchists pointed out that direct action is,
firstly, very effective (since it often gets to the root of the
problem). Secondly, it increases the confidence of those who struggle by
showing them in practice the strength that they have (as a collective
body).
anarchist unions. Anarchists point out that workers are most powerful at
their place of work. This is where we must organise. And this is where
we must always attempt to implement democracy â not with the bosses but
against them.
things done. Anarchists obviously recognised that a mass assembly of
people is an unwieldy body for doing a lot of tasks. In a democracy it
is natural that we will appoint people to do certain things â this is a
vital division of labour that must be used. But this appointment should
be on the basis of delegation not representation. Delegates unlike
representatives are subject to recall (if they donât do what they were
asked to do by the assembly, they can be relieved of their mandate and
their actions reversed). This idea of delegation keeps the power of
decision-making at the level of the mass assembly.
the Spanish parliament. They argued that the various Socialist and
Communist parties in Spain would not bring about real change. Anarchists
emphasised that only the workers themselves could do this. Anarchists
refused to participate in the Spanish parliamentary process because they
believed it would divert or even compromise the ârevolutionaryâ
objective. Anti-parliamentarianism was a major part of the democracy
movement in Spain.
The anarchist strategy of direct action and direct democracy in Spain
was concretised by the formation of the syndicalist CNT union in 1910.
Syndicalism was an attempt to provide a link between the broader
anarchist movement and the workers on the shop-floor. Its basic ideas
revolved around all the workers being in one big union. All the
employees in a workplace would join. They would link up with those in
other jobs in the same area, and an area federation would be formed.
Delegates from these would go forward to regional federations who were
then united into a national federation. All the delegates of the CNT
were elected and recallable. They were given a clear mandate and if they
broke it they could be replaced with new delegates.
Every effort was made to prevent the growth of a bureaucracy of
unaccountable full-time officials. There was only one full-time official
in all of the CNT. Union work was done during working hours where
possible, otherwise after work. This ensured that the officials of the
union stayed in contact with the shop-floor.
The CNT experienced rapid growth from the time of its formation. By the
outbreak of the Civil War in 1936 it had almost two million members. Its
strongholds were in Catatonia and in Andalusia. It also had large
followings in Galicia, Asturias, Levant, Saragossa and Madrid. Its main
strength was among textile, building and wood workers as well as amongst
agricultural labourers. As it preached social revolution it was subject
to vicious repression not only under the semi-dictatorship which ruled
in Spain until 1931 but also the âreformingâ governments which followed.
The Popular Front Government in particular, with its social democratic
and Stalinist supporters, showed no mercy to the anarchist movement.
The revolution that overtook Spain in July 1936 [120] occurred initially
as a response to the attempted coup by the military led by General
Franco. The response to the coup in Catalonia, and Aragon and in many
other places where the anarchists were strong, was the fruition of years
of direct action and direct democracy in the Spanish workersâ movement.
Immediately the popular movement that had resisted the fascists moved
beyond the notion of restoring âparliamentary democracyâ and began to
implement a new democratic society.
ON THE LAND: Collectivisation of the land was extensive. Close on two
thirds of all land in the Republican zone (that area controlled by the
anti-fascist forces) was taken over. In all between five and seven
million peasants were involved. The major areas were Aragon where there
were 450 collectives, the Levant (the area around Valencia) with 900
collectives and Castille (the area surrounding Madrid) with 300
collectives. Not only was the land collectivised but in the villages
workshops were set up where the local trades-people could produce tools,
furniture, etc. Bakers, butchers, barbers and so on also decided to
collectivise.
Collectivisation was voluntary and thus quite different from the forced
âcollectivisationâ presided over by Stalin in Russia. Usually a meeting
was called in the village (most collectives were centred on a particular
village) and all present would agree to pool together whatever land,
tools and animals they had. This âpoolâ would be added to what had
already been taken from the big landowners. The land was divided into
rational units and groups of workers were assigned to work them. Each
group had its delegate who represented their views at meetings of the
collective. A management committee was also elected and was responsible
for the overall running of the collective. They would look after the
buying of materials, exchanges with other areas, distributing the
produce and necessary public works such as the building of schools. Each
collective held regular general meetings of all its participants. If you
didnât want to join the collective you were given some land but only as
much as you could work yourself. You were not allowed to employ workers.
Production was changed by the Revolution but so was distribution. This
was altered so as to be on the basis of what people needed. In many
areas money was abolished. People come to the collective store (often
churches which had been turned into warehouses) and got what was
available. If there were shortages, rationing was introduced to ensure
that everyone got their fair share. But it was usually the case that
production increased under the new system, thereby eliminating
shortages.
In agricultural terms the revolution occurred at a good time. Harvests
that would normally have been sold off to make big profits for a few
landowners were instead distributed to those in need. Doctors, bakers,
barbers, etc. were given what they needed in return for their services.
Where money was not abolished a âfamily wageâ was introduced so that
payment was on the basis of need and not the number of hours worked.
Production increased greatly. Technicians and agronomists helped the
peasants to make better use of the land. Modern scientific methods were
introduced and in some areas yields increased by as much as 50%. There
was enough to feed the collectivists and the militias in their areas.
Often there was enough for exchange with other collectives in the cities
for machinery. In addition food was handed over to the supply committees
who looked after distribution in the urban areas.
Federations of collectives were established, the most successful being
in Aragon. In June 1937 a plenum of Regional Federations of Peasants was
held. Its aim was the formation of a national federation âfor the
co-ordination and extension of the collectivist movement and also to
ensure an equitable distribution of the produce of the land, not only
between the collectives but for the whole countryâ. Unfortunately many
collectives were smashed, not by Francoâs army but by the soldiers of
the Stalinist General Lister, before this could be done.
The collectivists were not only concerned with their material well
being. They had a deep commitment to education and as a result of their
efforts many children received an education for the first time. This was
not the usual schooling either. The methods of Francisco Ferrer, the
world famous anarchist educationalist, were employed. Children were
given basic literacy skills and after that inquisitive skills were
encouraged. Old people were also looked after and where necessary
special homes for them were built. Refugees from the fascist controlled
areas were looked after too.
IN THE CITY: In industry the situation was a little different. The
collectivisation was not as extensive in urban areas but it still
occurred on a huge scale. In Barcelona over 3,000 enterprises were
collectivised. All the public services, not only in Catalonia but
throughout the Republican zone, were taken over and run by committees of
workers.
To give some idea of the extent of the collectivisation here is a list
provided by one observer [121] . He says
ârailways, traincars and buses, taxicabs and shipping, electric light
and power companies, gasworks and waterworks, engineering and automobile
assembly plants, mines and cement works, textile mills and paper
factories, electrical and chemical concerns, glass bottle factories and
perfumeries, food processing plants and breweries were confiscated and
controlled by workmenâs (sic) committees, either term possessing for the
owners almost equal significance ... Motion picture theatres and
legitimate theatres, newspapers and printing, shops, department stores
and hotels, deluxe restaurants and bars were likewise sequestered.â
Often the workplaces were seized because the owners had fled or had
stopped production to sabotage the revolution. But the workers did not
stop with these workplaces â all major places of work were taken over.
Some were run and controlled by the workers. In others âcontrol
committeesâ were established to ensure that production was maintained
(these existed to exercise a power of veto on the decisions of the boss
in cases where the workers had not taken over the actual power of
management).
In each workplace an assembly of all the workers was the basic unit.
Within the factory workers would elect delegates to represent them on
day-to-day issues. Anything of overall importance had to go to the
assembly. This would elect a committee of between five and fifteen
workers, which would elect a manager to oversee the day-to-day running
of the workplace. Within each industry there was an Industrial Council
which had representatives of the two main unions (CNT and UGT) and
representatives from the committees. Technicians were also on these
committees to provide technical advice. The job of the Industrial
Council was to set out an overall plan for the industry.
The Barcelona trams are a good example of what workers achieved when
they took over:
Out of the 7,000 workers on the tramways at the time of the Revolution,
some 6,500 were members of the CNT. Because of the street battles, all
transport had been brought to a halt. The transport syndicate (as unions
of the CNT were known) appointed a commission of seven to occupy the
administrative offices while others inspected the tracks and drew up a
plan of repair work that needed to be done. Five days after the fighting
stopped 700 tramcars, instead of the usual 600, all painted in the black
and red colours of the CNT, were operating on the streets of Barcelona.
With the profit motive gone, safety became more important and the number
of accidents was reduced. Fares were lowered and services improved. In
1936, over 183 million passengers were carried. By 1937 this had gone up
to over 233 million. The trams were running so efficiently that the
workers were able to give money to other sections of urban transport.
Wages were equalised for all workers and increased over the previous
rates. For the first time free medical care was provided for the work
force.
Extensive reorganisation took place to make industry more efficient.
Many uneconomic small plants, which were usually unhealthy, were closed
down and production was concentrated in those plants with the best
equipment. In Catalonia 70 foundries were closed down. The number of
tanning plants was reduced from 71 to 40 and the whole wood industry was
reorganised by the CNT Woodworkers Union.
In 1937 the central government admitted that the war industry of
Catalonia produced ten times more than the rest of Spanish industry put
together and that this output could have been quadrupled if Catalonia
had the access to the necessary means of purchasing raw materials.
As with the examples of rural collectivisation, distribution was also
changed. Many parasitic âmiddlemenâ were cut out of distribution. The
wholesale business in fish and eggs was taken over as were the principal
fruit and vegetable markets. The milk trade in Barcelona was
collectivised which saw over 70 un-hygienic pasteurising plants closed
down. Everywhere supply committees were set up. All of this made the
middle classes very unhappy. To them, with their notions of becoming
bigger bosses, the revolution was a step backwards.
Equalisation funds were established to help out the poorer collectives.
Indeed there were many problems. Many markets were cut off in the
fascist zone and some foreign markets were also temporarily lost. Raw
materials were often scarce, as sources of supply had been cut off;
there was the added problem that money was held back from the
collectives by the central government (for political reasons). This was
one serious, though artificial, short-coming of the collectivisation â
its lack of credit facilities which would have allowed investment and
future planning. (During the Revolution the banks had not been seized
and the gold reserve already referred to stayed in the hands of the
government. The CNT did hatch a plan to seize it, but backed down at the
last moment).
Despite all this, production was increased and living standards for many
working class people improved. In October 1936 the government was forced
to recognise the collectivisation by passing a decree that recognised
the fait accompli. It was also an attempt to control future
collectivisation.
This is only a very brief look at the collectivisation that happened.
But in keeping with anarchist beliefs the revolution did not stop there.
For the first time in Spain many workers had the benefit of a health
service â organised by the CNT Federation of Health Workers. The
Federation consisted of 40,000 health workers â nurses, doctors,
administrators and orderlies. Once again the major success was in
Catalonia where it ensured that all of the 2.5 million inhabitants had
adequate health care. Victims of the Civil War were also treated. A
programme of preventive medicine was also established based on local
community health centres. At their 1937 Congress these workers developed
a health plan for a future anarchist Spain which could have been
implemented if the revolution had been successful.
The importance of the workersâ collectives in Spain lie in the example
that they provide. Elitist opinion since time immemorial has portrayed
âpopular ruleâ as an impossibility on the one hand, or as a state of
affairs that is likely to result in a shambles, on the other. The
workers of Spain showed this to be entirely false â and showed this on a
grand scale. Now as much as then, they offer us a concrete idea of how
society can be organised by workers in a democratic and free way. This
is viable alternative.
Despite the power of such an example we are still faced with a difficult
and tough struggle ahead â how to end the capitalist system with its
greed, its misery and its competition. Now is as good a time as any to
consider how we should conduct this struggle, what its aims should be,
and what methods we should use. We must aim for revolution and we must
aim for real democracy. These are the essential goals, the points that
we must reach before we can ever change anything. To do this, we argue
as anarchists that we must build where we are actually strong â at work
and in the community. Our methods must build on class solidarity, they
must use direct action, they must aim to increase the self-activity of
workers and the poor; they must always encourage participation.
About one thing we have no doubts. Parliament will not bring us the
change that we now need. Parliament is a means of diffusing democracy,
of channelling real struggles into a safe dead-end. Time and time again
it has become a graveyard for the workersâ movement. That is a mistake
we must not repeat again.
[1]
S. Bowles and H. Gintis, Democracy and Capitalism (Routledge Keegan
Paul, 1986), p28.
[2] ibid., p28.
[3] ibid., p28.
[4]
A. Arblaster, The Rise And Decline Of Western Liberalism (Basil
Blackwell, 1984), p160.
[5] ibid., p160.
[6]
E. Hobsbawm, The Age Of Revolution (Mentor, 1962), p54.
[7] ibid., p168.
[8] ibid., p42.
[9] ibid., p45.
[10] ibid., p38.
[11] ibid., p49.
[12] ibid., p49.
[13] ibid., p49.
[14] ibid., p173
[15]
A. Arblaster, op. cit., p267.
[16] ibid., p265.
[17] ibid., p264.
[18] ibid., p265.
[19] ibid., p278.
[20] ibid., p278.
[21] ibid., p279.
[22] ibid., p280.
[23] ibid., p279.
[24] ibid., p279.
[25] ibid., p280.
[26] ibid., p278.
[27]
E. Hobsbawm, The Age of Capital (Mentor, 1975), p102.
[28] Norman Wintrop ed., Liberal Democratic Theory and Its Critics,
(Croom Helm, 1983) p33.
[29]
A. Arblaster, op. cit., p273.
[30] Stewart Edwards ed., The Communards of Paris, 1871 (Cornell
University Press, 1973) p31.
[31] Karl Marx, The Civil War In France, (Progress Press, 1979) p53.
[32] Stewart Edwards, op. cit., p34-39.
[33] Stewart Edwards ed., The Communards of Paris, 1871 (Cornell
University Press, 1973), p158.
[34] Reprints in Labour History, The Minersâ Next Step, (Pluto Press,
1973), p32.
[35]
N. Wintrop, op. Cit., p216.
[36]
G. Foote, The Labour Partyâs Political Thought, A History (Croom Helm,
1985),p28.
[37] ibid., p28.
[38] ibid., p31.
[39] ibid., p29.
[40] Norman Wintrop, op. cit., p216.
[41] V.I. Lenin, What Is To Be Done (Progress, 1947), p78.
[42] Norman Wintrop, op. cit., p312.
[43] ibid., p312.
[44]
G. Foote, op. cit., p48.
[45]
R. McMullin, The Light on the Hill (Oxford University Press, Australia,
1991),p6.
[46] Norman Wintrop, op. cit., p313.
[47] ibid., p313.
[48] ibid., p214.
[49]
R. McMullin, op. cit., p6.
[50] ibid., p38.
[51] ibid., p89-90.
[52] ibid., p71.
[53] ibid., p75.
[54] ibid., p38.
[55]
K. Laybourn, The Rise of Labour, 1890 -1979 (Edward Arnold, 1988), p57.
[56]
G. Foote, op cit., p55.
[57]
G. Foote, op cit., p56.
[58]
K. Laybourn, op cit., p58.
[59]
G. Foote, op cit., p56.
[60]
K. Laybourn, op cit., p57.
[61]
R. McMullin, op. cit. p90.
[62] Norman Wintrop, op. cit., p315.
[63] ibid., p315.
[64] ibid., p315.
[65]
R. McMullin, op cit., p1.
[66] ibid., p251.
[67] ibid., p251.
[68] Noam Chomsky, Deterring Democracy (Hill and Wang, 1991)p367-8. See
also references therein.
[69] ibid., p367.
[70] Noam Chomsky, âThe Struggle For Democracy In The New World Orderâ,
Low Intensity Democracy (Pluto Press, 1993), p81.
[71]
E. Herman and N. Chomsky, Manufacturing Consent (Pantheon, 1988).
[72] Barry Gillis, op. cit., p47.
[73] Economist, 11 June 1994, p54.
[74] Economist, 15 July 1995, p24.
[75] Economist, 15 July 1995 p25
[76] Economist, 23 September 1995 p43
[77] Economist, 29 April 1995, Survey p24.
[78] Economist, 23 September 1995, p44.
[79] Economist, April 29. 1995, Survey p10.
[80] G.T. Kurian Ed., The New Book Of World Rankings, (Facts On File,
1991), Table 52.
[81] Interview for Indian Business Report, BBC Asia, 1 August 1993.
[82] see âReformsâ, Times of India, 28 September 1993.
[83] p61, Economist, June 3, 1995.
[84] see âReformsâ, Times of India, 28 September 1993.
[85] see âHistoric FallĂâ, The Australian, 5 March 1993.
[86] Peter Roberts, Australian Financial Review, 23 March 1993.
[87] âKeating sets reform agenda Ăâ, The Australian, 22 April 1993.
[88] see in Noam Chomsky, âThe Struggle For Democracy In The New World
Orderâ, Low Intensity Democracy (Pluto Press, 1993), p87.
[89] Economist, 25 November 1995, p31.
[90] Economist, 25 September 1993, p66.
[91] Economist, 25 September 1993, p66.
[92] Economist, 7 October 1995, Survey, p5.
[93] Economist, 4 June 1994, p51.
[94]
S. Padgett and W. Paterson, A History of Social Democracy in Post-war
Europe (Longman, 1991), p189.
[95] ibid., p189.
[96] The Irish Times, 17 December 1994.
[97] The Irish Times, 22 March 1994.
[98] Financial Times, 8 August 8 1996.
[99] Andre Gunder Frank in âMarket Democracy In An Undemocratic Marketâ,
Low Intensity Democracy (Pluto, 1993) p52.
[100] ibid., p52.
[101] For a recent account of the trends see also âSurvey of the World
Economyâ, Economist, 7 Oct. 1995.
[102]
I. Roxborough, P. OâBrien, J Roddick, Chile: The State And Revolution,
Macmillan Press 1977, p161.
[103] Kevin Phillips, The Politics Of Rich And Poor (HarperPerennial,
1990), pp9-10.
[104] ibid., p11
[105] Economist, 11 May 1996, pp53-54.
[106] E.B. Atkinson, Ed., Wealth, Income and Inequality (Oxford
University Press, 1980), p75.
[107] N Wintrop, ed., op. cit., p318.
[108] ibid., p323.
[109] ibid., p318.
[110]
S. Padgett, op. cit., p176.
[111] Report UNâs World Development Report, Independent On Sunday, 24
July 1996, p1.
[112]
S. Padgett, op. cit., p176.
[113]
S. Padgett, op. cit., pp167-170.
[114]
R. McMullin, p 431.
[115]
R. McMullin, p 432.
[116] Economist, 25 August, 1995.
[117] See most recent survey by ESRI in The Irish Times, 20 December,
1996
[118] C.B. Macpherson, The Real World Of Democracy (Clarendon Press,
1967),pp1-2.
[119] see A. Bauer, With The Peasants Of Aragon (Cienfuegos Press,
1982); G. Leval, Collectives In The Spanish Revolution (Freedom Press,
1975); S. Dolgoff, Workers Self-Management: Anarchist Collectives In The
Spain, 1936â39 (Black Rose, 1990).
[120] see E. Conlon, The Spanish Civil War: Anarchism In Action (WSM
Pamphlets, 1993); P. Preston, A Concise History Of The Spanish Civil War
(Fontana Press, 1996).
[121]
B. Bolloten, The Grand Camoflage (New York: Praeger, 1968).