đž Archived View for library.inu.red âş file âş carlo-cafiero-karl-marx-s-capital.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 08:25:30. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄď¸ Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Karl Marxâs *Capital* Author: Carlo Cafiero Date: 1879 Language: en Topics: Marxism, scientific socialism Source: Retrieved on 2020-07-31 from [[https://www.marxists.org/archive/cafiero/1879/summary-of-capital.htm]] Notes: Translated by Paul M. Perrone in 2018. See this in Italian: https://www.marxists.org/italiano/marx-engels/1867/capitale/compendiocafiero.html.
Itâs with great pride and anticipation that I present this first
complete English translation of Carlo Cafieroâs summary of Karl Marxâs
Capital. My ultimate hope is that this work will further Cafieroâs
original goal in writing this book: to develop class consciousness and
the knowledge of basic Marxian economics among workers, activists, and
students. Given the length of Capital, Volume 1, those without the
adequate time or skill set may be put off in reading it in its entirety.
However, this summary, while not a substitute, is undoubtedly an
adequate primer. Not only is it an easily digestible length, but it
fully encapsulates the major points of Marxâs analysis of production,
accumulation of capital, and the exploitation of labor. Cafieroâs
dynamic and impassioned prose is sure to inspire a similar feeling in
the hearts of readers, and his inclusion of large portions of Marxâs
original volume can also better acquaint modern readers with the
masterful writing and research skills embodied in Marx.
For the translation of this work, I tried as best as possible to render
Cafieroâs writing as easy to comprehend in English while still
maintaining the intentions and structure from the original Italian
publication. When it came to the citations Cafiero included from Marxâs
Capital, instead of translating into English his Italian translations of
the French translations of the original German text, which I figured
would be far too contrived, I opted to cite the 1887 English
translation, directly from the German, by Samuel Moore and Edward
Averling (and notably edited by Friedrich Engels).[1] This way, I
ensured that Marxâs original words would be as accurate as possible. The
synthesis of the work done by both men is, I find, a comprehensive image
of the entire breadth of the original first volume of Capital.
Cafiero, now all but forgotten in English leftist circles, is worthy of
further study by those of us in the modern age. Born to a bourgeois
family in southern Italy in 1846, he was a devoted revolutionary who
furthered the cause of anarcho-communism in Italy during his short life.
After being arrested for helping to inspire a failed insurrection in
Benevento in 1877, Cafiero drafted his summary of Capital in prison.
First published in 1879, this work was highly praised, even by Marx,
whose opinion of the work can be read in the Appendix at the end of this
translation. Sadly, Cafieroâs life following this publication took a
turn for the worse; intermittent periods of exile and return to Italy
coincided with the development of a serious mental illness that caused
Cafiero to attempt suicide on several occasions. He died of tuberculosis
in a mental hospital in Italy in 1892 at only 45.
I therefore dedicate this first English translation of Carlo Cafieroâs
summary of Capital to Cafiero himself. In this day and age, 200 years
since the birth of Marx and 150 years since the publication of the first
volume of Capital, these ideas, and the understanding of them, are more
necessary than ever.
Paul M. Perrone
2018
Marxists Internet Archive, 2008
Carlo Cafiero accomplished an important work in drafting this summary of
Capital, approved and looked over by experts and even by Marx himself,
not only because it is able to synthesize the thinking of the âmasterâ
in a few pages, but also because it is able to convey Capitalâs message
in an impassioned, yet concise, manner, in a tenacious and complete, as
well as illuminating, writing. It is not that this writing is sufficient
to ascertain all of the contents of that immense work and milestone that
is Marxâs Capital, but it certainly has the value and capacity to better
acquaint the reader with the universe of Marxist works, Capital
included; this is no small task in an age like ours, in which Marxism
unfortunately enjoys a lack of fame, due to the rule of bourgeois
capital and to so many preconceptions and false myths surrounding
communism.
One cannot blame communist groups and parties for this crisis, but above
all one can blame the historical and social doings that have
characterized the last twenty years, with the explosion of technology,
that has favored globalization and therefore a further reinforcement of
the bourgeoisie, which controls politics and media. It is exactly in
this context that, around two centuries later, the work that we have in
front of us gains tremendous truth, more than many contemporary
sociological writings.
Italy, March 1878
A profound feeling of sadness struck me, studying Capital, when I
thought that this work was, and who knows how much longer it would
remain, entirely unknown in Italy.
But if that is, I then said to myself, I want to say that my duty is to
work for all people, so that this would no longer be. And what to do? A
translation? Phew! That wouldnât help at all. The people who can
understand the work of Marx, such that he has written, certainly know
French, and can make use of J. Royâs beautiful translation, fully
reviewed by the author, who says it even deserves to be consulted by
those who speak the German language. Itâs a very different group of
people for whom I must work. Itâs divided into three categories: the
first is composed of workers gifted with intelligence and of a certain
education; the second, composed of young people who came out of the
bourgeoisie, and have embraced the cause of labor, but who for now donât
have the set of studies or the sufficient intellectual development to
understand Capital in its original text; the third, finally, composed of
the youngest in schools, still of pure heart, who I can compare to a
beautiful nursery of still tender plants, but who will bear the best
fruits, if transplanted into fertile soil. My work must therefore be an
easy and brief summary of Marxâs book.
This book represents the new true, which completely demolishes, crushes,
and disperses to the winds a secular edifice of mistakes and lies. It is
all a war. A glorious war, and by the power of the enemy, and by the
even greater power of the captain, who undertook it with great
quantities of the newest weapons, tools and machinery of every sort,
which his genius had known how to portray from all the modern sciences.
My work is a great length shorter and more modest. I must only guide a
crowd of willing followers along the shortest and simplest path to the
temple of capital; and to tear down that god there, so that all can see
with their own eyes and touch with their own hands the elements of which
it is composed; and to rip off the vestments from the priests, so that
all can see the hidden stains of human blood, and the cruelest weapons,
with which they go about, every day, sacrificing an ever-growing number
of victims.
And with these intentions I prepare to work. Meanwhile Marx can fulfill
his promise, giving us the second volume of Capital, which will deal
with The Process of Circulation of Capital (book II), and with The
Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole (book III), and the fourth
and final volume which will explain A History of Economic Theories.
This first book of Capital, originally written in German and afterwards
translated into Russian and into French, is now briefly summarized in
Italian in the interests of the cause of labor. May the workers read it
and think about it carefully because in it is contained not only the
story of The Development of Capitalist Production, but also The
Martyrdom of the Worker.
And finally, I will also appeal to a class highly interested in the fact
of capitalist accumulation, i.e. to the class of small property holders.
How is it that this class, once so widespread in Italy, shrinks more and
more every day? The reason is very simple. Because since 1860 Italy has
set course with more alacrity down the path, which all modern nations
must necessarily travel; the path that leads to capitalist accumulation,
which has reached that classic form in England, which Italy wishes to
reach along with all other modern nations. May the small property
holders meditating on these pages about the history of England reported
in this book, meditating on capitalist accumulation, increased in Italy
by the usurpations of big property holders and by the liquidation of
ecclesiastical and state property, shake off the torpor that oppresses
their minds and hearts, and once and for all persuade themselves that
their cause is the cause of the workers, because they will all
inevitably be reduced, by modern capitalist accumulation, to this sad
condition: either sell themselves to the government for a loaf of bread,
or disappear forever within the dense rows of the proletariat.
A commodity is an object that has two values; a use value and an
exchange value, or an appropriately determined value. If I have, for
example, 20 kilos of coffee, I can either consume it for my own use, or
exchange it for 20 meters of canvas, or for a suit, or for 250 grams of
silver, if, instead of coffee, I need one of these three commodities.
The use value of a commodity is based on the actual qualities of the
commodity itself, is meant to equal such qualities based on its
qualities, and not any other needs. The use value of 20 kilos of coffee
is based on the qualities of the coffee; these qualities being such that
they make it clear to all that it is apt for us to drink, but they donât
enable us to clothe ourselves, or give us material for a shirt. It is
for this reason that we are able to gain from the use value of 20 kilos
of coffee, only if we feel the desire to drink coffee; but if instead we
need a shirt, or to wear a suit that costs the use value of 20 kilos of
coffee, we donât know what to do; or, to say it better, we wouldnât know
what to do, if alongside the use value, there wasnât, in the commodity,
the exchange value. We in fact find another who has a suit, but who
doesnât need it, and needs coffee instead. Now one makes a trade right
away. We give him the 20 kilos of coffee and he gives us the suit.
But does it follow that the commodities, while they differ completely
between themselves because of their different qualities, that is for
their use values, can be exchanged one for the other? We have already
shown this.
Because, alongside the use value, there is also found an exchange value
in the commodity. Now, the foundation of the exchange value, or the
appropriately determined value, is the human labor needed for its
production. The commodity is made by the worker; human labor is the
life-force that gives it existence. All commodities therefore, although
theyâre different in quality, are substantially the same, because
daughters of the same father all have the same blood in their veins. If
20 kilos of coffee are exchanged for a suit, or for 20 meters of canvas,
it is indeed because the same amount of human labor is needed to produce
20 kilos of coffee as is needed to produce a suit, or 20 meters of
canvas. Therefore, the valueâs substance is human labor, and the size of
the value is determined from the amount of human labor itself. The
valueâs substance is the same in all commodities; therefore it does not
stand that they must be equal in size, because the commodities are, like
expressions of value, all equal to one another, i.e., all able to be
exchanged one for the other.
The size of the value depends on the amount of work; in 12 hours of work
one produces a value double that which is produced in only six hours of
work. Therefore, someone would say, the more one works and the longer
one works, save for disability or for laziness, the more value is
produced. Nothing is falser. Labor, which forms the substance of value,
isnât the work of a superhuman, but average labor, which is always the
same, and that is rightly called social labor. This is that work, which,
in a given center of production, can be averaged by a worker, who works
with an average ability and an average intensity.
The dual nature of commodities known, being, that is, use value and
exchange value, one will see that commodities can be born only by the
work of labor, and by labor that is useful to all. Air for example,
grasslands, virgin soil, etc. are useful to people, but donât constitute
any value to them, because they arenât the products of work and,
consequentially, arenât commodities. We can make ourselves objects for
our own personal uses, but which canât be useful for others; in such a
case we donât produce commodities; even less we produce commodities when
we work on objects, which do not have any usefulness either for us or
for others.
Commodities, therefore, are exchanged for each other; the one, that is,
that presents itself as the otherâs equivalent. For the greater comfort
of exchanges one begins to use always one given commodity as the
equivalent; that which so steps out from the rank of all the others, to
stand in front of them as a general equivalent; that is currency.
Currency therefore is that commodity which, by custom and by legal
sanction, has monopolized the position of the general equivalent. Thus
has happened for us with silver. While before 20 kilos of coffee, a
suit, 20 meters of canvas and 250 grams of silver were four commodities,
which were exchanged indistinctly for one another, today instead you
have that 20 kilos of coffee, 20 meters of canvas and a suit are three
commodities, which are worth 250 grams of silver, i.e. 50 lire.
However, whether the exchange is done immediately from commodity to
commodity, or the exchange is done by means of currency, the law of
exchange always remains the same. A commodity can never be exchanged
with another, if the labor that is needed to produce one is not equal to
the labor that is needed to produce the other. This law must be kept
well in mind, because above it is founded everything that we will
afterwards.
With the arrival of currency, immediate or direct exchanges, commodity
for commodity, end. Exchanges must all be done, from now on, through
currency; so that a commodity that wishes to transform into another,
must, first, from a commodity transform into currency, then from
currency transform itself again into a commodity. The formula of
exchanges, therefore, will not be a chain of commodities anymore, but a
chain of commodities and currency. See here:
CommodityâCurrencyâCommodityâCurrencyâCommodityâCurrency.
Now, if in this formula we find indicated the turns that make the goods,
in their successive transformations, we find equally marked the turns of
currency. It is from this same formula therefore that we will derive the
formula of capital.
When we find ourselves in possession of a certain accumulation of
commodities, or of currency, which is the same thing, we are owners of a
certain wealth. If we are able to give a body to this wealth, that is an
organism able to develop itself, we will have capital. Giving it a body,
or an organism able to develop itself, means to be born and to grow; and
in fact the essence of capital is placed precisely in the possibly
prolific nature of currency.
The resolution of the problem (to find the way to give birth to capital)
is contained in the resolution of another problem: to find a way to make
money grow progressively.
In the formula, which marks the turns of commodities and of currency, we
add, to the term currency, a mark of progressive growth indicating it,
for example, with a number and we will have:
CurrencyâCommoditiesâCurrencyšâCommoditiesâCurrency²âCommoditiesâCurrencyÂł.
This is the formula of capital.
Carefully examining the formula of capital, it can be noted in the last
analysis that the matter of the accrual of capital is resolved in the
following way: finding a commodity that profits more than what it costs;
finding a commodity that, in our hands, can give rise to value, so that,
by selling it, we come to amass more money than we spent to buy it. In
short, it must be an elastic commodity that, stretched however much in
our hands, can grow in value. This very singular commodity indeed exists
and it is called labor power, or labor force.
For example, here is a money-owner, who possesses a large amount of
wealth, and wants to use his wealth to give rise to capital. He comes
into the marketplace solely in search of labor power. Letâs follow his
process. He walks around the marketplace, and meet a proletarian, who
came solely to sell their only commodity: labor power. The worker,
however, is not selling his labor power in whole, not completely, but
only partly, for a given time, ie for a day, for a week, for a month,
etc. If he sold it altogether, of course, he would become a commodity
himself; he would no longer be a wage-worker, but the slave of his
owner.
The price of labor power is calculated in the following way. One takes
the cost of food, daily life, rent, and however many other things are
needed every year by a worker to maintain their labor power, always in
their normal state; one adds, to this first amount, the amount needed
every year by a worker to procreate, raise, and educate, according to
their condition, their children; one divides the total by 365, the
number of days in a year, and one will have how much, every day, is
required to maintain labor power, oneâs daily price, that is the daily
wages of the worker.
A part of this calculation is also that which is needed for the worker
to procreate, raise, and educate his children because these are the
future sources of labor power. If the proletarian sold all of his labor
power, instead of just a part, of course, he would become a commodity
himself, i.e. a slave of his owner, and his children would also be a
commodity, i.e. slaves, just like their parent, of their owner; but, by
taking only a part of the labor power of the proletarian away, he has
the right to keep the rest, which is found partially in himself and
partially in his children.
With this calculation we obtain the exact price of labor power. The law
of exchange, explained in the previous chapter, says that a commodity
cannot be exchanged with another if the labor that is needed to produce
the former is not equal to the labor that is needed to produce the
latter. Now, the labor that is needed to produce labor power is equal to
the labor needed to produce the things needed by the worker, and as a
consequence the value of those things necessary to the worker is equal
to the value of their labor power. Therefore if the worker needs 3 lire
every day for all of their necessities, itâs clear that 3 lire will be
the price of their labor power every day.
Now letâs suppose â a supposition never hurt anyone â that the daily
wages of a worker, found in the above manner, amount to 3 lire. Letâs
also suppose that, in 6 hours of work, one can produce 15 grams of
silver, which is equivalent to 3 lire. The money-owner has meanwhile
formed a contract with the proletarian, paying him for his labor power
at the correct price of 3 lire a day. Heâs a perfectly honest and
religious member of the bourgeoisie, for whom it may look good to
defraud the workerâs wages. He will be able to make the point that the
salary is paid to the worker at the end of the day or the end of the
week, that is after he has already completed his labor; because this is
also how itâs done with other commodities, whose value is realized in
use, like, for example, the rent for a house, or a small farm, whose
price one is able to pay at the expiring of terms.
There are three elements of the labor process: firstly, labor power;
secondly, raw materials; and thirdly, the means of production. Our
money-owner, after the labor power, also bought raw materials at the
market, namely cotton wool; the means of production, namely the workshop
with all of its tools, is good and ready; and, consequently, he has
nothing left to do than to make the way clear between his legs for the
work to begin.
â[W]e think we can perceive a change in the physiognomy of our dramatis
personae. He, who before was the money-owner, now strides in front as
capitalist; the possessor of labour-power follows as his labourer. The
one with an air of importance, smirking, intent on business; the other,
timid and holding back, like one who is bringing his own hide to market
and has nothing to expect but â a hidingâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
6).
Our characters arrive at the workshop, where the boss hurries to put his
worker to task, giving him 10 kilos of cotton wool, since he is a cotton
spinner.
Labor is made up of the utilization of the elements that compose it; the
utilization of labor power, raw materials, and means of production. The
utilization of the means of production is calculated in the following
way. From the sum of the value of all the means of production, the
building, radiators, coal, etc, one subtracts the sum of the value of
all of the raw materials that will remain of the means of production put
out by the consumption of use; one divides the result of this
subtraction by the number of days that the means of production can last,
and one will have the daily consumption of the means of production. Our
worker works a 12-hour day. When itâs over, he has transformed the 10
kilos of cotton wool into 10 kilos of thread, which he hands over to his
boss, and he leaves the workshop to shrink at home. Along the way,
however, for that ugly vice that workers have, to always want to reckon
behind the backs of their boss, he tries to find out in his mind how
much his boss will be able to earn off of those 10 kilos of thread.
âI donât rightly know how much the thread costs,â he says to himself,
but the amount is soon figured out. âI saw cotton wool when he bought it
at the market at 3 lire per kilo. All of the means of production cost 4
lire per day. Therefore:
â10 kilos of cotton wool: â¤30
âUtilization of the means of production: â¤4
âDaily salary: â¤3
âTotal: â¤37
âThe 10 kilos of thread are worth 37 lire. Now on the cotton wool he
certainly didnât gain anything, because he paid for it at the proper
price, neither a cent too much nor a cent too little; as for me, he pays
for my labor power 3 lire a day, the price that suits him; therefore it
must be the case that he profits by selling his thread for more than
itâs worth. It absolutely must be this way; otherwise he would be
spending 37 lire just to earn 37 lire, not counting the time that he
lost and the inconvenience that it took.
âNow look how the bosses do things! They have a good wish to make out
like honest people with the worker from whom they buy labor power, with
the merchant from whom they buy raw materials, but they have an eternal
flaw, and the rest of us workers, who know how the industry works, shall
go on strike. But to sell a commodity for more than it is worth is like
selling with false weights, which is illegal. Therefore, if the workers
were to expose their bossesâ tricks, they would be forced to close their
factories; and to produce goods based on need, maybe they would open
large government facilities; that would be much better.â
So the daydreaming worker arrived at home; and there, dined, went to
bed, and slept deeply, dreaming of the disappearance of bosses and the
creation of government workshops.
Sleep, poor friend, sleep in peace, while hope still rests within you.
Sleep in peace, for the disappointing day will soon come. Soon you will
learn how your boss can sell their goods for profit, without defrauding
anyone. He will make you see how one becomes a capitalist, and a large
capitalist, while remaining perfectly honest.
Now your dreams will never again be so peaceful. You will see capital in
your nights, like a nightmare, that presses you and threatens to crush
you. With terrified eyes you will see it get fatter, like a monster with
one hundred proboscises that feverishly search the pores of your body to
suck your blood. And finally you will learn to assume its boundless and
gigantic proportions, its appearance dark and terrible, with eyes and
mouth of fire, morphing its suckers into enormous hopeful trumpets,
within which youâll see thousands of human beings disappear: men, women,
children. Down your face will trickle the sweat of death, because your
time, and that of your wife and your children will soon arrive. And your
final moan will be drowned out by the happy sneering of the monster,
glad with your state, so much richer, so much more inhumane.
Letâs return to our money-owner. This bourgeois, a model of accuracy and
of order, has adjusted all of his daily counts; and here is how he has
figured the price of his 10 kilos of thread:
For 10 kilos of cotton wool at 3 lire per kilo â â¤30
For the utilization of the means of production â â¤4
But around the third element, fitting into the production of his
commodity, he has not noted the salary paid to the worker. He knows very
well that a large difference occurs between the price of labor and the
product of labor power. A daily salary represents how much is needed to
sustain the worker for 24 hours, but it doesnât by any means represent
what the worker produces in one day of work.
Our money-owner knows very well that the 3 lire of salary he paid paid
represent the upkeep for 24 hours for his worker, but not that which he
produced in the 12 hours that he worked in his factory. He knows all of
this, precisely as a farmer knows the difference that occurs between
what it costs to maintain a cow in a stable, to feed it, etc, and what
is produced in milk, cheese, butter, etc. Labor power has the singular
quality to give something more worth than it cost and it is for this
exactly this fact that the money-owner went to purchase it in the
marketplace.
The worker has nothing to smile about. He took the fair price for his
good; the law of exchanges was observed perfectly; and he doesnât have
the right to tell the buyer what to do with the commodity, like how a
grocer canât tell their patron how to use the sugar and pepper bought in
their shop.
We have supposed above that, in 6 hours of work, 15 grams of silver are
produced, equivalent to 3 lire. Therefore, if in 6 hours the labor power
produces a value of 3 lire, in 12 hours it will produce a value of 6
lire. Here therefore is the calculation, which states the value of 10
kilos of thread:
10 kilos of cotton wool at 3 lire per kilo: â¤30
Use of the means of production: â¤4
12 hours of labor power: â¤6
Total: â¤40
The money-owner has therefore spent 37 lire and has obtained a commodity
that is worth 40 lire; so he gained 3 lire; his money has increased.
The problem is unraveled. Capital is born.
Capital, just born, feels quickly the need for nourishment to develop
itself; and the capitalist, who lives now but for the life of the
capital, attentively worries about the needs of this being, which has
become his heart and soul, and he finds a way to satisfy himself.
The first method, employed by the capitalist in favor of his capital, is
the extension of the workday. Itâs certain that the workday has its
limits. Foremost, a day only consists of 24 hours; it is then necessary
from these 24 hours to cut a certain number, because the worker must
satisfy all his physical and moral needs: to sleep, feed himself, rest
his strength, etc.
âBut both these limiting conditions are of a very elastic nature, and
allow the greatest latitude. So we find working-days of 8, 10, 12, 14,
16, 18 hours, i.e., of the most different lengths.
âThe capitalist has bought the labour-power at its day-rate. To him its
use-value belongs during one working-day. He has thus acquired the right
to make the labourer work for him during one day. But, what is a
working-day?
âAt all events, less than a natural day. By how much? The capitalist has
his own views of this ultima Thule [the outermost limit], the necessary
limit of the working-day. As capitalist, he is only capital personified.
His soul is the soul of capital. But capital has one single life
impulse, the tendency to create value and surplus-value, to make its
constant factor, the means of production, absorb the greatest possible
amount of surplus-labour.
âCapital is dead labour, that, vampire-like, only lives by sucking
living labour, and lives the more, the more labour it sucks. The time
during which the labourer works, is the time during which the capitalist
consumes the labour-power he has purchased of him.
âIf the labourer consumes his disposable time for himself, he robs the
capitalist.
âThe capitalist then takes his stand on the law of the exchange of
commodities. He, like all other buyers, seeks to get the greatest
possible benefit out of the use-value of his commodity. Suddenly the
voice of the labourer, which had been stifled in the storm and stress of
the process of production, rises:
ââThe commodity that I have sold to you differs from the crowd of other
commodities, in that its use creates value, and a value greater than its
own. That is why you bought it. That which on your side appears a
spontaneous expansion of capital, is on mine extra expenditure of
labour-power. You and I know on the market only one law, that of the
exchange of commodities. And the consumption of the commodity belongs
not to the seller who parts with it, but to the buyer, who acquires it.
To you, therefore, belongs the use of my daily labour-power. But by
means of the price that you pay for it each day, I must be able to
reproduce it daily, and to sell it again. Apart from natural exhaustion
through age, &c., I must be able on the morrow to work with the same
normal amount of force, health and freshness as to-day. You preach to me
constantly the gospel of âsavingâ and âabstinence.â Good! I will, like a
sensible saving owner, husband my sole wealth, labour-power, and abstain
from all foolish waste of it. I will each day spend, set in motion, put
into action only as much of it as is compatible with its normal
duration, and healthy development. By an unlimited extension of the
working-day, you may in one day use up a quantity of labour-power
greater than I can restore in three. What you gain in labour I lose in
substance. The use of my labour-power and the spoliation of it are quite
different things. If the average time that (doing a reasonable amount of
work) an average labourer can live, is 30 years, the value of my
labour-power, which you pay me from day to day is 1/(365Ă30) or 1/10950
of its total value. But if you consume it in 10 years, you pay me daily
1/10950 instead of 1/3650 of its total value, i.e., only 1/3 of its
daily value, and you rob me, therefore, every day of 2/3 of the value of
my commodity. You pay me for one dayâs labour-power, whilst you use that
of 3 days. That is against our contract and the law of exchanges. I
demand, therefore, a working-day of normal length, and I demand it
without any appeal to your heart, for in money matters sentiment is out
of place. You may be a model citizen, perhaps a member of the Society
for the Prevention of Cruelty to Animals, and in the odour of sanctity
to boot; but the thing that you represent face to face with me has no
heart in its breast. That which seems to throb there is my own
heart-beating. I demand the normal working-day because I, like every
other seller, demand the value of my commodity.â
âWe see then, that, apart from extremely elastic bounds, the nature of
the exchange of commodities itself imposes no limit to the working-day,
no limit to surplus-labour. The capitalist maintains his rights as a
purchaser when he tries to make the working-day as long as possible, and
to make, whenever possible, two working-days out of one. On the other
hand, the peculiar nature of the commodity sold implies a limit to its
consumption by the purchaser, and the labourer maintains his right as
seller when he wishes to reduce the working-day to one of definite
normal duration. There is here, therefore, an antinomy, right against
right, both equally bearing the seal of the law of exchanges. Between
equal rights force decidesâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 10, sec. 1).
We will now see exposed how force acts, as told by the facts, when all
is made by and for capital. The facts cited in this book are all taken
from England: primarily, because this is the country where capitalist
production has reached the greatest development, towards which the rest
of all civilized countries tend; and, in the second place, because only
in England is there a suitable amount of documents, regarding the
conditions of work, collected by regular government commissions. The
modest limits of this summary, however, only allow for a reproduction of
a small part of the rich materials collected in the work of Marx.
âWilliam Wood, 9 years old, was 7 years and 10 months when he began to
work. He âran mouldsâ (carried ready-moulded articles into the
drying-room, afterwards bringing back the empty mould) from the
beginning. He came to work every day in the week at 6 a.m., and left off
about 9 p.m. ââ work till 9 oâclock at night six days in the week. I
have done so seven or eight weeks.â
âFifteen hours of labour for a child 7 years old! J. Murray, 12 years of
age, says: âI turn jigger, and run moulds. I come at 6. Sometimes I come
at 4. I worked all night last night, till 6 oâclock this morning. I have
not been in bed since the night before last. There were eight or nine
other boys working last night. All but one have come this morning. I get
3 shillings and sixpence. I do not get any more for working at night. I
worked two nights last weekâŚâ
âMr. Charles Parsons, late house surgeon of the same institution, writes
in a letter to Commissioner Longe, amongst other things:
ââI can only speak from personal observation and not from statistical
data, but I do not hesitate to assert that my indignation has been
aroused again and again at the sight of poor children whose health has
been sacrificed to gratify the avarice of either parents or employers.â
He enumerates the causes of the diseases of the potters, and sums them
up in the phrase, âlong hoursâŚâ
âHalf the workers [in matchstick factories] are children under thirteen,
and young persons under eighteen. The manufacture is on account of its
unhealthiness and unpleasantness in such bad odour that only the most
miserable part of the labouring class, half-starved widows and so forth,
deliver up their children to it, âthe ragged, half-starved, untaught
children.â
âOf the witnesses that Commissioner White examined (1863), 270 were
under 18, 50 under 10, 10 only 8, and 5 only 6 years old. A range of the
working-day from 12 to 14 or 15 hours, night-labour, irregular
meal-times, meals for the most part taken in the very workrooms that are
pestilent with phosphorus. Dante would have found the worst horrors of
his Inferno surpassed in this manufactureâŚ
âIn the manufacture of paper-hangings the coarser sorts are printed by
machine; the finer by hand (block-printing). The most active business
months are from the beginning of October to the end of April. During
this time the work goes on fast and furious without intermission from 6
a.m. to 10 p.m. or further into the night.
âJ. Leach deposes:
ââLast winter six out of nineteen girls were away from ill-health at one
time from over-work. I have to bawl at them to keep them awake.â W.
Duffy: âI have seen when the children could none of them keep their eyes
open for the work; indeed, none of us could.â J. Lightbourne: âAm 13 ...
We worked last winter till 9 (evening), and the winter before till 10. I
used to cry with sore feet every night last winter.â G. Apsden: âThat
boy of mine when he was 7 years old I used to carry him on my back to
and fro through the snow, and he used to have 16 hours a day ... I have
often knelt down to feed him as he stood by the machine, for he could
not leave it or stopâŚâ
âIn the last week of June, 1863, all the London daily papers published a
paragraph with the âsensationalâ heading, âDeath from simple over-work.â
It dealt with the death of the milliner, Mary Anne Walkley, 20 years of
age, employed in a highly-respectable dressmaking establishment,
exploited by a lady with the pleasant name of Elise. The old, often-told
story, was once more recounted. This girl worked, on an average, 16½
hours, during the season often 30 hours, without a break, whilst her
failing labour-power was revived by occasional supplies of sherry, port,
or coffee. It was just now the height of the season. It was necessary to
conjure up in the twinkling of an eye the gorgeous dresses for the noble
ladies bidden to the ball in honour of the newly-imported Princess of
Wales. Mary Anne Walkley had worked without intermission for 26½ hours,
with 60 other girls, 30 in one room, that only afforded 1/3 of the cubic
feet of air required for them. At night, they slept in pairs in one of
the stifling holes into which the bedroom was divided by partitions of
board. And this was one of the best millinery establishments in London.
Mary Anne Walkley fell ill on the Friday, died on Sunday, without, to
the astonishment of Madame Elise, having previously completed the work
in hand. The doctor, Mr. Keys, called too late to the death-bed, duly
bore witness before the coronerâs jury that
ââMary Anne Walkley had died from long hours of work in an over-crowded
work-room, and a too small and badly ventilated bedroomâŚâ
âIn Marylebone, blacksmiths die at the rate of 31 per thousand per
annum, or 11 above the mean of the male adults of the country in its
entirety. The occupation, instinctive almost as a portion of human art,
unobjectionable as a branch of human industry, is made by mere excess of
work, the destroyer of the manâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 10, sec. 3).
This is how capital whips labor, which, after much suffering, searches
until the end to resist it. The workers unite and demand, to the powers
that be, the establishment of a normal workday. One may easily
comprehend how much of this they are able to obtain, considering that
the law must be made and upheld by the capitalists themselves, against
whom the workers would like to contend.
Labor power, producing a greater value than how much something is worth,
that is a âsurplus,â has created capital; enlarging then this surplus
value with prolongation of the workday, has given sufficient nourishment
to the capital for its infancy. The capital grows, and the surplus value
must increase to satisfy the grown need. Increase of surplus value,
however, does not mean, like we saw before, the extension of the
workday, which eventually also has its necessary limits, although it is
a very elastic length. For what little time there is that the capitalist
leaves to the worker for the satisfaction of his most basic needs, the
workday will always be less than 24 hours. The workday meets then a
natural limit, and the surplus value, consequently, an insurmountable
obstacle. Letâs represent the workday with the line AâB.
A-------D-------C----------------B
The letter A here represents the beginning and B the end, that natural
limit, that is, past which it isnât possible to go. A-C is the part of
the day in which the worker produces the value of the salary received
and C-B the part of the day in which the worker produces surplus value.
We see that our cotton spinner, in fact, receiving 3 lire in salary, was
reproducing the value of his salary with half of his day, and was
producing 3 lire of surplus value with the other. The work done from
A-C, with which the salaryâs value is produced, is necessary labor,
while the work done from C-B, which produces surplus value, is called
exploitation.
The capitalist is thirsty for exploitation, because it is this that
creates surplus value. Prolonged exploitation prolongs the workday,
which finishes at its natural limit B, which represents an
insurmountable obstacle to exploitation and surplus value. What to do
now? The capitalist soon finds the solution. He observes that
exploitation has two limits, one B, the end of the workday, the other C,
the end of the necessary work; if the limit B is fixed, it wonât be so
for limit C. Being able to move the point C all the way to point D, one
would grow the exploitation from C-B the length of D-C, exactly how much
the necessary work from A-C would decrease. Surplus value would thus
find a way to continue growing, not in the absolute way like at first,
which is by always prolonging the workday, but in relation to the growth
of exploitation with the corresponding decrease in necessary work. The
first was absolute surplus value, this is relative surplus value.
Relative surplus value is founded upon the decreasing of necessary work;
the decreasing of necessary work is founded upon the decreasing of
wages; the decreasing of wages is founded upon a decrease in prices of
things that are necessary for the worker; therefore relative surplus
value is founded on the depreciation of the commodities that the worker
uses.
And there would be an even quicker way of producing relative surplus
value, someone will say, and that would be to pay the worker a salary
less than that which he is due, that is not to pay him the proper price
of his commodity, labor power. We cannot consider this expedient, used
often in fact, minimally, because we arenât admitting that itâs the most
perfect observance of the law of exchange, according to which all
commodities, and consequently labor power as well, must be sold and
bought at their proper value.
Our capitalist, like we already saw, is an absolutely honest bourgeois;
he will never use, to enlarge his capital, a method that is not entirely
worthy of him.
Letâs suppose that, in a workday, a worker produces 6 items of a
commodity, that the capitalist sells for the price of â¤7,50, because in
the value of this commodity the raw materials and the means of
production come to â¤1,50 and 12 hours of labor power come to 6 lire: all
three components, therefore, come to â¤7,50. The capitalist finds a
surplus value of 3 lire on the value of â¤7,50, the cost of his
commodity, and on top of every component a surplus value of â¤0,50,
because he spends â¤0,75 and extracts â¤1,25 from each of these. Letâs
suppose that with a new system of work, or just with perfection of the
old way, production doubles, and that, instead of 6 items a day, the
capitalist is able to attain 12. If in 6 items the raw materials and the
means of production come to â¤1,50, in 12 he will come to 3 lire, that is
every item comes to â¤0,25. Those 3 lire combined with the 6 lire
produced by labor power in 12 hours, make 9 lire, that is how much the
12 items cost, each one of which therefore comes to the price of â¤0,75.
Now the capitalist needs to make himself a larger place in the market to
sell a double quantity of his commodity; and you can do this by somewhat
restricting the price. In other words, the capitalist needs to make a
reason arise for which he is able to sell their items on the market in
twice the number as before; and the reason is found exactly in price
reduction. He will sell, therefore, his items at a price somewhat lower
than â¤1,25, which was his price before, but greater than â¤0,75 (how much
each one of these is truly worth). He with sell them at a lira each, and
so he will have secured doubled sales of his items, from which he now
gains 6 lire; 3 lire of surplus value and 3 lire of difference between
their value and the price at which they are sold.
As you can see, the capitalist gains a great profit from this growth of
production. All capitalists are therefore highly interested in
increasing the products of their industries, and it is with this that
they are able to make this happen every day in any kind of production.
Their extraordinary gain, however, that which represents the difference
between the value of the commodity and the price at which it is sold,
doesnât last long, because right away the new or perfected system of
production becomes adopted by all out of necessity. So now as a result
the value of the commodity lessens by half. At first every item was
worth â¤1,25; now instead itâs worth 62 ½ cents. The capitalist however
always attains a profit, having doubled production. At first 3 lire of
surplus value for 6 items and now 3 lire of surplus value for 12 items;
but given that the 12 items are produced in the same time the 6 items
were made, that is in 12 hours of work, he always has as a final result
3 lire of surplus value for one 12-hour workday, but double the
production.
When this increase in production is regarding goods necessary to the
worker, it consequently carries the lowering of the price of labor
power, and therefore the lessening of necessary work and the increase of
exploitation, which makes up relative surplus value.
Itâs been a bit since we havenât dealt with the facts of our capitalist,
who must have certainly prospered in the meantime. Letâs go back to his
workshop, where we may have the pleasure of seeing our friend, the
spinner, again. Here we are. Letâs enter.
Oh, surprise! Thereâs no longer one worker, but now a large number of
workers find themselves at work. All quiet and in order as if they were
many soldiers. The lack of guards and inspectors is seen as supervisors
who walk among the ranks, all observing, giving orders, or overseeing
the the execution is by the books. Of the capitalist nothing is seen,
not even a shadow. A glass door opens inside, maybe it will be him;
letâs see. Itâs a solemn person, but itâs not our capitalist. The
supervisors carefully stand around him, and they receive his orders with
the utmost attention. The sound of an electric doorbell is heard; one of
the supervisors runs to put his ear to the mouth of a metal tube, which
descends from the doorway along the wall; and and he soon comes to
announce to the director that the boss demands a conference with him.
Letâs look in the crowd of workers for our old acquaintance the spinner;
and finally we come to find him in a corner, completely devoted to work.
Heâs become gaunt and pale in the face: on his face one reads a profound
thought of sadness. One day we saw him at the market negotiating his
labor power peer to peer with the money-owner; but how great the
distance between them has grown today! Today he is a worker lost in the
crowd of the many that populate the workshop, and oppressed by an
extraordinarily long workday; while the money-owner, whoâs already
become a big capitalist, stands like a god atop Mount Olympus, from
where he sends orders to his people through a group of intermediaries.
Whatsoever has happened? Itâs a piece of cake. The capitalist has
prospered. Capital has grown by a lot, and, in order to satisfy his new
needs, the capitalist has established cooperative labor, that is labor
done with a joining of forces. In this workshop, where at another time
only one labor force used to work, today there works a whole cooperation
of labor forces. Capital has gone out of its infancy, and presents
itself for the first time with its true appearance. The advantages that
capital finds in cooperation can be reduced to four. Firstly itâs in
cooperation that capital realizes true social labor power. Social labor
power being, as we already said, the average taken in a given center of
production among a number of workers who labor with an average degree of
ability and intensity, itâs clear that every single labor force will
move itself more or less from average or social force, which it
therefore can only obtain by gathering a great number of labor forces in
the same workshop; i.e. in cooperation.
The second advantage is the economics of the means of production. The
same workshop, the same heaters, etc., that used to serve only one, now
serve many workers.
The third advantage of cooperation is the growth of labor power.
âJust as the offensive power of a squadron of cavalry, or the defensive
power of a regiment of infantry is essentially different from the sum of
the offensive or defensive powers of the individual cavalry or infantry
soldiers taken separately, so the sum total of the mechanical forces
exerted by isolated workmen differs from the social force that is
developed, when many hands take part simultaneously in one and the same
undivided operation, such as raising a heavy weight, turning a winch, or
removing an obstacleâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 13).
The fourth advantage is the possibility to combine forces that are able
to execute tasks in a way that either wouldnât be able to be
accomplished with isolated efforts, or would be able to be accomplished
in a very flawed fashion. Who hasnât seen how 50 workers can move
enormous loads in one hour, while one labor force wouldnât be able to
move them, in 50 hours altogether, even one inch? Who hasnât seen how 12
workers, placed along the scaffolding of a house under construction, go
through a quantity of materials in one hour immensely greater than that
which one worker would go through in 12 hours? Who doesnât understand
how 20 bricklayers can do much more work in one day than only one can do
in 20 days?
âCo-operation ever constitutes the fundamental form of the capitalist
mode of productionâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 13).
When the Capitalist gathers the workers to perform the various tasks,
which make up all of the labor for a commodity, in his workshop, he
gives an entirely special nature to simple cooperation; he establishes
the division of labor and manufacturing; which is none other than âa
productive mechanism whose parts are human beingsâ (Marx, Capital, vol.
1, ch. 14, sec. 1).
Although manufacturing is always based on the division of labor, it also
has a double origin. In fact in some cases manufacturing has brought
together the different processing needs for the completion of a
commodity in the same workshop, which first, like so many special
trades, used to be distinct and divided up; in other cases it has
divided, while keeping them in the same workshop, the different work
operations, that before used to make up a whole of the completion of a
commodity.
âA carriage, for example, was formerly the product of the labour of a
great number of independent artificers, such as wheelwrights,
harness-makers, tailors, locksmiths, upholsterers, turners,
fringe-makers, glaziers, painters, polishers, gilders, &c. In the
manufacture of carriages, however, all these different artificers are
assembled in one building where they work into one anotherâs hands. It
is true that a carriage cannot be gilt before it has been made. But if a
number of carriages are being made simultaneously, some may be in the
hands of the gilders while others are going through an earlier processâ
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 1).
The production of a pin was divided into more than twenty partial
processes, which form the parts of the complete manufacture of a pin.
Manufacturing, therefore, sometimes brings many trades together into
only one, and sometimes divides a trade into many more.
Manufacturing multiplies the forces and instruments of labor, but
renders them predominantly technical and simple, constantly applying
them to one sole and unique basic operation.
Great are the advantages that capital realizes in manufacturing,
allocating different labor forces to the same basic operations
constantly. Labor power gains very much in intensity and precision. All
of those little intervals, which one finds like pores between the
different phases of production of a good created by only one individual,
disappear when this individual always executes the same operation. The
worker needs no more than an hour to learn all about a trade albeit a
simple one, a unique operation of the trade itself, which he learns in
much less time and with less expense than how much was needed to learn a
trade in its entirety. This diminishing of expense and time is a
diminishing of things needed for the worker, i.e. a diminishing of
necessary labor, and a corresponding growth of overwork and surplus
value. The capitalist, really a parasite, always grows fatter at the
expense of labor, and the worker suffers greatly.
âWhile simple co-operation leaves the mode of working by the individual
for the most part unchanged, manufacture thoroughly revolutionises it,
and seizes labour-power by its very roots. It converts the labourer into
a crippled monstrosity, by forcing his detail dexterity at the expense
of a world of productive capabilities and instincts; just as in the
States of La Plata they butcher a whole beast for the sake of his hide
or his tallow. Not only is the detail work distributed to the different
individuals, but the individual himself is made the automatic motor of a
fractional operation, and the absurd fable of Menenius Agrippa, which
makes man a mere fragment of his own body, becomes realisedâ (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
âDugald Stewart calls manufacturing labourers âliving automatons ...
employed in the details of the workââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14,
fn. 40).
âIf, at first, the workman sells his labour-power to capital, because
the material means of producing a commodity fail him, now his very
labour-power refuses its services unless it has been sold to capital.
Its functions can be exercised only in an environment that exists in the
workshop of the capitalist after the sale. By nature unfitted to make
anything independently, the manufacturing labourer develops productive
activity as a mere appendage of the capitalistâs workshop. As the chosen
people bore in their features the sign manual of Jehovah, so division of
labour brands the manufacturing workman as the property of capitalâ
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
Heinrich von Storch says: âThe worker who is the master of a whole craft
can work and find the means of subsistence anywhere; the other (the
manufacturing labourer) is only an appendage who, when he is separated
from his fellows, possesses neither capability nor independence, and
finds himself forced to accept any law it is thought fit to imposeâ
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, fn. 42).
âIntelligence in production expands in one direction, because it
vanishes in many others. What is lost by the detail labourers, is
concentrated in the capital that employs them. It is a result of the
division of labour in manufactures, that the labourer is brought face to
face with the intellectual potencies of the material process of
production, as the property of another, and as a ruling power. This
separation begins in simple co-operation, where the capitalist
represents to the single workman, the oneness and the will of the
associated labour. It is developed in manufacture which cuts down the
labourer into a detail labourer. It is completed in modern industry,
which makes science a productive force distinct from labour and presses
it into the service of capitalâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
âIn manufacture, in order to make the collective labourer, and through
him capital, rich in social productive power, each labourer must be made
poor in individual productive powers.
ââIgnorance is the mother of industry as well as of superstition.
Reflection and fancy are subject to err; but a habit of moving the hand
or the foot is independent of either. Manufactures, accordingly, prosper
most where the mind is least consulted, and where the workshop may ...
be considered as an engine, the parts of which are menâ (Adam Ferguson).
âAs a matter of fact, some few manufacturers in the middle of the
18^(th) century preferred, for certain operations that were trade
secrets, to employ half-idiotic persons.
ââThe understandings of the greater part of men,â says Adam Smith, âare
necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose whole
life is spent in performing a few simple operations ... has no occasion
to exert his understanding... He generally becomes as stupid and
ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become.â
âAfter describing the stupidity of the detail labourer he goes on:
ââThe uniformity of his stationary life naturally corrupts the courage
of his mind... It corrupts even the activity of his body and renders him
incapable of exerting his strength with vigour and perseverance in any
other employments than that to which he has been bred. His dexterity at
his own particular trade seems in this manner to be acquired at the
expense of his intellectual, social, and martial virtues. But in every
improved and civilised society, this is the state into which the
labouring poor, that is, the great body of the people, must necessarily
fall.â
âFor preventing the complete deterioration of the great mass of the
people by division of labour, A. Smith recommends education of the
people by the State, but prudently, and in homeopathic doses. G.
Garnier, his French translator and commentator, who, under the first
French Empire, quite naturally developed into a senator, quite as
naturally opposes him on this point. Education of the masses, he urges,
violates the first law of the division of labour, and with it âour whole
social system would be proscribed.â âLike all other divisions of
labour,â he says, âthat between hand labour and head labour is more
pronounced and decided in proportion as society (he rightly uses this
word, for capital, landed property and their State) becomes richer. This
division of labour, like every other, is an effect of past, and a cause
of future progress... ought the government then to work in opposition to
this division of labour, and to hinder its natural course? Ought it to
expend a part of the public money in the attempt to confound and blend
together two classes of labour, which are striving after division and
separation?ââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
Ferguson says: âAnd thinking itself, in this age of separations, may
become a peculiar craftâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, fn. 48).
âSome crippling of body and mind is inseparable even from division of
labour in society as a whole. Since, however, manufacture carries this
social separation of branches of labour much further, and also, by its
peculiar division, attacks the individual at the very roots of his life,
it is the first to afford the materials for, and to give a start to,
industrial pathologyâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
âRamazzini, professor of practical medicine at Padua, published in 1713
his work âDe morbis artificum,â which was translated into French 1781,
reprinted 1841 in the âEncyclopĂŠdie des Sciences MĂŠdicales. 7me Dis.
Auteurs Classiques.â The period of Modern Mechanical Industry has, of
course, very much enlarged his catalogue of labourâs diseases. See
âHygiène physique et morale de lâouvrier dans les grandes villes en
gĂŠnĂŠral et dans la ville de Lyon en particulier. Par le Dr. A. L.
Fonteret, Paris, 1858,â and âDie Krankheiten, welche verschiednen
Ständen, Altern und Geschlechtern eigenthßmlich sind. 6 Vols. Ulm,
1860,â and others. In 1854 the Society of Arts appointed a Commission of
Inquiry into industrial pathology. The list of documents collected by
this commission is to be seen in the catalogue of the âTwickenham
Economic Museum.â Very important are the official âReports on Public
Health.â See also Eduard Reich, M. D. âUeber die Entartung des
Menschen,â Erlangen, 1868â (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, fn 50).
David Urquhart says: âTo subdivide a man is to execute him, if he
deserves the sentence, to assassinate him if he does not... The
subdivision of labour is the assassination of a people.â (Marx, Capital,
vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
âHegel held very heretical views on division of labour. In his
âRechtsphilosophieâ he says: âBy well educated men we understand in the
first instance, those who can do everything that others doââ (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, fn. 51).
âIn its specific capitalist form â and under the given conditions, it
could take no other form than a capitalistic one â manufacture is but a
particular method of begetting relative surplus-value, or of augmenting
at the expense of the labourer the self-expansion of capital â usually
called social wealth, âWealth of Nations,â &c. It increases the social
productive power of labour, not only for the benefit of the capitalist
instead of for that of the labourer, but it does this by crippling the
individual labourers. It creates new conditions for the lordship of
capital over labour. If, therefore, on the one hand, it presents itself
historically as a progress and as a necessary phase in the economic
development of society, on the other hand, it is a refined and civilised
method of exploitationâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 14, sec. 5).
John Stuart Mill, in his Principles of Political Economy, says:
âHitherto [1848] it is questionable if all the mechanical inventions yet
made have lightened the dayâs toil of any human beingâ (Mill, Principles
of Political Economy, ch. 6).[2] This was not their purpose. Like every
other development of the productive force of labor, capitalist use of
machinery does not tend to lower the price of commodities, to shorten
the part of the day, in which the worker labors for himself, in relation
to lengthening the other, in which he works only for the capitalist. It
is a particular method for making relative surplus value.
But who is it that ever thinks of the worker? If the capitalist looks
after him, it is only to study a better way of exploiting him. The
worker sells his labor power, and the capitalist buys it, as the only
commodity that, with its surplus value, can enable him to give birth to
and grow capital. The capitalist, therefore, is only concerned with
making more surplus value. After having exhausted the resources of
absolute surplus value, he found relative surplus value. He now sees
that with machinery one can obtain in the same time a product two times,
four times, ten times, etc. bigger than before; and he begins to use
machinery. Cooperation, manufacturing, thus transform into modern
industry and his workshop into a factory. That capitalist, after having
mutilated and crippled the worker with the division of labor, after
having limited him to only one partial task, makes us watch a sadder
show yet. He rips from the hands of the worker that special tool, which
still reminds him of his art, his old status of a whole man, and
entrusts him to the machine. From now on the capitalist has no more need
for the worker, as he does a servant of his machinery. With the
introduction of machinery, the capitalist realizes an enormous profit at
first, one easily understands how, remembering how much we said about
relative surplus value. However with the propagation of the mechanical
system of production, the extraordinary profit ceases, and only the
growth of production remains that, made general by the generalization of
machinery, begins to lower the value of the things necessary to the
worker, the necessary labor time, and salaries, and to increase overwork
and surplus value.
Capital is divided into constant and variable. Constant capital is that
which is represented by raw materials and the means of production. The
building, the heaters, the tools, the auxiliary materials, like tallow,
coal, oil, etc., the means of production, like iron, cotton, silk,
silver, wood, etc., are all things that make up parts of constant
capital.
Variable capital is that which is represented by salary, by the price
that is of labor power. The first is called constant, because its value
remains constant in the value of the commodity, of which it is a
portion; while the second is called variable, exactly because its value
grows coming in to make a portion of the value of the commodity. It is
only variable capital that creates surplus value; and the machine only
makes up a portion of constant capital.
The capitalist aims, in modern industry, to profit from an enormous mass
of past labor, in the same way that he would profit from a mass of
natural forces, ie for free. To be able to reach his goal, however, he
needs to have a complete mechanism, which will be composed of more or
less expensive materials, and will always absorb a certain amount of
work. He certainly does not have to buy steam power, or the driving
property of water or of air; he certainly does not have to buy
mechanical breakthroughs and applications; nor the inventions and
improvements of the tools of a trade. He can avail himself of all of
this, always as he wishes, without expense; but he just needs to procure
all of a mechanism adapted to this. The machine enters therefore, as a
means of production, making up a portion of constant capital; and the
proportion, in which it comes in to compose the value of the commodity,
is in direct proportion with its consumption and with its auxiliary
materials, coal, tallow, etc., and in inverse proportion with the value
of the commodity. That is to say that the more one wears out a machine
with its auxiliary materials in producing a commodity, the more it tells
them of its value; while the value of the commodity is larger, for which
the machine works, the portion of value that comes from the consumption
of the machine is smaller.
âSince [the steam-hammerâs] daily wear and tear, its coal-consumption,
&c., are spread over the stupendous masses of iron hammered by it in a
day, only a small value is added to a hundred weight of iron; but that
value would be very great, if the cyclopean instrument were employed in
driving in nailsâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 15, sec. 2).
When, for the generalization of the system of modern industry, the
machine ceases to be a direct source of extraordinary wealth for the
capitalist, he succeeds in finding many other ways, with which he can
continue to get very large amounts of relative surplus value from this
new way of production.
âIn so far as machinery dispenses with muscular power, it becomes a
means of employing labourers of slight muscular strength, and those
whose bodily development is incomplete, but whose limbs are all the more
supple. The labour of women and children was, therefore, the first thing
sought for by capitalists who used machinery. That mighty substitute for
labour and labourers was forthwith changed into a means for increasing
the number of wage-labourers by enrolling, under the direct sway of
capital, every member of the workmanâs family, without distinction of
age or sex. Compulsory work for the capitalist usurped the place, not
only of the childrenâs play, but also of free labour at home within
moderate limits for the support of the family.
âThe value of labour-power was determined, not only by the labour-time
necessary to maintain the individual adult labourer, but also by that
necessary to maintain his family. Machinery, by throwing every member of
that family on to the labour-market, spreads the value of the manâs
labour-power over his whole family. It thus depreciates his
labour-power. To purchase the labour-power of a family of four workers
may, perhaps, cost more than it formerly did to purchase the
labour-power of the head of the family, but, in return, four daysâ
labour takes the place of one, and their price falls in proportion to
the excess of the surplus-labour of four over the surplus-labour of one.
In order that the family may live, four people must now, not only
labour, but expend surplus-labour for the capitalist. Thus we see, that
machinery, while augmenting the human material that forms the principal
object of capitalâs exploiting power, at the same time raises the degree
of exploitation.
âMachinery also revolutionises out and out the contract between the
labourer and the capitalist, which formally fixes their mutual
relations. Taking the exchange of commodities as our basis, our first
assumption was that capitalist and labourer met as free persons, as
independent owners of commodities; the one possessing money and means of
production, the other labour-power. But now the capitalist buys children
and young persons under age. Previously, the workman sold his own
labour-power, which he disposed of nominally as a free agent. Now he
sells wife and child. He has become a slave-dealerâ (Marx, Capital, vol.
1, ch. 15, sec. 3A).
âIf machinery be the most powerful means for increasing the
productiveness of labour â i.e., for shortening the working-time
required in the production of a commodity, it becomes in the hands of
capital the most powerful means, in those industries first invaded by
it, for lengthening the working-day beyond all bounds set by human
nature âŚ
âIn the first place, in the form of machinery, the implements of labour
become automatic, things moving and working independent of the workman.
The automaton, as capital, and because it is capital, is endowed, in the
person of the capitalist, with intelligence and will; it is therefore
animated by the longing to reduce to a minimum the resistance offered by
that repellent yet elastic natural barrier, man. This resistance is
moreover lessened by the apparent lightness of machine work, and by the
more pliant and docile character of the women and children employed on
it âŚ
âThe material wear and tear of a machine is of two kinds. The one arises
from use, as coins wear away by circulating, the other from non-use, as
a sword rusts when left in its scabbard. The latter kind is due to the
elements. The former is more or less directly proportional, the latter
to a certain extent inversely proportional, to the use of the machine.
âBut in addition to the material wear and tear, a machine also
undergoes, what we may call a moral depreciation. It loses
exchange-value, either by machines of the same sort being produced
cheaper than it, or by better machines entering into competition with
itâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 15, sec. 3B).
To repair this damage, the capitalist feels the need to make the machine
work as much as possible, and most importantly begins to prolong daily
labor, introducing night shifts and the relays system. As the word
itself indicates, used to indicate the changing of postal horses, the
relays system consists of making two teams of workers carry out labor,
that switch off every twelve hours, or three that switch off every eight
hours; in a way that labor always proceeds without the slightest
interruption for all 24 hours. This system, so advantageous for capital,
is also begun to be used in the first moment of the appearance of
machinery, when the capitalist is in a great rush to be able to amass
the greatest quantity possible of extraordinary profit, that soon must
stop for the generalization of the machinery itself. The capitalist,
therefore, breaks down all obstacles of time with the machinery, all of
the limits of the day that were imposed on labor in manufacturing. And
when he is joined with the natural limit of the day, to absorb that is
all of the 24 hours of the day, he finds the way to make of only one day
two, three, four or more days, intensifying labor two, three, four or
more times. In fact, if in one workday one finds a way of making a
worker carry out two times, three times, four times, etc. more labor
than before, itâs clear that the old workday will correspond to two,
three, four or more workdays. And the capitalist finds the way to do
this, rendering, as we have already said, labor more intense, squeezing,
in other words, into only one day the labor of two, three, four or more
days. It is with machinery that he is able to achieve this goal.
âThe improvements in the steam-engine have increased the piston speed,
and at the same time have made it possible, by means of a greater
economy of power, to drive with the same or even a smaller consumption
of coal more machinery with the same engine. The improvements in the
transmitting mechanism have lessened friction, and, what so strikingly
distinguishes modern from the older machinery, have reduced the diameter
and weight of the shafting to a constantly decreasing minimum. Finally,
the improvements in the operative machines have, while reducing their
size, increased their speed and efficiency, as in the modern power-loom;
or, while increasing the size of their framework, have also increased
the extent and number of their working parts, as in spinning-mules, or
have added to the speed of these working parts by imperceptible
alterations of detail, such as those which ten years ago increased the
speed of the spindles in self-acting mules by one-fifth.
âThe reduction of the working-day to 12 hours dates in England from
1832. In 1836 a manufacturer stated: âThe labour now undergone in the
factories is much greater than it used to be ... compared with thirty or
forty years ago ... owing to the greater attention and activity required
by the greatly increased speed which is given to the machinery.â
âIn the year 1844, Lord Ashley, now Lord Shaftesbury, made in the House
of Commons the following statements, supported by documentary evidence:
âThe labour performed by those engaged in the processes of manufacture,
is three times as great as in the beginning of such operations.
Machinery has executed, no doubt, the work that would demand the sinews
of millions of men; but it has also prodigiously multiplied the labour
of those who are governed by its fearful movementsââ (Marx, Capital,
vol. 1, ch. 15, sec. 3C).
âSo far as division of labour re-appears in the factory, it is primarily
a distribution of the workmen among the specialised machines; and of
masses of workmen, not however organised into groups, among the various
departments of the factory, in each of which they work at a number of
similar machines placed together; their co-operation, therefore, is only
simple. The organised group, peculiar to manufacture, is replaced by the
connexion between the head workman and his few assistants. The essential
division is, into workmen who are actually employed on the machines
(among whom are included a few who look after the engine), and into mere
attendants (almost exclusively children) of these workmen. Among the
attendants are reckoned more or less all âFeedersâ who supply the
machines with the material to be worked. In addition to these two
principal classes, there is a numerically unimportant class of persons,
whose occupation it is to look after the whole of the machinery and
repair it from time to time; such as engineers, mechanics, joiners, &c.
This is a superior class of workmen, some of them scientifically
educated, others brought up to a trade; it is distinct from the factory
operative class, and merely aggregated to it. This division of labour is
purely technical.
âTo work at a machine, the workman should be taught from childhood, in
order that he may learn to adapt his own movements to the uniform and
unceasing motion of an automaton. When the machinery, as a whole, forms
a system of manifold machines, working simultaneously and in concert,
the co-operation based upon it, requires the distribution of various
groups of workmen among the different kinds of machines. But the
employment of machinery does away with the necessity of crystallising
this distribution after the manner of Manufacture, by the constant
annexation of a particular man to a particular function. Since the
motion of the whole system does not proceed from the workman, but from
the machinery, a change of persons can take place at any time without an
interruption of the work. The most striking proof of this is afforded by
the relays system, put into operation by the manufacturers during their
revolt from 1848â1850. Lastly, the quickness with which machine work is
learnt by young people, does away with the necessity of bringing up for
exclusive employment by machinery, a special class of operatives. With
regard to the work of the mere attendants, it can, to some extent, be
replaced in the mill by machines, and owing to its extreme simplicity,
it allows of a rapid and constant change of the individuals burdened
with this drudgery.
âAlthough then, technically speaking, the old system of division of
labour is thrown overboard by machinery, it hangs on in the factory, as
a traditional habit handed down from Manufacture, and is afterwards
systematically re-moulded and established in a more hideous form by
capital, as a means of exploiting labour-power. The life-long speciality
of handling one and the same tool, now becomes the life-long speciality
of serving one and the same machine. Machinery is put to a wrong use,
with the object of transforming the workman, from his very childhood,
into a part of a detail-machine. In this way, not only are the expenses
of his reproduction considerably lessened, but at the same time his
helpless dependence upon the factory as a whole, and therefore upon the
capitalist, is rendered complete. Here as everywhere else, we must
distinguish between the increased productiveness due to the development
of the social process of production, and that due to the capitalist
exploitation of that process. In handicrafts and manufacture, the
workman makes use of a tool, in the factory, the machine makes use of
him. There the movements of the instrument of labour proceed from him,
here it is the movements of the machine that he must follow. In
manufacture the workmen are parts of a living mechanism. In the factory
we have a lifeless mechanism independent of the workman, who becomes its
mere living appendage.
ââThe miserable routine of endless drudgery and toil in which the same
mechanical process is gone through over and over again, is like the
labour of Sisyphus. The burden of labour, like the rock, keeps ever
falling back on the worn-out labourerâ (Friedrich Engels).
âAt the same time that factory work exhausts the nervous system to the
uttermost, it does away with the many-sided play of the muscles, and
confiscates every atom of freedom, both in bodily and intellectual
activity. The lightening of the labour, even, becomes a sort of torture,
since the machine does not free the labourer from work, but deprives the
work of all interest. Every kind of capitalist production, in so far as
it is not only a labour-process, but also a process of creating
surplus-value, has this in common, that it is not the workman that
employs the instruments of labour, but the instruments of labour that
employ the workman. But it is only in the factory system that this
inversion for the first time acquires technical and palpable reality. By
means of its conversion into an automaton, the instrument of labour
confronts the labourer, during the labour-process, in the shape of
capital, of dead labour, that dominates, and pumps dry, living
labour-power. The separation of the intellectual powers of production
from the manual labour, and the conversion of those powers into the
might of capital over labour, is, as we have already shown, finally
completed by modern industry erected on the foundation of machinery. The
special skill of each individual insignificant factory operative
vanishes as an infinitesimal quantity before the science, the gigantic
physical forces, and the mass of labour that are embodied in the factory
mechanism and, together with that mechanism, constitute the power of the
âmaster.â This âmaster,â therefore, in whose brain the machinery and his
monopoly of it are inseparably united, whenever he falls out with his
âhands,â contemptuously tells them:
ââThe factory operatives should keep in wholesome remembrance the fact
that theirs is really a low species of skilled labour; and that there is
none which is more easily acquired, or of its quality more amply
remunerated, or which by a short training of the least expert can be
more quickly, as well as abundantly, acquired.... The masterâs machinery
really plays a far more important part in the business of production
than the labour and the skill of the operative, which six monthsâ
education can teach, and a common labourer can learnâ (âThe Master
Spinnersâ and Manufacturersâ Defence Fund. Report of the Committeeâ,
1854).
âThe technical subordination of the workman to the uniform motion of the
instruments of labour, and the peculiar composition of the body of
workpeople, consisting as it does of individuals of both sexes and of
all ages, give rise to a barrack discipline, which is elaborated into a
complete system in the factory, and which fully develops the before
mentioned labour of overlooking, thereby dividing the workpeople into
operatives and overlookers, into private soldiers and sergeants of an
industrial army. âThe main difficulty [in the automatic factory] ... lay
... above all in training human beings to renounce their desultory
habits of work, and to identify themselves with the unvarying regularity
of the complex automaton. To devise and administer a successful code of
factory discipline, suited to the necessities of factory diligence, was
the Herculean enterprise, the noble achievement of Arkwright! Even at
the present day, when the system is perfectly organised and its labour
lightened to the utmost, it is found nearly impossible to convert
persons past the age of puberty, into useful factory handsâ (Andrew
Ure). The factory code in which capital formulates, like a private
legislator, and at his own good will, his autocracy over his workpeople,
unaccompanied by that division of responsibility, in other matters so
much approved of by the bourgeoisie, and unaccompanied by the still more
approved representative system, this code is but the capitalistic
caricature of that social regulation of the labour-process which becomes
requisite in co-operation on a great scale, and in the employment in
common, of instruments of labour and especially of machinery. The place
of the slave-driverâs lash is taken by the overlookerâs book of
penalties. All punishments naturally resolve themselves into fines and
deductions from wages, and the law-giving talent of the factory Lycurgus
so arranges matters, that a violation of his laws is, if possible, more
profitable to him than the keeping of themâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
15, sec. 4).
ââThe slavery in which the bourgeoisie has bound the proletariat, comes
nowhere more plainly into daylight than in the factory system. In it all
freedom comes to an end both at law and in fact. The workman must be in
the factory at half past five. If he come a few minutes late, he is
punished; if he come 10 minutes late, he is not allowed to enter until
after breakfast, and thus loses a quarter of a dayâs wage. He must eat,
drink and sleep at word of command.... The despotic bell calls him from
his bed, calls him from breakfast and dinner. And how does he fare in
the mill? There the master is the absolute law-giver. He makes what
regulations he pleases; he alters and makes additions to his code at
pleasure; and if he insert the veriest nonsense, the courts say to the
workman: Since you have entered into this contract voluntarily, you must
now carry it out .... These workmen are condemned to live, from their
ninth year till their death, under this mental and bodily tortureâ
(Friedrich Engels). What, âthe courts say,â I will illustrate by two
examples. One occurs at Sheffield at the end of 1866. In that town a
workman had engaged himself for 2 years in a steelworks. In consequence
of a quarrel with his employer he left the works, and declared that
under no circumstances would he work for that master any more. He was
prosecuted for breach of contract, and condemned to two monthsâ
imprisonment. (If the master break the contract, he can be proceeded
against only in a civil action, and risks nothing but money damages.)
After the workman has served his two months, the master invites him to
return to the works, pursuant to the contract. Workman says: No, he has
already been punished for the breach. The master prosecutes again, the
court condemns again, although one of the judges, Mr. Shee, publicly
denounces this as a legal monstrosity, by which a man can periodically,
as long as he lives, be punished over and over again for the same
offence or crime. This judgment was given not by the âGreat Unpaid,â the
provincial Dogberries, but by one of the highest courts of justice in
London. â [Added in the 4^(th) German edition. â This has now been done
away with. With few exceptions, e.g., when public gas-works are
involved, the worker in England is now put on an equal footing with the
employer in case of breach of contract and can be sued only civilly. â
F. E.] The second case occurs in Wiltshire at the end of November 1863.
About 30 power-loom weavers, in the employment of one Harrup, a cloth
manufacturer at Leowerâs Mill, Westbury Leigh, struck work because
master Harrup indulged in the agreeable habit of making deductions from
their wages for being late in the morning; 6d. for 2 minutes; 1s. for 3
minutes, and 1s. 6d. for ten minutes. This is at the rate of 9s. per
hour, and ÂŁ4 10s. 0d. per diem; while the wages of the weavers on the
average of a year, never exceeded 10s. to 12s. weekly. Harrup also
appointed a boy to announce the starting time by a whistle, which he
often did before six oâclock in the morning: and if the hands were not
all there at the moment the whistle ceased, the doors were closed, and
those hands who were outside were fined: and as there was no clock on
the premises, the unfortunate hands were at the mercy of the young
Harrup-inspired time-keeper. The hands on strike, mothers of families as
well as girls, offered to resume work if the timekeeper were replaced by
a clock, and a more reasonable scale of fines were introduced. Harrup
summoned I9 women and girls before the magistrates for breach of
contract. To the utter indignation of all present, they were each
mulcted in a fine of 6d. and 2s. 6d. for costs. Harrup was followed from
the court by a crowd of people who hissed himâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1,
ch. 15, fn. 108).
âThe contest between the capitalist and the wage-labourer dates back to
the very origin of capital. It raged on throughout the whole
manufacturing period. But only since the introduction of machinery has
the workman fought against the instrument of labour itself, the material
embodiment of capital. He revolts against this particular form of the
means of production, as being the material basis of the capitalist mode
of production.
âIn the 17^(th) century nearly all Europe experienced revolts of the
workpeople against the ribbon-loom, a machine for weaving ribbons and
trimmings, called in Germany BandmĂźhle, SchnurmĂźhle, and MĂźhlenstuhl.
These machines were invented in Germany. AbbĂŠ Lancellotti, in a work
that appeared in Venice in 1636, but which was written in 1579, says as
follows:
ââAnthony MĂźller of Danzig saw about 50 years ago in that town, a very
ingenious machine, which weaves 4 to 6 pieces at once. But the Mayor
being apprehensive that this invention might throw a large number of
workmen on the streets, caused the inventor to be secretly strangled or
drowned.â
âIn Leyden, this machine was not used till 1629; there the riots of the
ribbon-weavers at length compelled the Town Council to prohibit it.
ââIn this town,â says Boxhorn (Inst. Pol., 1663), referring to the
introduction of this machine into Leyden, âabout twenty years ago
certain people invented an instrument for weaving, with which a single
person could weave more cloth, and more easily, than many others in the
same length of time. As a result there arose disturbances and complaints
from the weavers, until the Town Council finally prohibited the use of
this instrument.â
âAfter making various decrees more or less prohibitive against this loom
in 1632, 1639, &c., the States General of Holland at length permitted it
to be used, under certain conditions, by the decree of the 15^(th)
December, 1661. It was also prohibited in Cologne in 1676, at the same
time that its introduction into England was causing disturbances among
the workpeople. By an imperial Edict of 19^(th) Feb., 1685, its use was
forbidden throughout all Germany. In Hamburg it was burnt in public by
order of the Senate. The Emperor Charles VI., on 9^(th) Feb., 1719,
renewed the edict of 1685, and not till 1765 was its use openly allowed
in the Electorate of Saxony. This machine, which shook Europe to its
foundations, was in fact the precursor of the mule and the power-loom,
and of the industrial revolution of the 18^(th) century. It enabled a
totally inexperienced boy, to set the whole loom with all its shuttles
in motion, by simply moving a rod backwards and forwards, and in its
improved form produced from 40 to 50 pieces at once.
âAbout 1630, a wind-sawmill, erected near London by a Dutchman,
succumbed to the excesses of the populace. Even as late as the beginning
of the 18^(th) century, sawmills driven by water overcame the opposition
of the people, supported as it was by Parliament, only with great
difficulty. No sooner had Everet in 1758 erected the first wool-shearing
machine that was driven by water-power, than it was set on fire by
100,000 people who had been thrown out of work. Fifty thousand
workpeople, who had previously lived by carding wool, petitioned
Parliament against Arkwrightâs scribbling mills and carding engines. The
enormous destruction of machinery that occurred in the English
manufacturing districts during the first 15 years of this century,
chiefly caused by the employment of the power-loom, and known as the
Luddite movement, gave the anti-Jacobin governments of a Sidmouth, a
Castlereagh, and the like, a pretext for the most reactionary and
forcible measures. It took both time and experience before the
workpeople learnt to distinguish between machinery and its employment by
capital, and to direct their attacks, not against the material
instruments of production, but against the mode in which they are usedâ
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 1, sec. 5).
Here, therefore, are the results of machinery and modern industry for
the workers. These are, foremost, driven in large part by factories, in
which the machine has taken its place. The few people who remain must
suffer the humiliation of seeing the last instrument of labor snatched
from their hand and being reduced to the condition of servants of
machinery; they must bear the burden of an extraordinarily grown
workday; the must renounce their wives and children, having become the
slaves of capital; and they must suffer, finally, the indescribable
spasms, products of the torture of labor progressively intensified by
the mad lust, by which the capitalist is taken in the period of modern
industry, for surplus value. But the theologians of the god of capital
arenât lacking, who explain all, and justify all with their eternal
laws. To the desperate cry of the workers hungered by machinery, they
respond with the announcement of a farfetched law of compensation.
âJames Mill, MacCulloch, Torrens, Senior, John Stuart Mill, and a whole
series besides, of bourgeois political economists, insist that all
machinery that displaces workmen, simultaneously and necessarily sets
free an amount of capital adequate to employ the same identical workmen.
âSuppose a capitalist to employ 100 workmen, at ÂŁ30 a year each, in a
carpet factory. The variable capital annually laid out amounts,
therefore, to ÂŁ3,000. Suppose, also, that he discharges 50 of his
workmen, and employs the remaining 50 with machinery that costs him
ÂŁ1,500. To simplify matters, we take no account of buildings, coal, &c.
Further suppose that the raw material annually consumed costs ÂŁ3,000,
both before and after the change. Is any capital set free by this
metamorphosis? Before the change, the total sum of ÂŁ6,000 consisted half
of constant, and half of variable capital. After the change it consists
of ÂŁ4,500 constant ( ÂŁ3,000 raw material and ÂŁ1,500 machinery), and
ÂŁ1,500 variable capital. The variable capital, instead of being one
half, is only one quarter, of the total capital. Instead of being set
free, a part of the capital is here locked up in such a way as to cease
to be exchanged against labour-power: variable has been changed into
constant capital. Other things remaining unchanged, the capital of
ÂŁ6,000, can, in future, employ no more than 50 men. With each
improvement in the machinery, it will employ fewer. If the newly
introduced machinery had cost less than did the labour-power and
implements displaced by it, if, for instance, instead of costing ÂŁ1,500,
it had cost only ÂŁ1,000, a variable capital of ÂŁ1,000 would have been
converted into constant capital, and locked up; and a capital of ÂŁ500
would have been set free. The latter sum, supposing wages unchanged,
would form a fund sufficient to employ about 16 out of the 50 men
discharged; nay, less than 16, for, in order to be employed as capital,
a part of this ÂŁ500 must now become constant capital, thus leaving only
the remainder to be laid out in labour-power.
âBut, suppose, besides, that the making of the new machinery affords
employment to a greater number of mechanics, can that be called
compensation to the carpet-makers, thrown on the streets? At the best,
its construction employs fewer men than its employment displaces. The
sum of ÂŁ1,500 that formerly represented the wages of the discharged
carpet-makers, now represents in the shape of machinery: (1) the value
of the means of production used in the construction of that machinery,
(2) the wages of the mechanics employed in its construction, and (3) the
surplus-value falling to the share of their âmaster.â Further, the
machinery need not be renewed till it is worn out. Hence, in order to
keep the increased number of mechanics in constant employment, one
carpet manufacturer after another must displace workmen by machines.
âAs a matter of fact the apologists do not mean this sort of setting
free.
âThey have in their minds the means of subsistence of the liberated
work-people. It cannot be denied, in the above instance, that the
machinery not only liberates 50 men, thus placing them at othersâ
disposal, but, at the same time, it withdraws from their consumption,
and sets free, means of subsistence to the value of ÂŁ1,500. The simple
fact, by no means a new one, that machinery cuts off the workmen from
their means of subsistence is, therefore, in economic parlance
tantamount to this, that machinery liberates means of subsistence for
the workman, or converts those means into capital for his employment.
The mode of expression, you see, is everything. Nominibus mollire licet
mala (Itâs lawful to hide evil with words)â (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
15, sec. 6).
The supporters of the capitalist mode of production pretend that salary
is payment for labor, and surplus value the product of capital.
But what is labor value? Labor, either still in the worker, or already
out; that is to say, labor, either the force, the power to do something,
or the thing itself already done: in short, labor, either labor power,
or the commodity. The worker cannot sell labor thatâs already left him,
ie the thing he produces, the commodity, because this belongs to the
capitalist, and not to him. Because the worker could sell labor thatâs
already left him, ie the commodity he produced, he would need to possess
the means of production and raw materials, and so he would be the
merchant of the commodities he produced. But he doesnât possess
anything, he is a proletarian, who, to live, must sell to others the
only good that rests in him, that is his power or force to work, labor
power. The capitalist therefore can buy nothing besides labor power;
which, like all other commodities, has a use value and an exchange
value. The capitalist pays the appropriately determined value, i.e. the
exchange value, to the worker for the commodity, which he sells. But
labor power also has a use value, which belongs to the capitalist who
bought it. Now, the use value of this singular commodity has a double
quality. The first is that which it has in common with the use value of
all other commodities, that is, of satisfying a need; the second is
that, completely special to it, of creating value, which distinguishes
this commodity from all the others.
Therefore, salary cannot represent the price of labor power. And surplus
value cannot be produced by capital, because capital is inert matter,
which is always found to have the same amount of value as it did when it
was used in the commodity; it is matter that hasnât any life, and that,
remaining by itself, without labor power, would never be able to have
it. It is only labor power that is able to produce surplus value. It is
this that gives the first seed of life to capital. It is this that
supports the whole life of capital. This, more than anything, first
sucks, then absorbs with all of its pores, and finally vigorously pumps
surplus value from labor.
The two main forms of salary are: time-wages and piece-wages.
Time-wages are those paid for a given time; like for a day, for a week,
for a month, etc, of labor. It is simply a transformation of the price
of labor power. Instead of saying that the worker has sold his labor
power of one day for 3 lire, one says that the worker goes to work for a
salary of 3 lire a day.
The salary of 3 lire per day is therefore the price of labor power for a
day. But this day can be more or less long. If, for example, a day of 10
hours of labor power is paid 30 cents per hour, then, if itâs 12 hours,
labor power is paid 25 cents per hour. Therefore, the capitalist,
extending the workday, pays the worker a smaller price for his labor
power. The capitalist can also increase salary, while continuing to pay
the worker, for his labor power, the same price as before, and even
less. If a capitalist increases his workerâs salary from 3 lire to â¤3,60
a day, and at the same time he prolongs the workday from the 10 hours
that it was before to 12 hours, he, by increasing daily wages by â¤0,60,
will always come out paying the worker â¤0,30 an hour for his labor
power. If then the capitalist increases the salary from â¤3 to â¤3,60,
but, at the same time, prolongs the day from 10 to 15 hours, he, by
increasing the daily wages, will be able to pay the worker less than
before for his labor power, ie 24 cents instead of 30 cents an hour. The
capitalist obtains the same effect, if, instead of increasing the length
of labor, he increases it in volume; as we have already seen he was able
to do with machinery. In conclusion, the capitalist, increasing labor,
is able to cheat the worker honestly; and he can do it while gaining
fame for his generosity, with the increase of his daily wages.
When the capitalist pays the worker by the hour, he still finds means of
damaging him, increasing or decreasing labor, but always honestly paying
the same price for every hour of labor. Indeed, the salary is 25 cents
for an hour of labor. If the capitalist makes the worker labor for 8
hours, instead of 12, he will pay him â¤2, instead of â¤3; he will be
losing, that is, one lira, with which the worker must satisfy the third
part of his daily needs. Inversely, if the capitalist makes the worker
labor for 14 or 16 hours, instead of 12, while paying him â¤3,50 or â¤4
instead of â¤3, he ends up taking 2 or 4 hours of labor from the worker
at a smaller price than itâs worth. After 12 hours of labor the workerâs
powers have already suffered consumption; and the other 2 or 4 hours of
labor, overtime, cost more than the first 12 hours. This rationale,
presented by the workers, in fact seems to be accepted by different
industries, where they pay a greater price for overtime done after the
established hours of the workday.
The smaller the price of labor power, represented by time-wages, the
longer the labor time. And that is clear. If the salary is â¤0,25 per
hour, instead of â¤0,30, the worker must work a 12-hour day, instead of
working a 10-hour day, to procure the â¤3 required for their daily needs.
If the salary is â¤2 a day, the worker must work three days, instead of
two, to procure how much he needs for only two days. Here the lessening
of salary increases labor; but it also happens that the increase of
labor makes salary lower. With the introduction of machinery, for
example, a worker comes to produce double than before; so the capitalist
lessens the number of workers; as a consequence the request for work
grows, and salaries fall.
Piece-wages are nothing but a transformation of time-wages; as shown by
the fact that these two forms of salary are used indifferently, not only
in different industries, but at times even in the same industry.
A worker labors 12 hours a day for a salary of â¤3 and produces a value
of â¤6. Here it is irrelevant to say that the worker produces, in the
first 6 hours of his labor, the â¤3 of his salary, and, in the other 6
hours, the â¤3 of surplus value; itâs equivalent to saying that the
worker produces, in every first half-hour, â¤0,25, a twelfth of his
salary, and, in every second half-hour, â¤0,25, a twelfth of the surplus
value. In the same way, if the worker produces, in 12 hours of work, 24
items, and receives 12,5 cents per item, in total â¤3, itâs exactly like
saying that the worker produces 12 items to reproduce the â¤3 given to
him in payment, and 12 items to produce â¤3 of surplus value; or that the
worker produces, in every hour of work, and item for his payment, and an
item for his bossâs gain.
In piece-wages:
âThe quality of the labour is here controlled by the work itself, which
must be of average perfection if the piece-price is to be paid in full.
Piece wages become, from this point of view, the most fruitful source of
reductions of wages and capitalistic cheating.
âThey furnish to the capitalist an exact measure for the intensity of
labour. Only the working-time which is embodied in a quantum of
commodities determined beforehand, and experimentally fixed, counts as
socially necessary working-time, and is paid as such. In the larger
workshops of the London tailors, therefore, a certain piece of work, a
waistcoat, e.g., is called an hour, or half an hour, the hour at 6d. By
practice it is known how much is the average product of one hour. With
new fashions, repairs, &c., a contest arises between master and labourer
as to whether a particular piece of work is one hour, and so on, until
here also experience decides. Similarly in the London furniture
workshops, &c. If the labourer does not possess the average capacity, if
he cannot in consequence supply a certain minimum of work per day, he is
dismissed.
âSince the quality and intensity of the work are here controlled by the
form of wage itself, superintendence of labour becomes in great part
superfluous. Piece wages therefore lay the foundation of the modern
âdomestic labour,â described above, as well as of a hierarchically
organized system of exploitation and oppression. The latter has two
fundamental forms. On the one hand, piece wages facilitate the
interposition of parasites between the capitalist and the wage-labourer,
the âsub-letting of labour.â The gain of these middlemen comes entirely
from the difference between the labour-price which the capitalist pays,
and the part of that price which they actually allow to reach the
labourer. In England this system is characteristically called the
âsweating system.â On the other hand, piece-wage allows the capitalist
to make a contract for so much per piece with the head labourer â in
manufactures with the chief of some group, in mines with the extractor
of the coal, in the factory with the actual machine-worker â at a price
for which the head labourer himself undertakes the enlisting and payment
of his assistant work people. The exploitation of the labourer by
capital is here effected through the exploitation of the labourer by the
labourer.
âGiven piece-wage, it is naturally the personal interest of the labourer
to strain his labour-power as intensely as possible; this enables the
capitalist to raise more easily the normal degree of intensity of
labour. It is moreover now the personal interest of the labourer to
lengthen the working-day, since with it his daily or weekly wages rise.
This gradually brings on a reaction like that already described in
time-wages, without reckoning that the prolongation of the working-day,
even if the piece wage remains constant, includes of necessity a fall in
the price of the labourâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 21).
Piece-wages are one of two principle supports of the above-mentioned
system, that is of paying the worker by the hour, without the bossâs
commitment to occupy the worker regularly during the day or the week.
âIn the workshops under the Factory Acts, piece wages become the general
rule, because capital can there only increase the efficacy of the
working-day by intensifying labourâ (Marx, Capital, vol.1, ch. 21).
The increase in production is followed by the proportional decrease in
salary. When the worker was producing 12 items in 12 hours, the
capitalist used to pay him, for example, a salary of â¤0,25 per item.
With the production doubled, the worker produces 24 items, instead of
12, and the capitalist lowers wages by half, i.e., to 12,5 cents per
item.
âThis change in piece-wage, so far purely nominal, leads to constant
battles between capitalist and labour. Either because the capitalist
uses it as a pretext for actually lowering the price of labour, or
because increased productive power of labour is accompanied by an
increased intensity of the same. Or because the labourer takes seriously
the appearance of piece wages (viz., that his product is paid for, and
not his labour-power) and therefore revolts against a lowering of wages,
unaccompanied by a lowering in the selling price of the commodity âŚ
âThe capitalist rightly knocks on the head such pretensions as gross
errors as to the nature of wage-labour. He cries out against this
usurping attempt to lay taxes on the advance of industry, and declares
roundly that the productiveness of labour does not concern the labourer
at allâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 21).
If we observe the formula of capital, we easily comprehend that its
conservation is placed completely in its successive and continuous
reproduction.
In fact, capital is divided, as we already know, in two: into constant,
that is, and variable. Constant capital, represented by the means of
production and raw materials, is worn away continuously during the
process of labor. Tools are used, machinery used, carbon, tallow, etc.,
that is needed by the machinery, and finally the building is used. At
the same time, however, that the labor is able in such a way to wear
away constant capital, it is also reproduced in the same proportions in
which it uses it. Constant capital finds itself reproduced in the
commodity in the proportions in which it was used during its production.
The value used of the means of production and the raw materials is
always reproduced exactly in the value of the commodity, as we have
already seen elsewhere. If, therefore, constant capital comes to be
partially reproduced in every commodity, itâs clear that, in the value
of a certain number of manufactured commodities, one will find all of
the constant capital, used in their production.
As it is with constant capital, so too with variable capital. Variable
capital, that represented by the value of labor power, i.e. by salary,
is also reproduced exactly in the value of the commodity. We have
already seen it. The worker, in the first part of his labor, produces
his salary, and in the second the surplus value. As the worker is not
paid salary for that finished work, so it arises that he collects his
salary after having already reproduced the equivalent in the commodity
of the capitalist.
The assembly of salaries paid to workers is therefore from these
endlessly reproduced. This endless reproduction behind salaries
perpetuates the subjection of the worker to the capitalist. When the
proletarian comes to the market to sell his labor power, he comes to
take the position assigned to him by the capitalist mode of production,
and to contribute to the social production through his share of the
labor, withdrawing, for his maintenance, that part behind salaries, that
he will have to, first, reproduce with his labor.
It is always the eternal bond of human subjection, either under the form
of slavery, serfdom, or wage-worker.
The superficial observer believes that the slave labors for nothing. And
he doesnât think that the slave must above all make up to his owner how
much was spent for his maintenance: and he observes that the maintenance
of the slave is at times a great deal better than that of the
wage-worker, his owner being highly interested in his conservation, like
the conservation of a part of his own capital. The serf, who belongs to
his lord, together with the land, to which he is bound, is, for the
superficial observer, a being who has made progress compared to the
slave, because he sees clearly that the serf gives only one part of his
labor to his lord, while he employs the other part on the little land
assigned to him, to live life. And being a wage-worker, in turn, appears
to the superficial observer, a state much further progressed compared to
slavery, because the worker seems perfectly free in it, collecting the
value of his own labor.
What a strange illusion! If the worker could realize for himself the
value of his own labor, the capitalist mode of production would not be
able to exist any longer. We have already seen it. The worker is only
able to obtain the value of his labor power, which is the only thing
that he can sell, because it is the only good that he possesses in the
world. The product of labor belongs to the capitalist, who pays salary
to the proletarian, i.e. his maintenance. In the same way, the piece of
land left by the lord to his serf, as well as the time and tools
necessary to work it, are the sum of the means that he has to live,
while he must labor for his lord the rest of the time.
The slave, serf and worker all labor in part to produce their
maintenance, and in part completely for the benefit of their patrons.
These represent three different forms of the very same bond of human
subjection and exploitation. It is always the subjection of the man
without any primitive accumulation (that is of means of production,
which are the means of life) to the the man who possesses a primitive
accumulation, the means of production, the sources of life.
Conservation, i.e. the reproduction of capital, is just, in the
capitalist mode of production, the conservation of this bond of human
subjection and exploitation.
Labor does not only reproduce capital, it also produces surplus value,
which forms that which is called ârevenue of capitalâ. If the capitalist
blends every year all or part of his revenue with capital, we will have
an accumulation of capital, which will grow progressively. With simple
reproduction labor conserves capital; with accumulation of surplus value
labor increases capital.
When one re-incorporates the revenue with capital, one comes to use this
revenue, partially in the means of production, partially in raw
materials and partially in labor power. Now you have that the past
overwork, past unpaid labor, increases the whole capital. One part of
last yearâs unpaid labor pays this yearâs necessary work. Here is what
the capitalist is able to do, thanks to the ingenious mechanism of
modern production.
Once the system of modern production is admitted, all based upon private
property and the wage-worker, nothing can be said about the consequences
that derive from it, one of which is capitalist accumulation. Is it
important to the worker Antonio if the 3 lire that are paid to him as
salary represent the worker Peterâs unpaid labor? What he has a right to
know is if the 3 lire are the right price of his labor power, i.e. if
they are the exact equivalent of the things necessary to him in a day,
if the law of exchange, in a word, was observed rigorously.
When the capitalist begins to accumulate capital upon capital, a new
virtue, all rightly his, develops in him; the so-called âvirtue of
abstinenceâ, which consists of limiting all of his own expenses, to use
the greater part of his revenue on accumulation. âSo far, therefore, as
his actions are a mere function of capital â endowed as capital is, in
his person, with consciousness and a will â his own private consumption
is a robbery perpetrated on accumulation, just as in book-keeping by
double entry, the private expenditure of the capitalist is placed on the
debtor side of his account against his capital. To accumulate, is to
conquer the world of social wealth, to increase the mass of human beings
exploited by him, and thus to extend both the direct and the indirect
sway of the capitalistâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 24, sec. 3).
âTaking the usurer, that old-fashioned but ever renewed specimen of the
capitalist for his text, Luther shows very aptly that the love of power
is an element in the desire to get rich. âThe heathen were able, by the
light of reason, to conclude that a usurer is a double-dyed thief and
murderer. We Christians, however, hold them in such honour, that we
fairly worship them for the sake of their money.... Whoever eats up,
robs, and steals the nourishment of another, that man commits as great a
murder (so far as in him lies) as he who starves a man or utterly undoes
him. Such does a usurer, and sits the while safe on his stool, when he
ought rather to be hanging on the gallows, and be eaten by as many
ravens as he has stolen guilders, if only there were so much flesh on
him, that so many ravens could stick their beaks in and share it.
Meanwhile, we hang the small thieves.... Little thieves are put in the
stocks, great thieves go flaunting in gold and silk.... Therefore is
there, on this earth, no greater enemy of man (after the devil) than a
gripe-money, and usurer, for he wants to be God over all men. Turks,
soldiers, and tyrants are also bad men, yet must they let the people
live, and Confess that they are bad, and enemies, and do, nay, must, now
and then show pity to some. But a usurer and money-glutton, such a one
would have the whole world perish of hunger and thirst, misery and want,
so far as in him lies, so that he may have all to himself, and every one
may receive from him as from a God, and be his serf for ever. To wear
fine cloaks, golden chains, rings, to wipe his mouth, to be deemed and
taken for a worthy, pious man .... Usury is a great huge monster, like a
werewolf, who lays waste all, more than any Cacus, Gerion or Antus...
And since we break on the wheel, and behead highwaymen, murderers and
housebreakers, how much more ought we to break on the wheel and kill....
hunt down, curse and behead all usurersââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
24, fn. 20).
Capitalist accumulation requires an increase of hands. The number of
workers must be increased, if one wishes to convert a part of the
revenue into variable capital. The same organism of capitalist
reproduction performs in a way that the worker is able to conserve his
labor power in the new generation, from which capital takes labor power
in order to continue its endless process of reproduction. But the labor
that is required today by capital is higher that that which was required
yesterday; and consequently its price would naturally have to increase.
And in fact wages would have to increase, if in the same accumulation of
capital there were not a reason to make them decrease instead.
Itâs true that revenue would have to be converted, partially into
constant capital, and partially into variable capital; partially, that
is, into the means of production and raw materials, and partially into
labor power, but it must be considered that with the accumulation of
capital come perfections of the old systems of production, new systems
of production and machinery; all things that make production grow, and
lessen the price of labor power, like we already know. To the extent
that the accumulation of capital grows, its variable part shrinks, while
its constant part increases. That is, the buildings, the machinery with
its auxiliary materials increase, the raw materials increase, but, at
the same time and in proportion to this increase, with the the
accumulation of capital the need for labor power decreases, the need of
hands. Decreasing the need of labor power diminishes the demand for it
and finally it also lowers its price. One has, therefore, that the more
the accumulation of capital progresses, the more the wages go down.
The accumulation of capital takes vast amounts of competition and
credit. Credit spontaneously brings more capital to merge together, or
to merge together with one stronger than any of the others. Competition,
instead, is the war that all of the capitalists wage between themselves;
it is there struggle for existence, from which emerge those who, to win,
had to already be the stronger ones before, rendered even stronger.
The accumulation of capital, therefore, makes a great number of hands
useless; it creates, that is, a surplus laboring population. âBut if a
surplus labouring population is a necessary product of accumulation or
of the development of wealth on a capitalist basis, this surplus
population becomes, conversely, the lever of capitalistic accumulation,
nay, a condition of existence of the capitalist mode of production. It
forms a disposable industrial reserve army, that belongs to capital
quite as absolutely as if the latter had bred it at its own cost.
Independently of the limits of the actual increase of population, it
creates, for the changing needs of the self-expansion of capital, a mass
of human material always ready for exploitation. With accumulation, and
the development of the productiveness of labour that accompanies it, the
power of sudden expansion of capital grows alsoâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1,
ch. 25, sec. 3).
This industrial reserve army, this surplus laboring population is
divided into different categories. The first of these is better-paid,
and is less short of work than the others, while doing a less painful
job. The last category instead is composed of workers, who find
themselves occupied more rarely than all the others, and always by a
more tiresome and vile job, which pays them at the lowest price that one
can ever pay human labor. This last category is the most numerous, not
only for the great contingent that industrial progress consigns year by
year, but above all because it is composed of the most prolific amount
of people, as the same fact demonstrates. ââPoverty seems favourable to
generation.â (A. Smith.) This is even a specially wise arrangement of
God, according to the gallant and witty AbbĂŠ Galiani âIddio af che gli
uomini che esercitano mestieri di prima utilitĂ nascono
abbondantemente.â (Galiani, l. c., p. 78.) [God ordains that men who
carry on trades of primary utility are born in abundance] âMisery up to
the extreme point of famine and pestilence, instead of checking, tends
to increase populationâ (S. Laing, âNational Distress,â 1844, p. 69.)â
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, fn. 24).
After these categories none remains besides âthe lowest sediment of the
relative surplus population finally dwells in the sphere of pauperism.
âExclusive of vagabonds, criminals, prostitutes, in a word, the
âdangerousâ classes, this layer of society consists of three categories.
First, those able to work. One need only glance superficially at the
statistics of English pauperism to find that the quantity of paupers
increases with every crisis, and diminishes with every revival of trade.
Second, orphans and pauper children. These are candidates for the
industrial reserve army, and are, in times of great prosperity, as 1860,
e.g., speedily and in large numbers enrolled in the active army of
labourers. Third, the demoralised and ragged, and those unable to work,
chiefly people who succumb to their incapacity for adaptation, due to
the division of labour; people who have passed the normal age of the
labourer; the victims of industry, whose number increases with the
increase of dangerous machinery, of mines, chemical works, &c., the
mutilated, the sickly, the widows, &c. Pauperism is the hospital of the
active labour-army and the dead weight of the industrial reserve army.
Its production is included in that of the relative surplus population,
its necessity in theirs; along with the surplus population, pauperism
forms a condition of capitalist production, and of the capitalist
development of wealth. It enters into the faux frais of capitalist
production; but capital knows how to throw these, for the most part,
from its own shoulders on to those of the working class and the lower
middle class.
âThe greater the social wealth, the functioning capital, the extent and
energy of its growth, and, therefore, also the absolute mass of the
proletariat and the productiveness of its labour, the greater is the
industrial reserve army. The same causes which develop the expansive
power of capital, develop also the labour power at its disposal. The
relative mass of the industrial reserve army increases therefore with
the potential energy of wealth. But the greater this reserve army in
proportion to the active labour army, the greater is the mass of a
consolidated surplus population, whose misery is in inverse ratio to its
torment of labour. The more extensive, finally, the lazarus layers of
the working class, and the industrial reserve army, the greater is
official pauperism. This is the absolute general law of capitalist
accumulation. Like all other laws it is modified in its working by many
circumstances, the analysis of which does not concern us here.
âThe folly is now patent of the economic wisdom that preaches to the
labourers the accommodation of their number to the requirements of
capital. The mechanism of capitalist production and accumulation
constantly effects this adjustment. The first word of this adaptation is
the creation of a relative surplus population, or industrial reserve
army. Its last word is the misery of constantly extending strata of the
active army of labour, and the dead weight of pauperism.
âThe law by which a constantly increasing quantity of means of
production, thanks to the advance in the productiveness of social
labour, may be set in movement by a progressively diminishing
expenditure of human power, this law, in a capitalist society â where
the labourer does not employ the means of production, but the means of
production employ the labourer â undergoes a complete inversion and is
expressed thus: the higher the productiveness of labour, the greater is
the pressure of the labourers on the means of employment, the more
precarious, therefore, becomes their condition of existence, viz., the
sale of their own labour power for the increasing of anotherâs wealth,
or for the self-expansion of capital. The fact that the means of
production, and the productiveness of labour, increase more rapidly than
the productive population, expresses itself, therefore, capitalistically
in the inverse form that the labouring population always increases more
rapidly than the conditions under which capital can employ this increase
for its own self-expansion.
âWe saw in Part IV., when analysing the production of relative
surplus-value: within the capitalist system all methods for raising the
social productiveness of labour are brought about at the cost of the
individual labourer; all means for the development of production
transform themselves into means of domination over, and exploitation of,
the producers; they mutilate the labourer into a fragment of a man,
degrade him to the level of an appendage of a machine, destroy every
remnant of charm in his work and turn it into a hated toil; they
estrange from him the intellectual potentialities of the labour process
in the same proportion as science is incorporated in it as an
independent power; they distort the conditions under which he works,
subject him during the labour process to a despotism the more hateful
for its meanness; they transform his life-time into working-time, and
drag his wife and child beneath the wheels of the Juggernaut of capital.
But all methods for the production of surplus-value are at the same time
methods of accumulation; and every extension of accumulation becomes
again a means for the development of those methods. It follows therefore
that in proportion as capital accumulates, the lot of the labourer, be
his payment high or low, must grow worse. The law, finally, that always
equilibrates the relative surplus population, or industrial reserve
army, to the extent and energy of accumulation, this law rivets the
labourer to capital more firmly than the wedges of Vulcan did Prometheus
to the rock. It establishes an accumulation of misery, corresponding
with accumulation of capital. Accumulation of wealth at one pole is,
therefore, at the same time accumulation of misery, agony of toil
slavery, ignorance, brutality, mental degradation, at the opposite pole,
i.e., on the side of the class that produces its own product in the form
of capital. This antagonistic character of capitalistic accumulation is
enunciated in various forms by political economists, although by them it
is confounded with phenomena, certainly to some extent analogous, but
nevertheless essentially distinct, and belonging to pre-capitalistic
modes of production.
âThe Venetian monk Ortes, one of the great economic writers of the
18^(th) century, regards the antagonism of capitalist production as a
general natural law of social wealth.
ââIn the economy of a nation, advantages and evils always balance one
another (il bene ed il male economico in una nazione sempre all, istessa
misura): the abundance of wealth with some people, is always equal to
the want of it with others (la copia dei beni in alcuni sempre eguale
alia mancanza di essi in altri): the great riches of a small number are
always accompanied by the absolute privation of the first necessaries of
life for many others. The wealth of a nation corresponds with its
population, and its misery corresponds with its wealth. Diligence in
some compels idleness in others. The poor and idle are a necessary
consequence of the rich and active,â &c.In a thoroughly brutal way about
10 years after Ortes, the Church of England parson, Townsend, glorified
misery as a necessary condition of wealth.
ââLegal constraint (to labour) is attended with too much trouble,
violence, and noise, whereas hunger is not only a peaceable, silent,
unremitted pressure, but as the most natural motive to industry and
labour, it calls forth the most powerful exertions.â
âEverything therefore depends upon making hunger permanent among the
working class, and for this, according to Townsend, the principle of
population, especially active among the poor, provides.
ââIt seems to be a law of Nature that the poor should be to a certain
degree improvidentâ [i.e., so improvident as to be born without a silver
spoon in the mouth], âthat there may always be some to fulfil the most
servile, the most sordid, and the most ignoble offices in the community.
The stock of human happiness is thereby much increased, whilst the more
delicate are not only relieved from drudgery ... but are left at liberty
without interruption to pursue those callings which are suited to their
various dispositions ... itâ [the Poor Law] âtends to destroy the
harmony and beauty, the symmetry and order of that system which God and
Nature have established in the world.â If the Venetian monk found in the
fatal destiny that makes misery eternal, the raison dâĂŞtre of Christian
charity, celibacy, monasteries and holy houses, the Protestant
prebendary finds in it a pretext for condemning the laws in virtue of
which the poor possessed a right to a miserable public relief.
ââThe progress of social wealth,â says Storch, âbegets this useful class
of society ... which performs the most wearisome, the vilest, the most
disgusting functions, which takes, in a word, on its shoulders all that
is disagreeable and servile in life, and procures thus for other classes
leisure, serenity of mind and conventionalâ [câest bon!] âdignity of
character.â
âStorch asks himself in what then really consists the progress of this
capitalistic civilisation with its misery and its degradation of the
masses, as compared with barbarism. He finds but one answer: security!
ââThanks to the advance of industry and science,â says Sismondi, âevery
labourer can produce every day much more than his consumption requires.
But at the same time, whilst his labour produces wealth, that wealth
would, were he called on to consume it himself, make him less fit for
labour.â According to him, âmenâ [i.e., non-workers] âwould probably
prefer to do without all artistic perfection, and all the enjoyments
that manufacturers procure for us, if it were necessary that all should
buy them by constant toil like that of the labourer.... Exertion today
is separated from its recompense; it is not the same man that first
works, and then reposes; but it is because the one works that the other
rests.... The indefinite multiplication of the productive powers of
labour can then only have for result the increase of luxury and
enjoyment of the idle rich.â
âFinally Destutt de Tracy, the fish-blooded bourgeois doctrinaire,
blurts out brutally:
ââIn poor nations the people are comfortable, in rich nations they are
generally poorââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec. 4).
We now come to see, in the facts, what the effect of the accumulation of
capital are. Here, as elsewhere, our examples are all taken from
England, the preeminent country of the accumulation of capital, towards
which (letâs repeat it, and never forget it) all modern nations tend. I
regret that Iâm only able to reproduce only a small part of the rich
material gathered by Marx.
âIn the year 1863, the Privy Council ordered an inquiry into the state
of distress of the worst-nourished part of the English working class.
Dr. Simon, medical officer to the Privy Council, chose for this work the
above-mentioned Dr. Smith. His inquiry ranges on the one hand over the
agricultural labourers, on the other, over silk-weavers, needlewomen,
kid-glovers, stocking-weavers, glove-weavers, and shoemakers. The latter
categories are, with the exception of the stocking-weavers, exclusively
town-dwellers. It was made a rule in the inquiry to select in each
category the most healthy families, and those comparatively in the best
circumstances.
âAs a general result it was found that
ââin only one of the examined classes of in-door operatives did the
average nitrogen supply just exceed, while in another it nearly reached,
the estimated standard of bare sufficiency [i.e., sufficient to avert
starvation diseases], and that in two classes there was defect â in one,
a very large defect â of both nitrogen and carbon. Moreover, as regards
the examined families of the agricultural population, it appeared that
more than a fifth were with less than the estimated sufficiency of
carbonaceous food, that more than one-third were with less than the
estimated sufficiency of nitrogenous food, and that in three counties
(Berkshire, Oxfordshire, and Somersetshire), insufficiency of
nitrogenous food was the average local diet.â
âAmong the agricultural labourers, those of England, the wealthiest part
of the United Kingdom, were the worst fed. The insufficiency of food
among the agricultural labourers, fell, as a rule, chiefly on the women
and children, for âthe man must eat to do his work.â Still greater
penury ravaged the town-workers examined.
ââThey are so ill fed that assuredly among them there must be many cases
of severe and injurious privation.â
â(âPrivationâ of the capitalist all this! i.e., âabstinenceâ from paying
for the means of subsistence absolutely necessary for the mere
vegetation of his âhandsâ) âŚ
âDr. Simon in his General Health Report says:
ââThat cases are innumerable in which defective diet is the cause or the
aggravator of disease, can be affirmed by any one who is conversant with
poor law medical practice, or with the wards and out-patient rooms of
hospitals.... Yet in this point of view, there is, in my opinion, a very
important sanitary context to be added. It must be remembered that
privation of food is very reluctantly borne, and that as a rule great
poorness of diet will only come when other privations have preceded it.
Long before insufficiency of diet is a matter of hygienic concern, long
before the physiologist would think of counting the grains of nitrogen
and carbon which intervene between life and starvation, the household
will have been utterly destitute of material comfort; clothing and fuel
will have been even scantier than food â against inclemencies of weather
there will have been no adequate protection â dwelling space will have
been stinted to the degree in which overcrowding produces or increases
disease; of household utensils and furniture there will have been
scarcely any â even cleanliness will have been found costly or
difficult, and if there still be self-respectful endeavours to maintain
it, every such endeavour will represent additional pangs of hunger. The
home, too, will be where shelter can be cheapest bought; in quarters
where commonly there is least fruit of sanitary supervision, least
drainage, least scavenging, least suppression of public nuisances, least
or worst water supply, and, if in town, least light and air. Such are
the sanitary dangers to which poverty is almost certainly exposed, when
it is poverty enough to imply scantiness of food. And while the sum of
them is of terrible magnitude against life, the mere scantiness of food
is in itself of very serious moment.... These are painful reflections,
especially when it is remembered that the poverty to which they advert
is not the deserved poverty of idleness. In all cases it is the poverty
of working populations. Indeed, as regards the in-door operatives, the
work which obtains the scanty pittance of food, is for the most part
excessively prolonged. Yet evidently it is only in a qualified sense
that the work can be deemed self-supporting.... And on a very large
scale the nominal self-support can be only a circuit, longer or shorter,
to pauperism âŚâ
âEvery unprejudiced observer sees that the greater the centralisation of
the means of production, the greater is the corresponding heaping
together of the labourers, within a given space; that therefore the
swifter capitalistic accumulation, the more miserable are the dwellings
of the working-people. âImprovementsâ of towns, accompanying the
increase of wealth, by the demolition of badly built quarters, the
erection of palaces for banks, warehouses, &c., the widening of streets
for business traffic, for the carriages of luxury, and for the
introduction of tramways, &c., drive away the poor into even worse and
more crowded hiding places.
âI quote, as preliminary, a general remark of Dr. Simon.
ââAlthough my official point of view,â he says, âis one exclusively
physical, common humanity requires that the other aspect of this evil
should not be ignored .... In its higher degrees it [i.e.,
over-crowding] almost necessarily involves such negation of all
delicacy, such unclean confusion of bodies and bodily functions, such
exposure of animal and sexual nakedness, as is rather bestial than
human. To be subject to these influences is a degradation which must
become deeper and deeper for those on whom it continues to work. To
children who are born under its curse, it must often be a very baptism
into infamy. And beyond all measure hopeless is the wish that persons
thus circumstanced should ever in other respects aspire to that
atmosphere of civilisation which has its essence in physical and moral
cleanlinessââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec. 5B).
âWe turn now to a class of people whose origin is agricultural, but
whose occupation is in great part industrial. They are the light
infantry of capital, thrown by it, according to its needs, now to this
point, now to that. When they are not on the march, they âcamp.â Nomad
labour is used for various operations of building and draining,
brick-making, lime-burning, railway-making, &c. A flying column of
pestilence, it carries into the places in whose neighbourhood it pitches
its camp, small-pox, typhus, cholera, scarlet fever, &c. In undertakings
that involve much capital outlay, such as railways, &c., the contractor
himself generally provides his army with wooden huts and the like, thus
improvising villages without any sanitary provisions, outside the
control of the local boards, very profitable to the contractor, who
exploits the labourers in two-fold fashion â as soldiers of industry and
as tenants. According as the wooden hut contains 1, 2, or 3 holes, its
inhabitant, navvy, or whatever he may be, has to pay 1, 3, or 4
shillings weekly. One example will suffice. In September, 1864, Dr.
Simon reports that the Chairman of the Nuisances Removal Committee of
the parish of Sevenoaks sent the following denunciation to Sir George
Grey, Home Secretary: â
ââSmall-pox cases were rarely heard of in this parish until about twelve
months ago. Shortly before that time, the works for a railway from
Lewisham to Tunbridge were commenced here, and, in addition to the
principal works being in the immediate neighbourhood of this town, here
was also established the depĂ´t for the whole of the works, so that a
large number of persons was of necessity employed here. As cottage
accommodation could not be obtained for them all, huts were built in
several places along the line of the works by the contractor, Mr. Jay,
for their especial occupation. These huts possessed no ventilation nor
drainage, and, besides, were necessarily over-crowded, because each
occupant had to accommodate lodgers, whatever the number in his own
family might be, although there were only two rooms to each tenement.
The consequences were, according to the medical report we received, that
in the night-time these poor people were compelled to endure all the
horror of suffocation to avoid the pestiferous smells arising from the
filthy, stagnant water, and the privies close under their windows.
Complaints were at length made to the Nuisances Removal Committee by a
medical gentleman who had occasion to visit these huts, and he spoke of
their condition as dwellings in the most severe terms, and he expressed
his fears that some very serious consequences might ensue, unless some
sanitary measures were adopted. About a year ago, Mr. Jay promised to
appropriate a hut, to which persons in his employ, who were suffering
from contagious diseases, might at once be removed. He repeated that
promise on the 23^(rd) July last, but although since the date of the
last Promise there have been several cases of small-pox in his huts, and
two deaths from the same disease, yet he has taken no steps whatever to
carry out his promise. On the 9^(th) September instant, Mr. Kelson,
surgeon, reported to me further cases of small-pox in the same huts, and
he described their condition as most disgraceful. I should add, for your
(the Home Secretaryâs) information that an isolated house, called the
Pest-house, which is set apart for parishioners who might be suffering
from infectious diseases, has been continually occupied by such patients
for many months past, and is also now occupied; that in one family five
children died from small-pox and fever; that from the 1^(st) April to
the 1^(st) September this year, a period of five months, there have been
no fewer than ten deaths from small-pox in the parish, four of them
being in the huts already referred to; that it is impossible to
ascertain the exact number of persons who have suffered from that
disease although they are known to be many, from the fact of the
families keeping it as private as possibleââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
25, sec. 5C).
Letâs now see the effects of the crises on the better-paid part of the
working class. Here much is told by a correspondent of a newspaper, the
Morning Star, who, in January 1867, on the occasion of an industrial
crisis, visited the main localities in distress.
ââIn the East End districts of Poplar, Millwall, Greenwich, Deptford,
Limehouse and Canning Town, at least 15,000 workmen and their families
were in a state of utter destitution, and 3,000 skilled mechanics were
breaking stones in the workhouse yard (after distress of over half a
yearâs duration).... I had great difficulty in reaching the workhouse
door, for a hungry crowd besieged it.... They were waiting for their
tickets, but the time had not yet arrived for the distribution. The yard
was a great square place with an open shed running all round it, and
several large heaps of snow covered the paving-stones in the middle. In
the middle, also, were little wicker-fenced spaces, like sheep pens,
where in finer weather the men worked; but on the day of my visit the
pens were so snowed up that nobody could sit in them. Men were busy,
however, in the open shed breaking paving-stones into macadam. Each man
had a big paving-stone for a seat, and he chipped away at the
rime-covered granite with a big hammer until he had broken up, and
think! five bushels of it, and then he had done his dayâs work, and got
his dayâs pay â threepence and an allowance of food. In another part of
the yard was a rickety little wooden house, and when we opened the door
of it, we found it filled with men who were huddled together shoulder to
shoulder for the warmth of one anotherâs bodies and breath. They were
picking oakum and disputing the while as to which could work the longest
on a given quantity of food â for endurance was the point of honour.
Seven thousand ... in this one workhouse ... were recipients of relief
... many hundreds of them ... it appeared, were, six or eight months
ago, earning the highest wages paid to artisans.... Their number would
be more than doubled by the count of those who, having exhausted all
their savings, still refuse to apply to the parish, because they have a
little left to pawn. Leaving the workhouse, I took a walk through the
streets, mostly of little one-storey houses, that abound in the
neighbourhood of Poplar. My guide was a member of the Committee of the
Unemployed.... My first call was on an ironworker who had been seven and
twenty weeks out of employment. I found the man with his family sitting
in a little back room. The room was not bare of furniture, and there was
a fire in it. This was necessary to keep the naked feet of the young
children from getting frost bitten, for it was a bitterly cold day. On a
tray in front of the fire lay a quantity of oakum, which the wife and
children were picking in return for their allowance from the parish. The
man worked in the stone yard of the workhouse for a certain ration of
food, and threepence per day. He had now come home to dinner quite
hungry, as he told us with a melancholy smile, and his dinner consisted
of a couple of slices of bread and dripping, and a cup of milkless
tea.... The next door at which we knocked was opened by a middle-aged
woman, who, without saying a word, led us into a little back parlour, in
which sat all her family, silent and fixedly staring at a rapidly dying
fire. Such desolation, such hopelessness was about these people and
their little room, as I should not care to witness again. âNothing have
they done, sir,â said the woman, pointing to her boys, âfor six and
twenty weeks; and all our money gone â all the twenty pounds that me and
father saved when times were better, thinking it would yield a little to
keep us when we got past work. Look at it,â she said, almost fiercely,
bringing out a bank-book with all its well kept entries of money paid
in, and money taken out, so that we could see how the little fortune had
begun with the first five shilling deposit, and had grown by little and
little to be twenty pounds, and how it had melted down again till the
sum in hand got from pounds to shillings, and the last entry made the
book as worthless as a blank sheet. This family received relief from the
workhouse, and it furnished them with just one scanty meal per day....
Our next visit was to an iron labourerâs wife, whose husband had worked
in the yards. We found her ill from want of food, lying on a mattress in
her clothes, and just covered with a strip of carpet, for all the
bedding had been pawned. Two wretched children were tending her,
themselves looking as much in need of nursing as their mother. Nineteen
weeks of enforced idleness had brought them to this pass, and while the
mother told the history of that bitter past, she moaned as if all her
faith in a future that should atone for it were dead.... On getting
outside a young fellow came running after us, and asked us to step
inside his house and see if anything could be done for him. A young
wife, two pretty children, a cluster of pawn-tickets, and a bare room
were all he had to showâ âŚ
âAs it is the fashion amongst English capitalists to quote Belgium as
the Paradise of the labourer because âfreedom of labour,â or what is the
same thing, âfreedom of capital,â is there limited neither by the
despotism of Tradesâ Unions, nor by Factory Acts, a word or two on the
âhappinessâ of the Belgian labourer. Assuredly no one was more
thoroughly initiated in the mysteries of this happiness than the late M.
DucpĂŠtiaux, inspector-general of Belgian prisons and charitable
institutions, and member of the central commission of Belgian
statistics. Let us take his work: âBudgets ĂŠconomiques des classes
ouvrières de la Belgique,â Bruxelles, 1855. Here we find among other
matters, a normal Belgian labourerâs family, whose yearly income and
expenditure he calculates on very exact data, and whose conditions of
nourishment are then compared with those of the soldier, sailor, and
prisoner âŚ
ââCalculated at this rate, the resources of the family would amount, at
the maximum, to 1,068 francs a-year âŚâ
âAccording to this the budget of the family is:
âThe annual expenditure of the family would cause a deficit upon the
hypothesis that the labourer has the food of:
ââFrom an elaborate comparison between the diet of convicts in the
convict prisons in England, and that of paupers in workhouses and of
free labourers in the same country ... it certainly appears that the
former are much better fed than either of the two other classes,â whilst
âthe amount of labour required from an ordinary convict under penal
servitude is about one half of what would be done by an ordinary
day-labourerââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec. 5E).
A report on Public Health, from 1865, speaks of a visit made in a time
of epidemic to houses of farmers, citing among others the following :
ââA young woman having fever, lay at night in a room occupied by her
father and mother, her bastard child, two young men (her brothers), and
her two sisters, each with a bastard child â 10 persons in all. A few
weeks ago 13 persons slept in itââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec.
5E).
The modest size of this summary does not permit me to report here, from
the text, the minute aspects of the horrible state in which the farmers
of England lie.
Letâs close, therefore, this chapter, speaking of a completely special
plight, produced in England, among agricultural workers, by the
accumulation of capital.
The surplus agricultural population produces the effect of making wages
sink, while not even satisfying all of the needs of capital in
exceptional and urgent moments of labor, which are required in a given
period of the year from agriculture. It follows, therefore, that a great
number of women and children come to be employed for the momentary need
of capital, past which, these people go on to increase the countiesâ
overpopulation of workers. This fact has produced the system of
organized gangs in the counties of England.
âThe gang consists of 10 to 40 or 50 persons, women, young persons of
both sexes (13â18 years of age, although the boys are for the most part
eliminated at the age of 13), and children of both sexes (6â13 years of
age). At the head is the gang-master, always an ordinary agricultural
labourer, generally what is called a bad lot, a scapegrace, unsteady,
drunken, but with a dash of enterprise and savoir-faire. He is the
recruiting-sergeant for the gang, which works under him, not under the
farmer. He generally arranges with the latter for piece-work, and his
income, which on the average is not very much above that of an ordinary
agricultural labourer, depends almost entirely upon the dexterity with
which he manages to extract within the shortest time the greatest
possible amount of labour from his gang. The farmers have discovered
that women work steadily only under the direction of men, but that women
and children, once set going, impetuously spend their life-force â as
Fourier knew â while the adult male labourer is shrewd enough to
economise his as much as he can. The gang-master goes from one farm to
another, and thus employs his gang from 6 to 8 months in the year.
Employment by him is, therefore, much more lucrative and more certain
for the labouring families, than employment by the individual farmer,
who only employs children occasionally. This circumstance so completely
rivets his influence in the open villages that children are generally
only to be hired through his instrumentalityâŚ
âThe âdrawbacksâ of the system are the overwork of the children and
young persons, the enormous marches that they make daily to and from the
farms, 5, 6, and sometimes 7 miles distant, finally, the demoralisation
of the gang. Although the gang-master, who, in some districts is called
âthe driver,â is armed with a long stick, he uses it but seldom, and
complaints of brutal treatment are exceptional. He is a democratic
emperor, or a kind of Pied Piper of Hamelin. He must therefore be
popular with his subjects, and he binds them to himself by the charms of
the gipsy life under his direction. Coarse freedom, a noisy jollity, and
obscenest impudence give attractions to the gang. Generally the
gangmaster pays up in a public house; then he returns home at the head
of the procession reeling drunk, propped up right and left by a stalwart
virago, while children and young persons bring up the rear, boisterous,
and singing chaffing and bawdy songs. On the return journey what Fourier
calls âphanerogamie,â is the order of the day. The getting with child of
girls of 13 and 14 by their male companions of the same age, is common.
The open villages which supply the contingent of the gang, become Sodoms
and Gomorrahs, and have twice as high a rate of illegitimate births as
the rest of the kingdomâŚ
âThe gang in its classical form just described, is called the public,
common, or tramping gang. For there are also private gangs. These are
made up in the same way as the common gang, but count fewer members, and
work, not under a gang-master, but under some old farm servant, whom the
farmer does not know how to employ in any better way. The gipsy fun has
vanished here, but according to all witnesses, the payment and treatment
of the children is worse.
âThe gang-system, which during the last years has steadily increased,
clearly does not exist for the sake of the gang-master. It exists for
the enrichment of the large farmers, and indirectly of the landlordsâ
(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec. 5E).
ââSmall farmers never employ gangs.â âIt is not on poor land, but on
land which affords rent of from 40 to 50 shillings, that women and
children are employed in the greatest numbersââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1,
ch. 25, fn. 114).
âTo one of these gentlemen the taste of his rent was so grateful that he
indignantly declared to the Commission of Inquiry that the hole hubbub
was only due to the name of the system. If instead of âgangâ it were
called âthe Agricultural Juvenile Industrial Self-supporting
Association,â everything would be all rightâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch.
25, fn. 115).
ââGang work is cheaper than other work; that is why they are employed,â
says a former gang-master. âThe gang-system is decidedly the cheapest
for the farmer, and decidedly the worst for the children,â says a
farmerâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, fn. 116).
âFor the farmer there is no more ingenious method of keeping his
labourers well below the normal level, and yet of always having an extra
hand ready for extra work, of extracting the greatest possible amount of
labour with the least possible amount of money and of making adult male
labour âredundant.â From the exposition already made, it will be
understood why, on the one hand, a greater or less lack of employment
for the agricultural labourer is admitted, while on the other, the
gang-system is at the same time declared ânecessaryâ on account of the
want of adult male labour and its migration to the townsâ (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 25, sec. 5E).
Here we are at the end of our drama.
We met a worker at the market one day, come to sell his labor power, and
we saw him negotiate as equals with the money-owner. His still didnât
know how hard the Calvary road would be that he had to climb, not yet
had the most bitter cup approached his lips, all of which had to be
gulped down to the last dregs. The money-owner, not yet become a
capitalist, was nothing more than a modest owner of a little wealth,
timid and uncertain of the success of his new enterprise, in which he
was investing his fortune.
We the saw how the scene came to change.
The worker, after having generated, with his first overwork, capital,
was oppressed by the excessive labor of an extraordinarily prolonged
day. With relative surplus value the labor time necessary for his
maintenance was restricted and that of overwork prolonged, destined to
always nourish capital more richly. In simple cooperation we saw the
worker in a stationary discipline, and, dragged by a current made of a
linking of labor powers, exhausted evermore, by giving greater nutrition
to ever-growing capital. We saw the worker mutilated, crestfallen, and
depressed to the greatest degree by the division of labor, in
manufacturing. We saw him suffering unspeakable material and moral
pains, created for him by the introduction of machinery, in modern
industry. Expropriated of the last bit of artisan virtue, we saw him
reduced to a mere servant of the machine, transformed, from a member of
a living organism, into the most vulgar appendage of a mechanism,
tortured by labor dramatically increased by the machine, which at every
stretch threatens to tear off a shred of his flesh, or to grind him
completely between its terrible gears; and whatâs more we saw his wife
and tender children become slaves of capital. And in the meantime the
capitalist, immensely enriched, pays him a salary, which he is able to
lessen at his pleasure, even making a show of keeping it at the same
level as before, and even of increasing it. Finally we saw the worker,
made temporarily useless by the accumulation of capital, passing from
the active industrial army into the reserves, from then on, from this,
falling forever into the hell of pauperism. All the sacrifice is
consummated!
But however was all of this able to happen?
In a very simple way. The worker was, itâs true, the owner of his labor
power, with which he would have been able to produce much more than he
needed for himself and his family every day, but he was lacking however
the other indispensable elements of labor, that is, the means of
production and raw materials. Devoid therefore of any wealth, the worker
was forced, in order to live his life, to sell his only good, his labor
power to the money-owner, who made it his property. Private property and
the wage-worker, foundations of the system of capitalist production,
were the foremost cause of so much pain.
But that is unfair! Itâs wicked! And whosoever granted man the right of
private property? And however did the money-owner find himself in
possession of a primitive accumulation, origin of many infamies?
A terrible voice comes forth from the temple of the God of Capital, and
shouts: âAll is right, because all is written in the book of eternal
laws. Already a very distant time arose, in which all humans still
roamed free and equal throughout the Earth. Few of these were laborious,
sober and economical; all of the others idlers, revelers and
squanderers. Virtue made the first rich, and vice impoverished the
second. The few had the right to enjoy (these and their descendants) of
the virtuously accumulated wealth; while the many pushed by their misery
to sell themselves to the rich, were condemned to serve those and their
descendants eternally.â
Here is how certain friends of the bourgeois order explain the matter.
âSuch insipid childishness is every day preached to us in the defence of
property. M. Thiers, e.g., had the assurance to repeat it with all the
solemnity of a statesman to the French people, once so spirituelâ (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 26).
If such were the origin of primitive accumulation, the theory, which
derives from it, that of original sin and of predestination, would be so
just. The father was an idler and a reveler, the son will suffer the
misery. Such is the son of a rich man, he is predestined to be happy,
powerful, learned, civil, strong, etc.; such is the other son of a poor
man, he is predestined to be unhappy, weak, ignorant, brutish, immoral,
etc. A society, founded upon such a law, would certainly have to end, as
so many other societies already ended, less barbarous and less
hypocritical, so many religions and gods, starting from Christianity, in
whose laws one finds similar examples of justice.
And here we could put an end to our say, if we were allowed to end it
with this bourgeois foolishness. But our drama has a catastrophe worthy
of it, as we will soon see, witnessing its final act.
We begin the story, that history written by the bourgeoisie, and for the
use and consumption of the bourgeoisie; we search in it for the origin
of primitive accumulation, and itâs here that we find it.
In the most ancient age, flocks of nomadic people came to establish
themselves in those places better disposed and more favored by nature.
They founded cities, they devoted themselves to cultivating the land,
and to doing so many other necessary things for their own wellbeing. But
is here that they encounter and collide with each other in their
development, and war follows, deaths, fires, robberies and massacres.
All that belongs to vanquished becomes property of the victors,
including the persons who survived, who are all made slaves.
Here is the origin of primitive accumulation in antiquity. Letâs come
now to the Middle Ages.
In this second age of history, we find nothing other than invasions of
people into countries of other people, richer and more favored by
nature, and always the same refrain of massacres, robberies, fires, etc.
All that belongs to the vanquished becomes property of the victors, with
the sole difference being that the survivors no longer become slaves,
like in the ancient age, but serfs, and they pass with the land, to
which they are joined, into the power of their lords. Therefore not even
in the Middle Ages do we find the slightest trace of the idyllic
laboriousness, sobriety and parsimoniousness praised by a certain
bourgeois doctrine as the origin of primitive accumulation. And notice
that the Middle Ages is the age to which our most illustrious owners of
wealth are able to brag about tracing their origins. But letâs come
finally to the modern age.
The bourgeois revolution has destroyed feudalism, and has transmuted
servitude into wage-work. At the same time, however, it has taken away
from the worker the few means of existence, which the state of servitude
used to ensure for them. The serf, although he had to labor for the
greater part of his time for his lord, also had a piece of land with the
means and the time to cultivate it/to live his life. The bourgeoisie has
destroyed all of that, and from the serf has made a free (?) worker, who
has no other choice, either be exploited in the way that we already saw,
by the first capitalist who happens upon him, or die of hunger.
Letâs now get down to the particulars. Letâs begin the story of a
populace, and letâs see how the expropriation of agricultural
populations came to be, and the formation of the working masses,
destined to provide their labor power to modern industries. We will
take, as usual, the story of England, because if England is the country,
where the disease that we are studying is more developed than elsewhere,
it is given that it will always be able to offer us the most suitable
scope for our practical observations.
âIn England, serfdom had practically disappeared in the last part of the
14^(th) century. The immense majority of the population consisted then,
and to a still larger extent, in the 15^(th) century, of free peasant
proprietors, whatever was the feudal title under which their right of
property was hidden. In the larger seignorial domains, the old bailiff,
himself a serf, was displaced by the free farmer. The wage labourers of
agriculture consisted partly of peasants, who utilised their leisure
time by working on the large estates, partly of an independent special
class of wage labourers, relatively and absolutely few in numbers. The
latter also were practically at the same time peasant farmers, since,
besides their wages, they had allotted to them arable land to the extent
of 4 or more acres, together with their cottages. Besides they, with the
rest of the peasants, enjoyed the usufruct of the common land, which
gave pasture to their cattle, furnished them with timber, fire-wood,
turf, &c. âŚ
âThe prelude of the revolution that laid the foundation of the
capitalist mode of production, was played in the last third of the
15^(th), and the first decade of the 16^(th) century. A mass of free
proletarians was hurled on the labour market by the breaking-up of the
bands of feudal retainers, who, as Sir James Steuart well says,
âeverywhere uselessly filled house and castle.â Although the royal
power, itself a product of bourgeois development, in its strife after
absolute sovereignty forcibly hastened on the dissolution of these bands
of retainers, it was by no means the sole cause of it. In insolent
conflict with king and parliament, the great feudal lords created an
incomparably larger proletariat by the forcible driving of the peasantry
from the land, to which the latter had the same feudal right as the lord
himself, and by the usurpation of the common lands. The rapid rise of
the Flemish wool manufactures, and the corresponding rise in the price
of wool in England, gave the direct impulse to these evictions. The old
nobility had been devoured by the great feudal wars. The new nobility
was the child of its time, for which money was the power of all powers.
Transformation of arable land into sheep-walks was, therefore, its cry.
Harrison, in his âDescription of England, prefixed to Holinshedâs
Chronicles,â describes how the expropriation of small peasants is
ruining the country. âWhat care our great encroachers?â The dwellings of
the peasants and the cottages of the labourers were razed to the ground
or doomed to decay. âIf,â says Harrison, âthe old records of euerie
manour be sought... it will soon appear that in some manour seventeene,
eighteene, or twentie houses are shrunk... that England was neuer less
furnished with people than at the present... Of cities and townes either
utterly decaied or more than a quarter or half diminished, though some
one be a little increased here or there; of townes pulled downe for
sheepe-walks, and no more but the lordships now standing in them... I
could saie somewhat âŚâ
âThe process of forcible expropriation of the people received in the
16^(th) century a new and frightful impulse from the Reformation, and
from the consequent colossal spoliation of the church property. The
Catholic church was, at the time of the Reformation, feudal proprietor
of a great part of the English land. The suppression of the monasteries,
&c., hurled their inmates into the proletariat. The estates of the
church were to a large extent given away to rapacious royal favourites,
or sold at a nominal price to speculating farmers and citizens, who
drove out, en masse, the hereditary sub-tenants and threw their holdings
into one. The legally guaranteed property of the poorer folk in a part
of the churchâs tithes was tacitly confiscated. âPauper ubique jacet,â
cried Queen Elizabeth, after a journey through England. In the 43^(rd)
year of her reign the nation was obliged to recognise pauperism
officially by the introduction of a poor-rate. âThe authors of this law
seem to have been ashamed to state the grounds of it, for [contrary to
traditional usage] it has no preamble whatever.â By the 16^(th) of
Charles I., ch. 4, it was declared perpetual, and in fact only in 1834
did it take a new and harsher formâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 27).
âIn the south of England certain landed proprietors and well-to-do
farmers put their heads together and propounded ten questions as to the
right interpretation of the poor-law of Elizabeth. These they laid
before a celebrated jurist of that time, Sergeant Snigge (later a judge
under James I.) for his opinion. âQuestion 9 â Some of the more wealthy
farmers in the parish have devised a skilful mode by which all the
trouble of executing this Act (the 43^(rd) of Elizabeth) might be
avoided. They have proposed that we shall erect a prison in the parish,
and then give notice to the neighbourhood, that if any persons are
disposed to farm the poor of this parish, they do give in sealed
proposals, on a certain day, of the lowest price at which they will take
them off our hands; and that they will be authorised to refuse to any
one unless he be shut up in the aforesaid prison. The proposers of this
plan conceive that there will be found in the adjoining counties,
persons, who, being unwilling to labour and not possessing substance or
credit to take a farm or ship, so as to live without labour, may be
induced to make a very advantageous offer to the parish. If any of the
poor perish under the contractorâs care, the sin will lie at his door,
as the parish will have done its duty by them. We are, however,
apprehensive that the present Act (43^(rd) of Elizabeth) will not
warrant a prudential measure of this kind; but you are to learn that the
rest of the freeholders of the county, and of the adjoining county of B,
will very readily join in instructing their members to propose an Act to
enable the parish to contract with a person to lock up and work the
poor; and to declare that if any person shall refuse to be so locked up
and worked, he shall be entitled to no relief. This, it is hoped, will
prevent persons in distress from wanting relief, and be the means of
keeping down parishesââ (Marx, Capital, vol.1, ch. 27, fn. 9).
âThe advance made by the 18^(th) century shows itself in this, that the
law itself becomes now the instrument of the theft of the peopleâs land,
although the large farmers make use of their little independent methods
as well. The parliamentary form of the robbery is that of Acts for
enclosures of Commons, in other words, decrees by which the landlords
grant themselves the peopleâs land as private property, decrees of
expropriation of the people. Sir F. M. Eden refutes his own crafty
special pleading, in which he tries to represent communal property as
the private property of the great landlords who have taken the place of
the feudal lords, when he, himself, demands a âgeneral Act of Parliament
for the enclosure of Commonsâ (admitting thereby that a parliamentary
coup dâĂŠtat is necessary for its transformation into private property),
and moreover calls on the legislature for the indemnification for the
expropriated poorâŚ
ââIn Northamptonshire and Leicestershire,â [says Addington,] âthe
enclosure of common lands has taken place on a very large scale, and
most of the new lordships, resulting from the enclosure, have been
turned into pasturage, in consequence of which many lordships have not
now 50 acres ploughed yearly, in which 1,500 were ploughed formerly. The
ruins of former dwelling-houses, barns, stables, &c.,â are the sole
traces of the former inhabitants. âAn hundred houses and families have
in some open-field villages dwindled to eight or ten.... The landholders
in most parishes that have been enclosed only 15 or 20 years, are very
few in comparison of the numbers who occupied them in their open-field
state. It is no uncommon thing for 4 or 5 wealthy graziers to engross a
large enclosed lordship which was before in the hands of 20 or 30
farmers, and as many smaller tenants and proprietors. All these are
hereby thrown out of their livings with their families and many other
families who were chiefly employed and supported by them.â It was not
only the land that lay waste, but often land cultivated either in common
or held under a definite rent paid to the community, that was annexed by
the neighbouring landlords under pretext of enclosureâŚâ
ââWhen,â says Dr. Price, âthis land gets into the hands of a few great
farmers, the consequence must be that the little farmersâ (earlier
designated by him âa multitude of little proprietors and tenants, who
maintain themselves and families by the produce of the ground they
occupy by sheep kept on a common, by poultry, hogs, &c., and who
therefore have little occasion to purchase any of the means of
subsistenceâ) âwill be converted into a body of men who earn their
subsistence by working for others, and who will be under a necessity of
going to market for all they want.... There will, perhaps, be more
labour, because there will be more compulsion to it.... Towns and
manufactures will increase, because more will be driven to them in quest
of places and employment. This is the way in which the engrossing of
farms naturally operates. And this is the way in which, for many years,
it has been actually operating in this kingdom.â He sums up the effect
of the enclosures thus: âUpon the whole, the circumstances of the lower
ranks of men are altered in almost every respect for the worse. From
little occupiers of land, they are reduced to the state of day-labourers
and hirelings; and, at the same time, their subsistence in that state
has become more difficult.â In fact, usurpation of the common lands and
the revolution in agriculture accompanying this, told so acutely on the
agricultural labourers that, even according to Eden, between 1765 and
1780, their wages began to fall below the minimum, and to be
supplemented by official poor-law relief. Their wages, he says, âwere
not more than enough for the absolute necessaries of lifeâŚâ
âIn the 19^(th) century, the very memory of the connexion between the
agricultural labourer and the communal property had, of course,
vanished. To say nothing of more recent times, have the agricultural
population received a farthing of compensation for the 3,511,770 acres
of common land which between 1801 and 1831 were stolen from them and by
parliamentary devices presented to the landlords by the landlords?â
(Marx, Capital, ch. 27).
For the last expedients of great historic importance, for expropriating
rural workers, one must rightly look to the Highlands of Scotland, where
they had the most savage application. George Ensor, in a book published
in 1818, says:
âThe Scotch grandees dispossessed families as they would grub up
coppice-wood, and they treated villages and their people as Indians
harassed with wild beasts do, in their vengeance, a jungle with
tigers.... Man is bartered for a fleece or a carcase of mutton, nay,
held cheaper.... Why, how much worse is it than the intention of the
Moguls, who, when they had broken into the northern provinces of China,
proposed in council to exterminate the inhabitants, and convert the land
into pasture. This proposal many Highland proprietors have effected in
their own country against their own countrymenâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1,
ch. 27, fn. 29).
âAs an example of the method obtaining in the 19^(th) century, the
âclearingâ made by the Duchess of Sutherland will suffice here. This
person, well instructed in economy, resolved, on entering upon her
government, to effect a radical cure, and to turn the whole country,
whose population had already been, by earlier processes of the like
kind, reduced to 15,000, into a sheep-walk. From 1814 to 1820 these
15,000 inhabitants, about 3,000 families, were systematically hunted and
rooted out. All their villages were destroyed and burnt, all their
fields turned into pasturage. British soldiers enforced this eviction,
and came to blows with the inhabitants. One old woman was burnt to death
in the flames of the hut, which she refused to leave. Thus this fine
lady appropriated 794,000 acres of land that had from time immemorial
belonged to the clan. She assigned to the expelled inhabitants about
6,000 acres on the sea-shore â 2 acres per family. The 6,000 acres had
until this time lain waste, and brought in no income to their owners.
The Duchess, in the nobility of her heart, actually went so far as to
let these at an average rent of 2s. 6d. per acre to the clansmen, who
for centuries had shed their blood for her family. The whole of the
stolen clanland she divided into 29 great sheep farms, each inhabited by
a single family, for the most part imported English farm-servants. In
the year 1835 the 15,000 Gaels were already replaced by 131,000 sheep.
The remnant of the aborigines flung on the sea-shore tried to live by
catching fish. They became amphibious and lived, as an English author
says, half on land and half on water, and withal only half on both.
âBut the brave Gaels must expiate yet more bitterly their idolatry,
romantic and of the mountains, for the âgreat menâ of the clan. The
smell of their fish rose to the noses of the great men. They scented
some profit in it, and let the sea-shore to the great fishmongers of
London. For the second time the Gaels were hunted out.
âBut, finally, part of the sheep-walks are turned into deer preservesâ
(Marx, Capital, ch. 27).
âIn April 1866, 18 years after the publication of the work of Robert
Somers quoted above, Professor Leone Levi gave a lecture before the
Society of Arts on the transformation of sheep-walks into deer-forest,
in which he depicts the advance in the devastation of the Scottish
Highlands. He says, with other things: âDepopulation and transformation
into sheep-walks were the most convenient means for getting an income
without expenditure... A deer-forest in place of a sheep-walk was a
common change in the Highlands. The landowners turned out the sheep as
they once turned out the men ⌠Immense tracts of land, much of which is
described in the statistical account of Scotland as having a pasturage
in richness and extent of very superior description, are thus shut out
from all cultivation and improvement, and are solely devoted to the
sport of a few persons for a very brief period of the year.â The London
Economist of June 2, 1866, says, âAmongst the items of news in a Scotch
paper of last week, we read... âOne of the finest sheep farms in
Sutherlandshire, for which a rent of ÂŁ1,200 a year was recently offered,
on the expiry of the existing lease this year, is to be converted into a
deer-forest.âââ(Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 27, Note to the second
edition).
Other newspapers, from the same era, speak further of these feudal
instincts, which are more developed in England; but then some of these
conclude, proving with figures, that such a fact has not lessened the
national wealth at all.
âThe proletariat created by the breaking up of the bands of feudal
retainers and by the forcible expropriation of the people from the soil,
this âfreeâ proletariat could not possibly be absorbed by the nascent
manufactures as fast as it was thrown upon the world. On the other hand,
these men, suddenly dragged from their wonted mode of life, could not as
suddenly adapt themselves to the discipline of their new condition. They
were turned en masse into beggars, robbers, vagabonds, partly from
inclination, in most cases from stress of circumstances. Hence at the
end of the 15^(th) and during the whole of the 16^(th) century,
throughout Western Europe a bloody legislation against vagabondage. The
fathers of the present working class were chastised for their enforced
transformation into vagabonds and paupers. Legislation treated them as
âvoluntaryâ criminals, and assumed that it depended on their own good
will to go on working under the old conditions that no longer existed.
âIn England this legislation began under Henry VII.
âHenry VIII. 1530: Beggars old and unable to work receive a beggarâs
licence. On the other hand, whipping and imprisonment for sturdy
vagabonds. They are to be tied to the cart-tail and whipped until the
blood streams from their bodies, then to swear an oath to go back to
their birthplace or to where they have lived the last three years and to
âput themselves to labour.â What grim irony! In 27 Henry VIII. the
former statute is repeated, but strengthened with new clauses. For the
second arrest for vagabondage the whipping is to be repeated and half
the ear sliced off; but for the third relapse the offender is to be
executed as a hardened criminal and enemy of the common wealâ (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28).
âThomas More says in his âUtopiaâ: âTherfore that on covetous and
unsatiable cormaraunte and very plage of his native contrey maye
compasse aboute and inclose many thousand akers of grounde together
within one pale or hedge, the husbandman be thrust owte of their owne,
or els either by coneyne and fraude, or by violent oppression they be
put besydes it, or by wrongs and iniuries thei be so weried that they be
compelled to sell all: by one meanes, therfore, or by other, either by
hooke or crooke they muste needes departe awaye, poore, selye, wretched
soules, men, women, husbands, wiues, fatherlesse children, widowes,
wofull mothers with their yonge babes, and their whole household smal in
substance, and muche in numbre, as husbandrye requireth many handes.
Awaye thei trudge, I say, owte of their knowen accustomed houses,
fyndynge no place to reste in. All their housholde stuffe, which is very
little woorthe, thoughe it might well abide the sale: yet beeynge
sodainely thruste owte, they be constrayned to sell it for a thing of
nought. And when they haue wandered abrode tyll that be spent, what cant
they then els doe but steale, and then iustly pardy be hanged, or els go
about beggyng. And yet then also they be caste in prison as vagaboundes,
because they go aboute and worke not: whom no man wyl set a worke though
thei neuer so willyngly profre themselues therto.â Of these poor
fugitives of whom Thomas More says that they were forced to thieve,
â7,200 great and petty thieves were put to death,â in the reign of Henry
VIII, [as Hollinshed says in his âDescription of Englandâ]â (Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28, fn. 2).
âEdward VI.: A statute of the first year of his reign, 1547, ordains
that if anyone refuses to work, he shall be condemned as a slave to the
person who has denounced him as an idler. The master shall feed his
slave on bread and water, weak broth and such refuse meat as he thinks
fit. He has the right to force him to do any work, no matter how
disgusting, with whip and chains. If the slave is absent a fortnight, he
is condemned to slavery for life and is to be branded on forehead or
back with the letter S; if he runs away thrice, he is to be executed as
a felon. The master can sell him, bequeath him, let him out on hire as a
slave, just as any other personal chattel or cattle. If the slaves
attempt anything against the masters, they are also to be executed.
Justices of the peace, on information, are to hunt the rascals down. If
it happens that a vagabond has been idling about for three days, he is
to be taken to his birthplace, branded with a red-hot iron with the
letter V on the breast and be set to work, in chains, in the streets or
at some other labour. If the vagabond gives a false birthplace, he is
then to become the slave for life of this place, of its inhabitants, or
its corporation, and to be branded with an S. All persons have the right
to take away the children of the vagabonds and to keep them as
apprentices, the young men until the 24^(th) year, the girls until the
20^(th). If they run away, they are to become up to this age the slaves
of their masters, who can put them in irons, whip them, &c., if they
like. Every master may put an iron ring round the neck, arms or legs of
his slave, by which to know him more easily and to be more certain of
him. The last part of this statute provides, that certain poor people
may be employed by a place or by persons, who are willing to give them
food and drink and to find them work. This kind of parish slaves was
kept up in England until far into the 19^(th) century under the name of
âroundsmenââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28).
âThe author of the âEssay on Trade, etc.,â 1770, says, âIn the reign of
Edward VI. indeed the English seem to have set, in good earnest, about
encouraging manufactures and employing the poor. This we learn from a
remarkable statute which runs thus: âThat all vagrants shall be branded,
&câââ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28, fn. 1).
âElizabeth, 1572: Unlicensed beggars above 14 years of age are to be
severely flogged and branded on the left ear unless some one will take
them into service for two years; in case of a repetition of the offence,
if they are over 18, they are to be executed, unless some one will take
them into service for two years; but for the third offence they are to
be executed without mercy as felonsâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28).
âIn Elizabethâs time, ârogues were trussed up apace, and that there was
not one year commonly wherein three or four hundred were not devoured
and eaten up by the gallowes.â (Strypeâs âAnnals of the Reformation and
Establishment of Religion and other Various Occurrences in the Church of
England during Queen Elizabethâs Happy Reign.â Second ed., 1725, Vol.
2.) According to this same Strype, in Somersetshire, in one year, 40
persons were executed, 35 robbers burnt in the hand, 37 whipped, and 183
discharged as âincorrigible vagabonds.â Nevertheless, he is of opinion
that this large number of prisoners does not comprise even a fifth of
the actual criminals, thanks to the negligence of the justices and the
foolish compassion of the people; and the other counties of England were
not better off in this respect than Somersetshire, while some were even
worseâ (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28, fn. 2).
âJames 1: Any one wandering about and begging is declared a rogue and a
vagabond. Justices of the peace in petty sessions are authorised to have
them publicly whipped and for the first offence to imprison them for 6
months, for the second for 2 years. Whilst in prison they are to be
whipped as much and as often as the justices of the peace think fit...
Incorrigible and dangerous rogues are to be branded with an R on the
left shoulder and set to hard labour, and if they are caught begging
again, to be executed without mercy. These statutes, legally binding
until the beginning of the 18^(th) century, were only repealed [in
1714]â (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 28).
And here by means of such horrors, by means of so much blood the
expropriation of the agricultural population is completed, and the
formation of that working class, destined to feed modern industry. Less
than idyllic! It was sword and fire that were the only origin of
primitive accumulation; it was sword and fire that prepared the
necessary environment for capital to develop, the mass of human force
destined to nourish it; and if today sword and fire are no longer the
ordinary means of the ever-growing accumulation, it is because it has
another method, in its stead, much more inexorable and terrible, one of
the glorious modern achievements of the bourgeoisie, a method that forms
a necessary part of the mechanism itself of capitalist production, a
method that acts by itself, without making much noise, without producing
scandal, in short a perfectly civil method: hunger. And for him that
rebels against hunger, always and forever sword and fire.
The modest size of this summary does not permit me to tell also of the
glories of capital in the colonies. I refer the reader to the history of
discoveries, starting from that of Christopher Columbus, and of all the
colonizations, limiting myself only to cite in this regard the words of
âW. Howitt, a man who makes a speciality of Christianity, [who] says:
âThe barbarities and desperate outrages of the so-called Christian race,
throughout every region of the world, and upon every people they have
been able to subdue, are not to be paralleled by those of any other
race, however fierce, however untaught, and however reckless of mercy
and of shame, in any age of the earth.â
âIf money, according to Augier, âcomes into the world with a congenital
blood-stain on one cheek,â capital comes dripping from head to foot,
from every pore, with blood and dirt.â (Marx, Capital, vol. 1, ch. 31).
And this is pure, or bourgeois, history, a sad history of blood, which
would deserve to be well read and meditated on by you, who know in your
virtue how to conceive a holy horror for the lust of the blood of modern
revolutionaries; by you, who declare not being able to allow the workers
the sole use of the moral means.
The disease is sweeping. Itâs been a long time that the workers of the
civilized world have known it; certainly not all, but a great number,
and these are already preparing the means of action to destroy it.
They have considered these:
private property;
founded upon a new class rule, but upon the end of all class privileges
and monopolies and upon the equality of rights and duties;
workers themselves.
And so a mighty voice has shouted: âWorkers of the world, unite! No more
rights without duties, no more duties without rights! Revolution!â
But the revolution demanded by the workers is not a revolution of
pretext, it is not the practical method of a moment to reach a given
aim. Even the bourgeoisie, like so many others, demanded the revolution
one day; but only to supplant the nobility, and to substitute for the
feudal system of serfdom that more refined and cruel system of
wage-work. And they call this progress and civility! In fact every day
we help the ridiculous show of the bourgeoisie, who go babbling the word
revolution, with the sole aim of being able to jump up onto the maypole
tree, and to grab power. The workersâ revolution is the revolution for
the revolution.
The word âRevolutionâ, taken in its largest and truest sense, means
turning, transformation, change. As such, revolution is the soul of all
infinite mass. In fact, all in nature changes, but nothing is created
and nothing is destroyed, as chemistry shows us. Mass, remaining always
in the same quantity, can change form in infinite ways. When mass loses
its old form and acquires a new one, it passes from the old life, in
which it dies, to the new life, in which it is born. When our spinner,
using a familiar example for us, transformed the 10 kilos of cotton into
10 kilos of thread, what else came about if not the death of 10 kilos of
mass in the form of cotton, and at their birth in the form of thread?
And when the weaver transforms the thread into cloth, what else will
come about if not the matter passing from a life of string unto a life
of cloth, as it has passed already before from a life of cotton unto a
life of thread? Mass, therefore, passing from one turn of life to
another, lives ever-changing, transforming, revolutionizing.
Now, if revolution is the law of nature, which is all, it must
necessarily also be the law of humanity, which is a part of nature. But
you have a few men upon the Earth who do not think this is so, or,
rather, who close their eyes so as not to see and their ears so as not
to hear.
âYes, it is true,â I hear shouting from a bourgeois, âthe natural law,
the revolution that you claim, is the absolute regulator of human
relations. The fault of all the oppressions, of all the exploitations,
of all the tears and all of the massacres they are caused by, one must
justly attribute to this inexorable law that imposes revolution upon us,
that is, continuous transformation, the struggle for existence, the
absorption of the weaker made stronger, the sacrifice of the less
perfect types for the development of the more perfect types. If hundreds
of workers are burned up for the wellbeing of only one bourgeois, that
happens without the slightest fault of this, that is indeed sad and
dreary, but only by the decree of natural law, of revolution.â
If one speaks in such a way, the workers ask nothing better, who wish
for transformation, the struggle for existence, revolution, under the
same natural law, the ones indeed preparing themselves to be stronger,
to sacrifice all monstrous and parasitic plants for the complete and
flourishing development of the most beautiful human tree, whole and
perfect, which it must be, in all of the wholeness of its human
character.
But the bourgeoisie are too fearful and pious to be able to appeal to
the natural law of revolution. They have been able to invoke it in a
moment of drunkenness; but, afterwards back to their normal selves,
their accounts done, and having found that their doings were nice and
pleasing, they gave themselves to shouting until they couldnât anymore:
âOrder, religion, family, property, conservation!â It is so that, after
having arrived at conquering, with massacre, fire and robbery, the role
of the dominators and exploiters of the human race, they believe that
they can stop the course of revolution; without realizing, in their
stupidity, that they can do nothing else, with their efforts, than to
make horrible troubles for humanity, and as a consequence for
themselves, with the sudden explosions of the revolutionary force they
madly repress.
The revolution, the material obstacles that oppose it shot down, and
left free in its path, will by itself be enough to create the most
perfect balance, order, peace, and the most complete happiness between
people, because people, in their free development, will not proceed in
the manner of wild animals but in the manner of human beings, eminently
reasonable and civil, who understand that no person can be truly free
and happy if they are not within the common liberty and happiness of all
of humanity. No more rights without duties, no more duties without
right. Therefore no more struggle for existence between people, but
struggle for existence of all people with nature, by appropriating from
the great sum of natural forces for the benefit of all of humanity.
The disease known, it is easy to know the remedy: revolution for the
revolution.
But how will the workers be able to restore the course of the
revolution?
This is not the place for a revolutionary program, already elaborated
and published long ago elsewhere in other books; I confine myself to
conclude, replying with the words taken from the lips of a worker and
placed in epigraph to this volume: âThe worker has made everything; and
the worker can destroy everything, because he can rebuild everything.â
Les Molières, 27 July 1879
Most Esteemed Sir,
Iâm sending with the same courier two copies of your work Capital,
summarized briefly by me. I wanted to deliver them to you sooner, but
only now was I able to obtain some copies by the benevolence of a
friend, who with his intervention was able to affect the publication of
the book.
In fact, if the publication could have been done at my expense, I would
have desired to submit the manuscript to your examination beforehand.
But in fear of seeing a favorable opinion escape me, I hurried to allow
the publication proposed to me. And it is only now that I was able to
address you in the hopes that you may say if I was able to comprehend
and express your exact concept.
I pray, sir, that you appreciate the expressions of my deepest respect
and that you put your trust in me.
Most devotedly,
Carlo Cafiero
Dear Citizen,
The sincerest of thanks for the two copies of your work! At the same
time I received two similar works, one written in Serbian, the other in
English (published in the United States), but they both are faulty,
wanting to give a succinct and popular summary of Capital and clinging,
at the same time, too pedantically to the scientific form of discussion.
In this way, they seem to me to miss more or less their principle
purpose: that of moving the public for whom the summaries are intended.
And here is the great superiority of your work.
As far as the conception of things, I believe Iâm not deceiving myself
in attributing a gap to the considerations espoused in your preface, and
that is the proof that the material conditions necessary to the
emancipation of the proletariat are generated spontaneously by the
development of capitalist exploitation. After all, I agree with you (if
I interpreted your preface well) that it isnât necessary to overload
those who you wish to educate. Nothing will prevent you from returning,
at the opportune time, to the charge of bringing out this materialist
basis of Capital.
Renewing my thanks, I am most devoted to you,
Karl Marx
[1] See Karl Marx:
Capital. A Critique of Political Economy. Volume I
.
[2] See John Stuart Mill,
Principles of Political Economy
.