đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș kevin-carson-vulgar-libertarian-smackdown.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:49:37. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Vulgar Libertarian Smackdown Author: Kevin Carson Date: March 7, 2005 Language: en Topics: right libertarianism Source: Retrieved on 3rd September 2021 from https://mutualist.blogspot.com/2005/03/vulgar-libertarian-smackdown.html
Some good stuff at Our Word is Our Weapon this week.
In a post on water privatization, Jim gets in a good one against the
ASIâs Alex Singleton, who wrote an (obviously) pro-privatization post at
the Globalization Institute blog.
In addition to mysterious memory lapses when it comes to revealing
vested interests, Alexâs post for the Globalization Institute betrays
all the hallmarks of an ASI blogpost: no link to the material being
criticised so that people can actually get the other side of the
argument, no factual evidence to back up your assertions, carefully
phrased generalisations that sound more impressive than they actually
are, and so on. One thing is different, though: the ASI blog is famed
for deleting comments and trackbacks that express dissenting views,
while the Globalization Institute saves time by not allowing any
comments or trackbacks in the first place!
Incidentally, why is it that for people like our friends at the ASI,
âprivatizationâ always equates to âsell-off to a capitalist
corporationâ? Itâs hardly self-evident. Producer and consumer
cooperatives, commons and other communal property, etc., have just as
legitimate a claim to being âprivate propertyâ as General Motors or
Wal-Mart. In fact, theyâre probably a lot closer to the forms of
property that would predominate in a genuine free market than GM or
Wally World. Hereâs what Karl Hess had to say in Libertarian Forum back
in 1970:
Libertarianism is a peopleâs movement and a liberation movement. It
seeks the sort of open, non-coercive society in which the people, the
living, free, distinct people, may voluntarily associate, dis-associate,
and, as they see fit, participate in the decisions affecting their
lives. This means a truly free market in everything from ideas to
idiosyncracies. It means people free collectively to organize the
resources of their immediate community or individualistically to
organize them; it means the freedom to have a community-based and
supported judiciary where wanted, none where not, or private arbitration
services where that is seen as most desirable. The same with police. The
same with schools, hospitals, factories, farms, laboratories, parks, and
pensions. Liberty means the right to shape your own institutions. It
opposes the right of those institutions to shape you simply because of
accreted power or gerontological status.
And more than one libertarian with the best of free market credentials
has argued that the best way to âprivatizeâ state property is to treat
it as âunownedâ property (in the Lockean sense), to be âhomesteadedâ by
those currently using it (either the labor force or the consumers of its
services). For example, in the same first volume of Libertarian Forum
that the quote from Karl Hess is found, Murray Rothbard argued that
government property is always and everywhere fair game for the
libertarian; for the libertarian must rejoice every time any piece of
governmental, and therefore stolen, property is returned by any means
necessary to the private sector.... Therefore, the libertarian must
cheer any attempt to return stolen, governmental property to the private
sector: whether it be in the cry, âThe streets belong to the peopleâ, or
âthe parks belong to the peopleâ, or the schools belong to those who use
them, i.e. the students and faculty. The libertarian believes that
things not properly owned revert to the first person who uses and
possesses them, e.g. the homesteader who first clears and uses virgin
land; similarly, the libertarian must support any attempt by campus
âhomesteadersâ the students and faculty, to seize power in the
universities from the governmental or quasi-governmental bureaucracy.
Rothbard and Hans-Hermann Hoppe both proposed âprivatizingâ state
industry in post-communist societies on a radically different model from
the ASI. To quote Rothbard:
It would be far better to enshrine the venerable homesteading principle
at the base of the new desocialized property system. Or, to revive the
old Marxist slogan: âall land to the peasants, all factories to the
workers!â
Larry Gambone has suggested âmutualizingâ social services:
decentralizing them to the smallest possible unit of control, and making
them the cooperative property of those using them. If we take the final
step of funding them entirely with voluntary user fees, we will have
completed the process described by Proudhon in General Idea of the
Revolution in the Nineteenth Century, of âdissolving the state within
the social body.â The state will wither away, its successor organization
being just another form of voluntary cooperation: and thereâs no reason
why the âsocial bodyâ thatâs left should have a corporate face.
If anything, water seems to be an ideal candidate for mutualization,
since (as the World Development Movement study Jim links to argues)
local water utilities are a natural monopoly, and insulated from
competition by the nature of things).
For a start, water is a natural monopoly meaning that competition â and
any resulting efficiencies â is impossible. As the European Commissionâs
Directorate General (DG) for Competition which, amongst other things, is
working on how to organise the water sector within the European Union,
recently stated, âthe liberalisation of water is unlikely to result in
the same benefits as other network industries because a large proportion
of the cost of supply of residential customers is incurred by the
distribution network (which would remain a monopoly) and there is little
scope for supply from distant sources.â In short, this is saying that
there will be no competition and no resulting efficiency gains. [p. 17]
Another interesting point is that âprivatizationâ often saves
governments little if any expenditure, after taking into account the
concessions needed to lure a private buyer or even subsidies to keep the
âprivatizedâ utility profitable. âCrony capitalismâ doesnât do this
phenomenon justice--a better term would be âlootingâ:
Instead of encouraging investment, privatisation has left governments
offering increased concessions to entice investors to acquire their
assetsâ often to meet the requirements of donors. For example, between
1991and 1998 the Brazilian Government made some US$85 billion through
the sale of state run enterprises. However, over the same period, it
spent US$87 billion âpreparingâ the companies for privatisation.
Rather than being a major source of finance, private contractors are
committing little of their own capital and are instead looking to
municipalities, central government or donor governments/institutions to
provide the money....
In fact, in many cases foreign companies are relying on the donor
community to bail them out when they get it wrong. [p. 23]
I do, however, dispute one of the WDMâs criticisms of privatized water:
that it fails to extend water and sanitation networks to the poor. All
public services should be operated on a cost basis, at least as an end
goal. Regardless of whether a water or sewer system is owned by state,
corporation, or mutual, it is unjust to force some people to pay rates
higher than the cost of delivering services, in order to subsidize
costlier services to the unfavorably situated. It seems to me that
outlying areas where the extension of centralized water and sewer grids
is prohibitively expensive are clearly cases in which it makes sense to
do as much as possible with decentralized, intermediate technology:
maximizing capture and storage of rainwater with cisterns, recycling
wash water, using cheap and well-designed composting toilets, mulching
and soil-building to minimize irrigation needs, etc.
In another great post, Jim eviscerates some vulgar libertarian
boilerplate at the ASI blog, also by Alex Singleton. This time, itâs
against Fair Trade coffee.
This part of Jimâs response, in particular, is crucial:
Itâs interesting that the ASI makes no mention whatsoever of the
remarkably uncompetitive nature of the world coffee market. As pointed
out by ActionAid and Jacques Morisset of the World Bank, the gap between
the price paid to coffee farmers and the prices paid by consumers has
grown greatly in the last few decades, a process which can be largely
attributed to the increasing concentration of market power among fewer
and fewer giant firms at the processing and retail stages of the
production chain. Farmers are faced with an oligopsony, and consumers
with an oligopoly â with the net result of this grossly uncompetitive
market being a great transfer of wealth from farmers and consumers to
hugely profitable firms.
Itâs a point that needs to be brought to Singletonâs attention. The
bulleted point in the latterâs post that struck me most was this:
Mechanization means that only a small proportion of the worldâs coffee
producers are actually needed. In Brazil five people and a machine
produce the same amount of coffee as 500 people in Guatemala. We should
help people adapt, not encourage them to stay in outdated jobs.
Itâs quite telling that Singleton refers to âmechanizationâ as some sort
of autonomous process that just happens, and people either âadaptâ to or
die. But unless youâre writing a puff piece for the ASI, there are
several questions that seem to spring to mind spontaneously. For
example, which firms decided what the standard model of production would
be? How many of production is controlled by how many firms? How much of
the coffee-growing land do they own or control, and how did they come by
it? In short, how, and by what right, did they come to be in a position
to âoutdateâ the jobs of people using more labor-intensive production
methods?
Whenever I hear someone attempting to depict globalization or the like
as an impersonal force of nature that just âhappens,â to which we all
need to âadapt,â I instinctively turn on my bullshit detector. It
reminds me of the demands in Who Moved My Cheese? that we âadaptâ to
âchange,â without asking a bunch of insubordinate questions about whoâs
imposing the change and who stands to benefit from it. Under state
capitalism, the prevalence of certain organizational cultures and
prodution technologies industry-wide, in any industry, is seldom (if
ever) the result of spontaneous market forces. It usually turns out to
be the result of domination, of revolution imposed from the top-down by
the holders of illegitimate power, and has about as much to do with
âfree marketsâ as Gosplan.
The corporate deadlock on world food production is almost entirely the
result of state intervention in the market.
For example, the new plant varieties (including genetically engineered
varieties) identified with the âGreen Revolutionâ are heavily dependent
on state funding of research and development, and on the stateâs
enforcement of so-called âintellectual property rightsâ (really a state
grant of monopoly privilege). One of the uses of so-called âintellectual
propertyâ is to prohibit the saving and distribution of seeds between
producers, and thus to drastically increase the cost of seed inputs. In
general, patents have huge concentrating and cartelizing effects on the
market structure: and this is particularly true of genetically modified
foods.
The market share of GM foods in the West reflects the imposition of
regulatory controls on the free flow of information in the market. In
the U.S., especially, the FDA acts on behalf of agribusiness to prohibit
processers or grocers from labelling GMO content; food libel laws are
also used to suppress the free flow of information. The market share of
GM foods depends on forcibly preventing consumers from learning of GMO
content.
The stateâs transportation subsidies, which externalize distribution
costs on the taxpayer, make it more feasible to offshore food production
to giant agribusiness plantations in the Third World.
The stateâs collusion with both quasi-feudal landlords and agribusiness
TNCs has resulted in millions of peasants being robbed of their
traditional rights in the land, their private plots being consolidated
for cash-crop agriculture. As one small example, consider this
description of Unileverâs operation in India (Hindustan Lever, or HLL):
Adivasi villagers say they have been harassed and intimidated, that
their houses have been pulled down and their tea plants uprooted in a
long-running land ownership dispute with estate managers at the
Davershola tea plantation, owned by HLL. Five adivasi tribes of the
Gudalur valley, including the Paniyas, Bettakurumbas and Irulas, are
fighting for their ancestral rights to the land. Villager Vayal Madan
from Kadchinkolly village says his family lived in constant fear of HLL
estate managers. âWe were terrified,â he says. âThey would tear down
semi-permanent huts that we built. Anything we planted was always
destroyed. They would chase us off our landâŠUnilever is very powerful.
This is a company controlling thousands of acres, yet they are not
ashamed to evict poor adivasis who have a quarter to half an acre of
tea.â
But the current war on peasant proprietors is merely a mopping-up
operation. Given the track record of expropriation by the colonialists
of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, and the genocidal
actions to thwart land reform like that taken in Guatemala in 1954, itâs
a wonder the landed oligarchies can find any traditional property rights
to abrogate. The past two centuries in the Third World have been a
replay of the English enclosure movement, and the persistence of
traditional property rights is a quaint relic comparable to the
occasional survival of peasant rights of commons in England.
The handful of giant, vertically integrated transnational agribusiness
corporations that control most of the food supply chain, from the
development of genetically engineered seeds through the distribution of
processed food, are enemies of free markets. Consider this quote from
Dwayne Andreas, the former CEO of one of them (Acher Daniels Midland):
There isnât one grain of anything in the world that is sold in a free
market. Not one! The only place you see a free market is in the speeches
of politicians.
Or this one by ADM President James Randall:
We have a saying in our company: âOur competitors are our friends.Our
customers are the enemy.â
It would be hard to find any nominally private industry thatâs more of a
state dependency than corporate agribusiness. Indeed, the distinction
between âpublicâ and âprivateâ becomes meaningless at the commanding
heights of the state capitalist economy. The giant corporations occupy
the same position in relation to the state as did the great landlords
under feudalism: they donât just control the state; they are the state.