💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › david-andrew-andrade-our-social-system.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 08:58:27. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Our Social System Author: David Andrew Andrade Date: 1890 Language: en Topics: anti-capitalist, Australia, individualist, mutualism, Melbourne Anarchist Club Source: https://en.wikisource.org/wiki/Our_Social_System
“I have said a hundred times, and I will repeat it till I die, that our
old form of society is dying.” To many, these words of Chateaubriand may
sound ridiculous, and merely the pessimistic wail of a false prophet;
but others, who have carefully studied the world in which they live, and
taken account of the violent internal struggles which are torturing the
society of the present day, will know that the statement is any but a
rash one, and that there are forces now at work in our midst which, if
they succeed in developing their influence much more fully, will ere
long wreck our civilization as they have wrecked so many grand
civilisations in the past.
What is the nature of our civilization? What is the controlling force
which is guiding our destinies, and regulating our actions towards our
fellowmen? What is the nature of the system; is it operating for good or
evil; could it be replaced by a better, or a worse, one; are its
elements preservative or self-destructive? Is our social system a
success, or is it a failure? These questions are to be considered in the
following pages, and considered fairly and squarely. This is recognized
to be a scientific age—an age of facts: let the facts then answer.
We pride ourselves on our system, which we call “civilized,” and compare
it with those primitive forms of society which we call “barbarian.” We
point at our grand works of art, our wondrous discoveries in science,
our massive buildings, railways, telegraphs, tunnels, bridges, shipping,
mining appliances, and machinery of all kinds; and then we drop a
sympathetic tear on the poor heathen who haven’t these luxuries. Oh, the
glories of civilization!
​But when we begin to ask more about it, we see things in a slightly
different light. The grand works of art are here, true enough; but we
soon find out that those who have been most active in their production
are rarely the ones who can afford to enjoy their beauty. Wonderful
scientific discoveries are constantly being made, but the reward is to
the speculating capitalist and not to the inventor. No sooner is a thing
produced than it passes into the hands of others: the builders of ships
cannot afford to travel in them; those who construct our railways cannot
afford the luxury of steam locomotion; tramways are constructed, and
they build fortunes for those who do not make them; builders do not
inhabit the fine houses they build, but live in wretched tenements only
fitted for the population of the farm yard; engineers and mechanics make
machinery with which to drive themselves and their fellow-workers from
remunerative employment; the miners bring up coal, which heats the
boilers of capitalists, while their own hearths are fireless; they delve
into the bowels of the earth for iron which they afterwards forge into
guns and cannons for their own destruction; and they toil beneath the
earth’s surface to bring up gold and silver, which they then convert
into coin to hamper their exchanges with their fellow-laborers, and to
make them poorer wherever it circulates. Notwithstanding all the giant
strides which are constantly being made in all the branches of invention
and industry, the worker’s condition only seems to get worse, and he
finds himself at the mercy of those who work not themselves but
accumulate the wealth of others. Oh! The glories of civilization!
Civilization is the dwelling together in society; and a civilization is
successful so far as it is associated with harmony. Civil warfare,
political intrigue, and internal strife of all kinds, are its
destruction. Mutual peace and individual prosperity mark its success.
Which course are we now pursuing?
Surely, if ever a people were well ruled, we of the present day may
claim to be so. Centuries ago, Aristotle is said to have perfected the
art of government, and we have been improving on him ever since, until
the individual has become almost forgotten and the State is supreme.
Whether it be a theocracy, autocracy, limited monarchy, or republic,
which keeps guard over our actions, we find in all alike the one common
political basis—the division of the people into the rulers and the
ruled. The government may differ in form, but they are alike in fact:
whatever they may be called, presidents are virtually kings,
plutocracies are intensified aristocracies, elections are conquests, and
elective rule is not better than hereditary rule. Whatever the form of
government, they are all marked by this ​general characteristic—they all
rest upon APPROPRIATION and EXPLOITATION.
Wherever the fiction of political property has been allowed to become
carried into practice, there slavery, in some form or other, is found to
underlie the social structure. It may be a primitive form of chattel
slavery, where the unfortunate toiler is bartered as so much merchandize
by those who have deprived him of his natural heritage in the world’s
wealth; or it may have developed into a form of feudalism, where he
becomes part of the soil he cultivates and is bought and sold along with
it by the baron who owns him; or it may have still further developed
into the modern system of landlordism, where the disinherited is free to
work for the proprietor, upon the latter’s terms, but with the only
alternative of starvation if he refuses. It is ever the same in effect;
those who have appropriated the world to which all are justly entitled,
hold in slavery the millions whom they have expropriated and live upon
the results of their toil. Mulhall[1] estimates that in the countries of
Europe, with the exception of some holding very small areas, only 6 in
every 100 of the population own the land in many instances; 14 in one
instance; 4 in every 100 in three cases; and in the United Kingdom, only
1 in every 200. In Australasia,[2] a similar monopoly of the land
prevails. Out of a population of three million people, there are 167,000
landowners and 19,011 squatters in possession of the land, of which
64,100,000 acres are held freehold, and 539,040,000 acres are used as
sheep runs, while the remaining 1,365,119,840 acres are held by the
respective governments, who keep them for the most part in idleness.
There is a situation for a newly-settled community to be placed in! Only
6% of the population owning land in Australasia; or 117 of the entire
population possessing â…“ of the entire soil! Of course, from such a tree,
we must expect unpleasant fruits. The many, who have not a share in this
monopoly must reward those who have, in order to obtain access to the
soil from which they must necessarily draw their subsistence. For the
privilege of being permitted to work, they pay to those who have stolen
their birthright a part of what they produce by their exertions, and it
is called rent. Rent is the amount paid by the laborer to the usurper
for the right to use the soil which he has appropriated. And the State
holds guard behind him, and with all the machinery of law, police, and
executive, compels him to render up the blackmail which the idle
proprietor extorts from him.
​Not only does the laborer find his efforts checked by the almost
unsurmountable monopoly which the creation of property has put in his
way but even when he has passed that barrier, when he has succeeded in
satisfying the demands of the proprietor, by agreeing to work for the
latter’s profit, he instantly confronts a new obstacle. He dare not
exchange his product with the product of another, without first paying
toll to privilege. There is only one medium of exchange which he is
permitted to use, and that is scarce and difficult of acquirement,
besides which he cannot borrow it without returning increase upon it as
recompense for its use. But as this monopolized money—this gold—has no
inherent power of increase, and he cannot return more of it than he has
borrowed, he is compelled to give up more of the products of his labor
to satisfy the demands of those who lend him the legalized means of
exchange. He may not know that a little bit of paper issued between
himself and those with whom he exchanges would answer all the
requirements of the case equally well, if not better, but those who rule
him know it also, and as it is their function to protect the interests
of property, and as property is the right to exploit labor, by the
creation of monopoly, so the ruler steps between them and enacts a bit
of human insolence called a law, which legalizes the monopolized means
of exchange and prohibits the recognition of a more just one, and thus
enables the monopolizers of the currency to extort an increase for a
loan of the money, which to the borrower is worse than useless, but
which he is compelled to employ. This increase for the use of money is
called interest, or more correctly, usury. Of course, those who own the
money, can buy the land; and those who own the land can often borrow the
money and pay the increase out of the proceeds of the laborer; while the
poor laborer himself, exploited by landlord and usurer, remains the
slave to both of them, and provides all the nourishment for them as well
as himself. The monetary possessions of Australasia are calculated to be
£19,000,000—£13,000,000 of which are in gold, £1,000,000 in silver, and
ÂŁ5,000,000 in paper. The total banking power is estimated at
£85,000,000. For the “use” of this, the bankers of Australasia draw
dividends averaging 12%; or, in other words, they fleece the public out
of about ÂŁ10,000,000 per annum. Not only are the usurers enabled to
extort increase upon the gold they put into circulation (and gold is the
only legal tender), but they are actually empowered to take interest
upon their paper issue, which is not money at all, but only a promise to
pay money—a printed acknowledgement of a debt! J. Sandlant[3] gives some
very instructive particulars on this point; “A banker is allowed by the
​State for a merely nominal consideration to issue two of paper to one of
bullion he may or is supposed to possess. On this principle, the six
different private banks in New Zealand, holding two millions of bullion,
could issue four millions of paper money... Now these four millions of
paper note issue become interest-bearing bonds to these banks directly
they are issued... Since then, by the act of issue, they become
interest-bearing bonds, let us see how they react upon society. When ÂŁ5%
is charged, a depression will occur about every ten or twelve years,
that is when worked in conjunction with profits arising from discount on
bills of recommendation, varying in the rate of time with the charge
made for discount. The Bank of England returns for 1847, 1857, and 1866,
convincingly prove the truth of this statement. These depressions were
by the unthinking attributed to the scarcity of money, but were not; in
reality depressions are the offspring of interest and the revertionary
powers of interest. So then the two millions of bullion held by the six
different Colonial Banks, by the addition of four millions of paper note
issue which the possession of this two millions of bullion empowers them
to employ, would, if fully used at 5%, give them a capital of eight
million in a little over fourteen years, and that without any of the
coin lying in the coffers of these banks; and this result is obtained
without taking into consideration or account the profits arising from
the discount on bills which could much more than pay the expense of
management.” That is the way the financiers amass their unearned
fortunes wherever the monopoly of money exists. They succeed in
demanding every year an ever-extending increase on the gold they lend
out, and the promises to pay the gold which they have not; and this, in
spite of the fact that the world’s gold supply is diminishing each year,
and is totally useless to measure the increasing commerce between the
nations. And the workers never cease toiling to satisfy the insatiable
demands of usury, and to pay the interest upon the millions they are
supposed to owe. Of course, the whole of this is paid for by the
laborers out of their own products. Not even do the capitalists pay any
portion of it, for they are only speculators interposing between the
usurer and the laborer and joining in the plunder of the latter. All the
interest which the capitalist is called upon to pay for the money
loaned, he first takes from those he employs or from those laborers who
purchase the product of his employees. Labor not only pays all rents,
but it pays all usury as well. Thus is the laborer bled. Monopoly first
checks production, and usury follows to check consumption.
It is labor alone which supplies all human wants. It has produced in the
past all the capital it now employs, and it is producing all the capital
​which will be employed in the future. Capital is ephemeral; but labor is
always creative. The total estimated wealth of Australasia, in 1882, was
ÂŁ590,000,000; and income was ÂŁ133,000,000, or nearly 1/4 of the capital.
In other words, the workers produced in one year a quarter of the wealth
that was around them. So that had it been possible for production to
cease, and for everything to be consumable, in 4 years, not a shred
would have been left to show that capital, or product, had ever existed.
It is the laborer alone who carries on civilization, satisfied all human
wants, and keeps the race alive.
And what about the capitalist—the good, kind, benevolent employer, to
whom the expropriated and exploited laborer goes hat in hand, cringing
for the privilege of being permitted to work? What is his place in our
social system? It is to extort another huge slice out of the worker, by
buying his services as much beneath their true value as he can possibly
procure them, and selling them as much above their worth as the
circumstances will permit him to extort. The more extensive his trade,
the greater will be his power over his employees. The wealth he has
accumulated from his laborers gives him the power to regulate commerce.
He can make trade dull or brisk as he desires. He has so much wealth
stored by him that he can rest on his oars when he wants to do so,
living on the reserves. This the laborer cannot do, for his earnings
have nearly all gone to others, and he only retains for himself enough
to sustain him for the day. If the capitalist wants to swell his
profits, he can form a ring with other capitalists and raise the prices
charged to consumers, or he can combine with them to make a corner on
the market by buying up an article of necessity and charging an
unusually exorbitant price for it. If the laborer wants to better his
condition under the existing conditions he cannot do it. His wages—that
is a small fraction of his product which is returned to him by his
so-called employer—are kept down to the lowest level on which he can
subsist, and he is worse off than a chattel slave. As John Adams said,
when drawing up the Constitution of the United States of America, “What
mattes whether you give the food and clothes to the slave direct, or
whether you just give him enough in wages to purchase the same?” The
laborer need not hope for a reasonable wage. The capitalist has but to
dismiss some of his hands, or fill their places with labor-saving
machinery which other laborers have invented and constructed, and those
thrown out of employment will immediately underbid those employed in
order to be reinstated. If the latter do not accede to a reduction of
wage, he will be dismissed to make room for the one who offers his
services cheaper. If the workers form a union, and strike for ​higher
wages, they cannot hold out as long as the capitalists to whom they have
given up nearly the whole of their product, but surrender as soon as
their idleness reduces them to poverty. Under the present system, where
the wage-receiver works for a profit-taker, he can never retain his
independence, or retain the fruits of his labor. If he is paid ÂŁ1 for
his work, and the product thereof is sold for ÂŁ5, he is unable to
re-purchase it, but must be content with a fifth part. The census of the
United States of America, for 1880,[4] shows that the daily average
product of each wage-worker in manufacturing industry was valued at $10,
while the daily average wage he received was but $1.15. That is not
one-eighth of his earnings. And that is the very home of industrialism.
It is probably a shade better elsewhere, but only a shade. The available
statistics do not show the Australian laborer’s position in this dismal
picture; but it may be safely concluded that his condition is not much
better than that of his American comrade, for his is a profitable field
for commercial speculation; and, of course, where the speculator’s
profits are large, the laborer’s losses must be large in the exact
proportion. The annual commerce of Australasia is ÂŁ90,000,000; the gross
earnings of labor in 1882, were ÂŁ133,000,000. Let us try to make an
approximate estimate of how those earnings are spent. The laborers paid
in that year for taxation, ÂŁ15,000,000;[5] the rent they paid to the
land monopolists, estimated at say 10% on the value of estates, amounted
to ÂŁ19,000,000; the interest they paid to financiers for hampering their
exchanges was ÂŁ10,000,000; and business profits, calculated at 75%[6] on
the merchantable commodities, were ÂŁ67,000,000. This will leave the
remuneration to the laborers at ÂŁ22,000,000, or about 1/6 of their
product, which is probably a fair estimate. The following will
accordingly represent, as nearly as possible, a statement of
How the Australasian Laborers Spend Annual Earnings.
Taxes - ÂŁ15,000,000
Rent @ 10% on estates’ value (£190,000,000) - 19000000
Interest @ over 12% - 10000000
Profits @ 75% on merchantable commodities - 67000000
Remuneration to labor - 22000000
———————
Total earnings of Labor - ÂŁ133,000,000
​Henry Thoreau has splendidly shown by his own experience how prolific
are the rewards of labor, and in what ease, comfort, and luxury, the
worker may live where his fellow does not prey upon him. Living as he
did in the woods, almost isolated from his fellows, deprived of the
advantages which contact with them and their products would bring him,
and at the mercy of wild creatures who constantly destroyed his crops,
he enjoyed a life such as not one in a thousand of the city laborers has
any taste of, and was never troubled with the demon of Want. “For more
than five years,” he wrote, “I maintained myself thus solely by the
labor of my hands; and I found that by working about six weeks in a year
I could meet all the expenses of living.” If this solitary individual
could produce so much with so little labor living under conditions of
relative freedom, how much more could these poor city wage-slaves
produce by their united efforts, assisted by the wonderful industrial
appliances of civilised life, were they also free to produce their own
necessities without having to bear the yoke of legalized robbery?
But have we not a government to protect us? some will ask. Yes: and you
have seen how it protects you from the aggressions of others, by making
you subservient to the landlord and the usurer from whom you are unable
to extricate yourselves. But, alas, that is not all. Government not only
fails to protect you against the ravages of others, but it does not
protect you against the ravages of itself. It taxes you at every turn;
and dearly do you have to pay for its services—always paying more than
its worth for what you need, or else paying for what you do not need.
And the whole taxation is paid by the laborer, as we have already seen,
out of his own products. No one else pays any taxes. If a merchant pays
a tax, he charges it to his customer, who may be a laborer, or who, if
he is not, will charge it to the laborer he employs. Government grants
you “protection,” does it? Yes, it erects a custom-house barrier at your
boundaries to protect the local capitalist, who employs you, from the
competition of the capitalist afar off, as it would tend to reduce the
price which the local capitalist charges for the goods you re-purchase
of him. The tariff your Government collects is charged for the buyer,
plus the usual profits, and labor again pays the whole bill. Perhaps you
may boast of the glorious “free trade” which your Government bestows
upon you. Poor deluded creatures! how do you expect to trade freely,
when you own nothing to trade with, when the land on which you work
belongs to others, when the tools and machinery you employ are theirs,
your exchanges are hampered by a monopolized money system, you are bled
by interest, and capitalistic monopolists form rings to defeat and rob
you and eternally extort ​profit out of your labors? Free trade, indeed?
No: there is no Government which affords Protection to labor, or allows
it facilities to enjoy Free Trade; they all exist to enforce the very
reverse of these things, by fostering Monopoly and Exploitation. The
Australasian Governments tax an annual revenue of ÂŁ15,000,000 from the
working people of these colonies, and expend ÂŁ20,000,000 in the same
time, leaving the laborers a deficit of ÂŁ5,000,000 to be met with loans
payable with interest. The expenditure in 53 years (1830-82) was
ÂŁ420,000,000, and the revenue collected only ÂŁ315,000,000, leaving labor
indebted for the sum of ÂŁ105,000,000, owing for nothing at all. All
public debts are fictitious obligations which are owed by labor to
idleness. The National Debt of Australasia in 1882, was
£97,000,000,—equal to £34 per inhabitant owing to the usurers for no
services rendered. It was also equal to 16% of the total wealth of the
colonies, and paid interest at the rate of 4 7/10 % or 3 1/2% of the
total income. All these so-called “debts,” and all the loans we receive
from the usurers, may be demanded in gold when the time comes for their
repayment; but of course the demand could never be met: the National
Debt alone is more than seven times the amount of gold we possess. So
the only way these bogus debts can be met is by borrowing fresh loans to
pay them with; and these, of course, bear interest and grow
eternally,—while the bankers live in idleness and affluence on the
products which they filch from labor in the name of interest.
The worker’s indebtedness to the idler is getting worse and worse as
time goes on. England’s experience in the last half-century shows what
will be the certain fate of the civilized world if some remarkable
change does not take place in the nature of our social system. There the
worker’s lot has steadily got worse. Between 1837 and 1887, the
population of the United Kingdom increased 42%, and had other things
remain relatively equal they would have shown a like increase. But such
was not the case. While the increase in population during the
half-century[7] was but 42%, the revenue had increased 73%; or in other
words, the worker’s burden of taxation had become 31% harder to bear.
And yet the country as a whole had become proportionally 82% wealthier.
But it need not be wondered at that the laborer’s condition did not
advance, considering that the trade, resting as it did on
profit-plundering, had grown to be 430% more extensive (still allowing
for the increased trade due to increased population); and the banking
transactions, which all the time were plundering the laborers, had made
an advance of 530% in excess of the advance of population! Everything in
the way of labor’s exploitation had advanced with ​prodigious strides.
But the lot of the laborer had become worse. The worker’s earnings,
since 1840, had only increased 25%, while the rents alone had increased
150%. Add to that the losses enumerated above, and then say whether such
“national progress” is progress on the part of the producer or of the
thief.
What the world’s money may amount to, and how it is distributed, can
never be accurately known; but it is a certainty that it is steadily
becoming concentrated into fewer hands. It has been estimated that
twenty millionaires (out of a population of nearly 600,000,000), alone
own wealth amounting to ÂŁ145,000,000 (many authorities say much more);
and the world’s coinage is said to be £1,190,000,000, and its total
money, ÂŁ1,946,000,000. If such is the case, it follows that 1/30,000,000
of the world’s population own wealth equal in value to 1/8 of its
coinage, or 1/14 of its money. However that may be, these facts are
certain: the world’s wealth is concentrating in fewer hands;
millionaires and paupers are both on the increase; trade is increasingly
dull, and employment becoming more scarce; employers are sending the
workers adrift to starve; insolvencies are increasing, and the big
capitalists are swallowing up the little ones; the Governments of the
world are at the beck of its plutocrats; life is getting intolerable to
the many and precarious to the few; homes are unhappy and woman and man
alike wretched; discontent is everywhere, and even the most comfortable
are beginning to ask whether life is worth living, and whether slavery,
dependence, marriage, and the other institutions of our civilization are
not failures after all.
That the present social system has failed must be apparent to all who
have studied it. It has rendered the many subservient to the few; it has
checked the best human endeavours, and facilitated every method of
exploitation; it disinherits the great mass, and foreordains their
lifelong misery before they are even born; it makes one man dependent
upon another’s caprice, instead of making him dependent on his own
energies; it is a premium to idleness, and an incentive to plunder; it
is responsible for the bad morals of the many, who are the creatures of
the vile surroundings in which it has placed them; it unites the sexes
when the requirements of nature would set them apart, and keeps them
apart when the healthiest impulses of their nature would have them
together; it creates jealousies, hatreds, and mutual injustice. All our
political institutions are destructive and reactionary; the opportunity
to control the actions of one’s fellow, which lies at the base of every
governmental system, tends surely and certainly to make those in power
self-seeking, dishonest, and tyrannical, and ever ready to dominate and
oppress those over whom they exert ​authority; and not only does it
corrupt those who rule it, but its evil effects extend to those whom
they govern, for every extension of governmental function assists in
decreasing and dwarfing the energies and self-reliance of the people
themselves and making them more helpless, cowardly, and servile than
before. Our social system, by its politically-fostered monopolies, is
continually driving men to poverty, intemperance, and debauchery, and
driving women to prostitution or the slavery of unhappy marriage; its
exploitations render the parents so poor, and their struggles for
existence so keen and uncertain, that they have neither the wealth,
time, inclination nor ability, to properly clothe, feed, educate, and
make moral their children, but allow them to grow up a criminal and
vicious generation, and one too well qualified to perpetuate the present
evils.
No political machinery can destroy the evils which the political
machinery has brought into being; for it is the nature of ruling
institutions to conserve the bad, to support and extend conventional and
reactionary opinion, and to check all progressive thought in religion,
sociology and philosophy. Laws are made to be obeyed—not to be repealed
for the public good. They are essentially conservative of privilege. All
law is made to protect property and proprietors alone. There is no law
for the poor. Legal victory is a luxury which it requires money to
purchase. If you have no money, you cannot go to law; or if you manage
to, you may safely reckon on coming out on the wrong side of the ledger.
The justice of a thing has little to do with a legal decision—that
decision has previously been inscribed on the Statute Books on the basis
of property and its right of exploitation. Plutocracy rules the world.
The existing evils of society are too gigantic to toy with. It is
useless to appeal to an extension of suffrage, when the suffrage can
offer nothing more than a choice of masters elected to carry on a system
of destruction. It is equally useless to pin your hopes on fine-spun
theories of the taxation of land-values, when those values exist only in
the imagination and all taxes are paid in the products of labor. It is
useless to preach thrift to those who have nothing to save, or to hope
for universal prosperity when the enrichment of the few is caused by the
plunder of the many. Again is it foolish to imagine that a general
patronage of savings banks, building societies, sharebroking
institutions, and the like, will ever tend to ameliorate social wrongs;
for their gains always implies someone else’s loss. Speculations in
investments in stocks, shares, railway, mining and other companies, are
all speculations on the possible future of losses of labor. Dividends do
not create themselves—they are all filched from labor. If the laborers
ceased to be plundered, there will be no dividends. These “remedies” are
no remedies at all.
​The present system cannot hold for ever. Every day sees its power
waning. It is the self-interest of everyone who hopes for the dawn of a
brighter day to assist in dispelling the darkness which overhands and
threatens to engulph us, and to work together to substitute in its place
a system that shall be more just, more merciful, more equitable, more
harmonious. The slavery of the workers by the politically-created and
politically-fostered monopoly of property, and the robbery of the
laborers by rent, interest, profit, and taxation, must be
abolished—abolished peacefully, expeditiously, and permanently. And to
do so, we must start from where we now stand, and despite all the
disadvantages which surround us, and with all the ignorance, all the
bigotry, all the intolerance, and all the debasement and cowardice which
characterize the down-trodden millions, we must side by side make our
way along the path which so many have found slippery, until we reach the
long-cherished goal of Labor’s Emancipation.
But how can we do it? How can we get from the present unjust,
destructive system, into one in which justice and happiness shall be the
distinguishing characteristics? How shall we fight out of the present
blood-thirsty system without the shedding of blood and without the
disastrous reaction which has marked the bloody rebellions of the past?
How shall we walk from bondage into liberty?
That is the problem which awaits our immediate solution. We cannot avoid
it: we must face it. We dare not ignore it, for the present system is
destroying us. We, slaves as we are, have to emancipate ourselves. It
can be done. It must be done. It shall be done. But how?
[1] Mulhall's Dictionary of Statistics, 1886, p. 267.
[2] These figures and a number that follow are taken from Hayter’s
Victorian Year Book, 1886-7.
[3] State Banks, by J. Sandlant Gisborne (N.Z.) 1886.
[4] Quoted in Parson’s Anarchism: its Philosophy and Scientific Basis,
p. 17.
[5] This is Mulhall’s computation. Hayter makes it nearly £22,000,000.
[6] Whether this estimate is an accurate one, the merchants and
speculators themselves will know best; however, without more accurate
data, it is safe, I think, to say that a paying business usually “turns
over” its stock in three to four months, and brings in an average of
something like 25%. I have heard a successful tradesman assert that his
stock doubled itself in twelve months, and I know that his calculation
could not have been far out of the truth.
[7] See Mulhall’s Fifty Years’ National Progress.