đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș anarcho-the-science-of-class-warfare.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 07:45:19. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: The âscienceâ of class warfare Author: Anarcho Date: October 16, 2009 Language: en Topics: science, class war Source: Retrieved on 1st February 2021 from https://anarchism.pageabode.com/?p=371
Since the 1970s, capitalist economic policy has been rooted in âfighting
inflation,â an euphemism for âcrushing the workers.â This policy is
rooted in the notion of the âNon-Accelerating Inflation Rate of
Unemploymentâ (or NAIRU) and, like most of the silly and/or nasty ideas
in modern economics, has its roots in the works of the late and
unlamented Milton Friedman.
The NAIRU is based on the idea that there is some rate of unemployment
below which inflation starts to rise. The problem is, it is invisible.
There is no way of determining what that rate is beyond looking at what
actually happens to the inflation rate. So the economic policy across
much of the world is based on a group of technocrats trying to guess
where an invisible value is and, to make matters worse, the rate changes
over time.
This is because the rate is dependent on many factors, the key ones
relate to working class power â i.e. our ability to demand and gain
better pay and conditions. The logic is simple. As unemployment falls,
workers feel more able to demand better pay and conditions, form unions
and so on. This raises the wage bill, which companies off-set by raising
prices. This, in turn, gets workers to demand higher wages and inflation
starts to accelerate. This was the process at work in the 1970s and was
broken by Thatcherâs and Reaganâs deep economic crises brought upon by
the application of Friedmanâs Monetarism nonsense (this silly dogma was
very fashionable with the right back then but did not survive impact
with reality, as predicted by such post-Keynesians as Nicholas Kaldor).
With the staggering levels of unemployment this theory produced, workers
could no longer offset price increases and so costs required for
ârecoveryâ were passed onto the working class.
Needless to say, Edmund Phelps (the economist who formulated the modern
version of this theory) was given the (non-)Nobel prize for economics in
October of 2006. Unsurprisingly, the Economist was cock-a-hoop over this
(âA natural choice: Edmund Phelps earns the economics professionâs
highest accoladeâ, Oct 12^(th) 2006). The reasons why become clear.
According to the magazine, âPhelps won his laurels in part for kicking
the feet from under his intellectual forerunnersâ by presenting a
neo-classical explanation for the breakdown of the so-called âPhillips
curveâ which presented a statistical trade-off between inflation and
unemployment (âunemployment was low in Britain when wage inflation was
high, and high when inflation was lowâ). The problem was that economists
âwere quick â too quick â to conclude that policymakers therefore faced
a grand, macroeconomic trade-off.â The magazine presents it as follows:
âIn such a tight labour market, companies appease workers by offering
higher wages. They then pass on the cost in the form of dearer prices,
cheating workers of a higher real wage. Thus policymakers can engineer
lower unemployment only through deception.â
Phelps innovation was to argue that â[e]ventually workers will cotton
on, demanding still higher wages to offset the rising cost of living.
They can be duped for as long as inflation stays one step ahead of their
rising expectations of what it will be.â This meant that the âstable
trade-off depicted by the Phillips curve is thus a dangerous mirageâ
which broke down in the 1970s with the rise of stagflation (high
unemployment and high inflation). Phelps, reports the Economist, argued
that there was a ânaturalâ rate of unemployment, where âworkersâ
expectations are fulfilled, prices turn out as anticipated, and they no
longer sell their labour under false pretences.â This âequilibrium does
not, sadly, imply full employmentâ and so capitalism required âleaving
some workers mouldering on the shelf. Given economistsâ almost
theological commitment to the notion that markets clear, the presence of
unemployment in the world requires a theodicy to explain it.â The
religious metaphor does seem appropriate as most economists (and the
Economist) do treat the market like a god (a theodicy is a specific
branch of theology and philosophy that attempts to reconcile the
existence of evil in the world with the assumption of a benevolent
God)..
And, as with all gods, sacrifices are required and Phelpsâ theory is the
means by which this is achieved. As the Economist notes: âin much of his
work he contends that unemployment is necessary to cow workers, ensuring
their loyalty to the company and their diligence on the job, at a wage
the company can afford to payâ (i.e., one which would ensure a profit).
Unsurprisingly, attempts to lower the ânatural rateâ have all involved
using the state to break the economic power of working class people
(attacking unions, increasing interest rates to raise unemployment in
order to temporarily âcowâ workers and so on). All so that profits can
be kept high in the face of the rising wages caused by the natural
actions of the market!
Yet Phelpsâ conclusions are hardly new. Anarchists and other socialists
have been arguing that capitalism has no tendency to full employment
since the 1840s either in theory or in practice. They have also noted
how periods of full employment bolstered workersâ power and harmed
profits. It is the fundamental disciplinary mechanism of the system (âa
whip in [the bossesâ] hands, constantly held over you, so you will slave
hard for him and âbehaveâ yourself,â to use Berkmanâs memorable phrase).
It is, in other words, âinherent in the wage systemâ and âthe
fundamental condition of successful capitalist production.â While it is
âdangerous and degradingâ to the worker, it is âvery advantageous to the
bossâ and so capitalism âcanât exist without it.â (Alexander Berkman,
What is Anarchism?, p. 26) As such, it is ironic Phelps has got a
(non-)Nobel prize for restating, in neo-classical jargon, the model of
the labour market long dismissed as nonsense by neo-classical economists
(the main branch of the religion).
Interestingly, the business section of the Washington Post reported
Phelps reward under the surreal headline âYou Might Have to Thank Him
for Your Job.â He, like Friedman, argued that the state has to keep the
unemployment rate at or above the (unknown and unknowable) ânatural
rateâ in order to keep inflation from accelerating. In other words, you
have to make people unemployed or fear being made unemployed (by raising
interest rates and slowing the economy) for capitalism to survive. Given
Phelpsâ theory, it would make far more sense for the Washington Post to
produce headlines like âYou Might Have to Thank Him for Not Having a
Jobâ; âYou Might Have to Thank Him for Your Job Insecurityâ; âYou Might
Have to Thank Him for Exploding Inequality caused by Stagnating Pay in
spite of Rising Productivityâ; or âYou Might Have to Thank Him for the
annual transfer of $235 billion from labour to capital since 1979â
(figure from âThe State of Working America 2006/7â). But, as with
economics, why let reality get in the way of a snappy sound-bite?
That this state manipulation is considered consistent with the âfree
marketâ says a lot about the bankruptcy of the capitalist system and its
defenders. But, then, for defenders of the system state intervention on
behalf of capital is part of the natural order, unlike state
intervention (at least in rhetoric) on behalf of the working class. Thus
neo-liberal capitalism is based on monetary policy that explicitly tries
to weaken working class resistance by means of unemployment. If
âinflationâ (i.e. labour income) starts to increase, interest rates are
raised so causing unemployment and, it is hoped, putting the plebs back
in their place.
This was the message of Mervyn King, the governor of the Bank of
England, a few days before Pelphs was given his prize. King warned
Britainâs pay bargainers to accept wage restraints or interest rates
would increase. This is despite dearer energy bills. King stated that
the current small increases in earnings were not âsufficiently
restrainedâ to compensate for the inflationary effects of higher energy
prices and unfavourable changes in the prices of imports and exports.
âUltimately, both developments must result in lower real incomes,â he
said (the silence on bosses exploding pay remains, as always,
deafening). In other words, the working class must pay the price for
capitalismâs problems. Hence the need to âto keep our eye on the ball
and monitor closely the evolution of wage and cost pressures.â As a
statement of class war, it is hard to find a more succinct one.
Of course, according to the eternal and sacred law of âsupply and
demand,â wage rises are to be expected when unemployment falls. The laws
of the market are the justification for bossesâ massive rises, after
all. Equally, according to the âscienceâ of neo-classical economics,
firms are price takers and so cannot influence market price of their
goods. But the reality of capitalism is far removed from neo-classical
ideology and the state is always at hand to give capital a helping hand.
Yet even in the unreal world of capitalist economics, wage rises need
not cause price increases. This is because wage increases can be offset
by reductions in profits.
However, this is not an option in reality. As King notes, while âwage
pressures have so far been subdued, it is still not clear that earnings
have been sufficiently restrained to accommodate the past rises in
energy prices and the fall over the past year in the prices of our
exports relative to our imports without a squeeze on profits.
Ultimately, both developments must result in lower real incomes.â Sorry,
but no. Why should there not be a âsqueeze on profitsâ? Are profits
sacred? Why should the majority accept âlower real incomesâ so that the
few can get see their incomes rise? And Blair declared that the class
war was over. Someone should tell KingâŠ