đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș daniil-dugum-anarchism-russian-style.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 09:01:32. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-06-20)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Anarchism, Russian-style Author: Daniil Dugum Date: 19 June 2015 Language: en Topics: money, counter-economics, Russia Source: Retrieved on 23rd January 2022 from https://www.opendemocracy.net/en/odr/anarchism-russianstyle/ Notes: The village of Kolionovo has a reputation for independent mindedness and upsetting the authorities. Now theyâve created their own currency â the koliony.
The story of Russian farmer Mikhail Shlyapnikov and his âself-madeâ
money has become something of a sensation of late, and has long
travelled beyond the confines of Kolionovo, the village where he lives.
The Moscow Prosecutorâs Office is now investigating Shlyapnikovâs
currency (named koliony after his village) and its creator on suspicion
of infringing the stateâs monopoly on issuing currency.
A remote and tiny village, Kolionovo lies at the end of a small road
just off a highway leading west out of the Russian capital. And
Kolionovo would have remained remote, tiny and unknown, if it wasnât for
the periodic scandal about how the villageâs elderly residents have
chased the local administration out of town, the campaign to save the
village hospital, the self-organised firefighting service or the ban on
public officials entering the village without a document testifying to
their mental health and a recent fluorography test for tuberculosis. But
now the residents of Kolionovo have devised their own currency and, in
doing so, have written themselves into a wider history â a history of
alternative currency and anarchism.
With the dubious honour of being Russiaâs leading anarchist farmer,
Mikhail Shlyapnikov was a successful entrepreneur before he moved to
Kolionovo.
After a series of unsuccessful operations for cancer in 2004, however,
doctors told Shlyapnikov he had three months to live. And Shlyapnikov
decided that, if he were going to die, heâd die in the countryside.
This existential downshifting did not help Shlyapnikov find peace.
Instead, the move to Kolionovo prompted Shlyapnikov to become something
of a rebel. This kind of story usually takes place in reverse: a former
activist, having come of age (and to his or her senses), moves to the
countryside in order to escape the madness of city life. After living
for a while in Kolionovo, though, Shlyapnikov began to invest his
entrepreneurial talents in what he understands by anarchism.
The move to Kolionovo prompted Shlyapnikov to become something of a
rebel.
For instance, take Kolionovoâs sapling nursery, a form of ecological
activism and business vital to the health of the Moscow region: the
forests here suffered huge fires in 2010 and after; and have been
punished by an epidemic of insects, which feed on tree bark.
But now Shlyapnikov and his comrades have gone too far (for the
authorities that is): they have started issuing their own promissory
notes; 20,000 of them. And with his charisma and popularity, Shlyapnikov
couldnât help but provoke the powers that be.
After all, the question on everybodyâs lips â in the break room at work,
hanging out with friends or chatting on the internet â is the exchange
rate. So one can understand the Russian stateâs concern for its currency
monopoly, as well as the press and public reaction to the koliony.
Minimise interactions with the state, develop mutually beneficial
relationships and good old-fashioned altruism (helping the less
well-off, orphans): this is anarchism, Kolionovo-style. This is not
total anarchy, however: Shlyapnikov is still paying his workers in
roubles, and paying employer taxes.
Weâre used to measuring so much in terms of money, itâs hard to think of
life without it.
But there are a large variety of currency systems, which depart from the
fiat system (that is, money issued by the government): time banks,
crypto-currencies (bitcoins being the most famous), local currencies and
currencies with âreturn percentageâ or planned inflation, goods-exchange
communities such as LETS (local exchange trading system) and internet
exchange communities.
The range of different forms of economic relations is striking.
According to Maxim Mitusov, an economist who specialises in local
currencies, there are more than 4,000 local economic systems in the
world.
In essence, any group, which is united by common interests and mutual
trust can create its own money or its own non-monetary system of
exchange with only a few simple skills. Itâs a question of how united
the group is â thatâs the deciding factor.
Itâs a question of how united the group is â thatâs the deciding factor.
Early societies did not suffer from the absence of money at all: they
simply werenât aware of it. Evidence for this can be found in numerous
observations made by ethnographers and social anthropologists.
First of all, primitive societies originally found and consumed all
goods together, collectively. Second, most primitive forms of ethics
were based on mutual assistance: you simply couldnât survive without it.
This kind of ethics excludes any form of selfishness, the desire for
profit â even the very idea of debt.
Self-organised economic activity rises to the fore when fiat currencies
begin to decline. During the 1990s, many Russians working in factories
remember being paid in the goods they produced themselves, or the goods
they were traded for. (Army families can recall how entire garrisons
were paid in groceries.) The money just wasnât there, but goods were
aplenty.
For people living in the Russian countryside, barter is still an
important mechanism in interpersonal relationships. Financial flows
simply canât penetrate this far, and remain in the metropole â in banks,
the cycle of urban consumption, in offshore accounts, and in
bureaucratic and criminal structures.
Crises are often accompanied by attempts to create money without the
involvement of the state. The crisis, which hit Argentina in 1998, for
instance, provoked an unprecedented level of cooperative activity.
Cast out from the closed factories and rented flats, ArgentinĐ” citizens
watched with hungry eyes how trains and trucks carried off basic items â
items which they needed â in order to pay off the stateâs foreign debt.
At that moment, millions of people without jobs realised that the only
things you can rely on in life are your own energies, skills, and other
people.
Looking at photographs from that time, you can see, not only people
holding stolen goods, molotov cocktails, sticks and stones, banners, but
brightly coloured bits of paper too â money theyâd made themselves, the
credito. With the help of this âmoneyâ, members of a rebellious and
self-organised community were able to pay one another and exchange
goods.
Or the example of Michael Unterguggenberger, mayor of the Austrian town
of Wörgl, who issued his own Wörgler Freigeld to save the town from
bankruptcy and build a series of public projects over a 13-month period
during the Great Depression. After a few years, though, when dozens of
other Austrian communities had become jealous of their neighbourâs
success and decided to replicate the idea, the national bank banned the
Freigeld, frightened by the threat to its monopoly.
Likewise, the Bashkirian sovkhoz (state farm) of Shaimuratova responded
to the financial crisis of 2008 by issuing its own currency â
shaimuratiki. According to the projectâs initiator, economist Rustam
Davletbaev, local currencies can channel unexpressed âdemandâ (usually
ignored by the market) in the sense that it allows people who want to
buy goods (but have no money) to use their own goods or skills in a
local system of exchange.
Unfortunately, though, while everyone in Shaimuratovo liked the idea,
the local Prosecutorâs Office didnât. The fight for shaimuratiki
continues, only now at various courts.
What is the secret of these and hundreds of other currencies just like
them? What makes them workable, and how do they affect the economy?
On the one hand, alternative currencies are more than just money: they
connect peopleâs real interests to their capabilities and the products
of their labour. As a rule, these kinds of currencies are not part of
the system of financial speculation, nor are they linked to the price of
hydrocarbons.
On the other, the cost of devaluation (demurrage) of alternative
currency means that accumulating this money is less than profitable. Yet
circulation of these currencies is increasing, and is leading to the
development of local infrastructure.
If alternative currencies are so useful, why is the state afraid of
them?
âPray God, your voice, like a piece of uncurrent gold, be not cracked
within the ring.â So speaks Hamlet in an elegant reference to the death
of the king, the father of the Danish prince, and whose face was
depicted on the âpiece of uncurrent goldâ.
Shakespeareâs metaphor exposes one of moneyâs most important
characteristics: while the fact that monarchs impress themselves on
every unit of currency may seem an act of vanity, the face of the
sovereign means that the value of this unit is guaranteed by the state.
For instance, the anthropologist Keith Hart writes: âLook at a coin from
your pocket. On one side is âheadsâ â the symbol of the political
authority, which minted the coin; on the other side is âtailsâ â the
precise specification of the amount the coin is worth as payment in
exchange. One side reminds us that states underwrite currencies and the
money is originally a relation between persons in society, a token
perhaps. The other reveals the coin as a thing, capable of entering into
definite relations with other things.â
The nominal value of every coin often did not correspond to the value of
the metal (gold, silver or bronze) used to make it. In Information, Work
and Value, Paul Cockshott goes back to the very first currency made in
the Kingdom of Lydia (coined from a mixture of gold and silver). Diluted
with silver, these seventh century coins were worth more than the gold
contained within them, and were, as such, very expensive coins. With a
single Lydian stater, you could satisfy your basic needs for a month.
Cockshott comes to the conclusion that ancient kings tried to avoid
deceiving their subjects, and both introduced and set the value of their
currency specifically to simplify the collection of taxes: âIf the Crown
imposes on its citizens a duty to pay tax in coin of the realm, then
these citizens must either work directly for the state â building roads,
acting as soldiers etc, or, they must produce commodities to sell to
those who do serve in the army, build roads etc. In this conception, it
is the coercive power of the state that accelerates the penetration
commodity production into the social organism.â
Today, it is the currencies of the worldâs most powerful states, which
are the most respected. (In this sense, the Eurozone is like an empire
created and managed by the unity of economic interests.) And today, the
stateâs main concern in the financial sphere is to preserve its status,
its monopoly on issuing money.
The stateâs main concern in the financial sphere is to preserve its
status, its monopoly on issuing money.
As Mikhail Shlyapnikov has argued in court and out (he has his own
LiveJournal account): âKoliony arenât even money, theyâre just IOUs.â In
this sense, this farmer-cum-anarchist from outside Moscow has not come
up with anything new.
In Debt: The first 5,000 years, David Graeber writes: âThere is an
unresolved debate between those who see money as a commodity and those
who see it as an IOU. Which one is it? By now, the answer should be
obvious: itâs both.â
Graeber uses numerous examples to illustrate how traders and artisans in
the past issued their own money made from iron, wood and leather. This
kind of money circulated in a community of business partners, among
consumers of the same institutions, stalls and studios. And as we face a
fresh economic crisis, small business owners have returned to these
practices.
This development is neither surprising, nor revolutionary. Small
business is creating currency in its own image â and now you can travel
down the âgoods-money-goodsâ trail without the involvement or management
of the central bank. Big capital expresses itself through fiat
currencies and comes alive in global currencies â even abstract ones
like electronic currencies.
But IOUs are goods like any other, and the exchange of goods is, in
turn, a mutual obligation. According to Graeber, economics is, in fact,
the material expression of ethics, and the market economy is a
reflection of the ethics of debt. But where is the border that separates
âmutual obligationsâ from the cut-throat world of financial monopolies?
It was the German economist Silvio Gesell who first detailed both the
useful and harmful aspects of money at the end of the 19^(th) century.
Indeed, it was Gesellâs concept of âfreeâ money, which inspired the
experiments in Wörgl and Shaimuratovo.
For Gesell, money can help people find a common economic language, to
recognise peopleâs contributions to society. But money also breeds a
tendency to accumulation, which creates hierarchies, competition, crises
and armed conflict. Gesell saw the basis of prosperity and justice in
making accumulation unprofitable and, on a conceptual level at least,
tried to think about money as an item of exchange like any other.
But we have to make sure that goods and money correspond in terms of
value, and all goods have an expiry date. So why shouldnât money?
Demurrage is precisely that: the ageing of money.
The Belgian economist Bernard Lietaer classified the worldâs currencies
in terms of Yin and Yang. Yang currencies are the fiat currencies we
know (and love) â units of value issued by the state. They are
convenient for international exchange (if the issuing state is
sufficiently powerful). They are capable of gathering societyâs
resources for large projects and quick mobilisation. But they also form
the basis of hierarchy, power and competition.
By contrast, Yin currencies stimulate the circulation of locally
produced goods and services, transforming the whole landscape of a
community through constant circulation.
Lietaer says directly that the more patriarchal a society is, the less
perfect the financial system it creates. The men standing at the top of
the patriarchal hierarchy do not allow âcurrency pluralismâ because it
erodes centralised control (hence the concern in the Moscow and
Bashkirian Prosecutorâs Offices).
Those ancient societies, which respected womenâs reproductive labour,
which idealised it and connected it to fertility cults â these societies
were more ready for cooperation. For Lietaer, this is the source of
currency pluralism:
âThe stronger the king, the larger the kingdom, and the less practical
it becomes to keep the demurrage system going. This happens in parallel
with a growing political necessity for a repression of women as well.
The stronger the patriarchal impulse, the more it may appear necessary
to give to each man the feeling of being âking in his own householdâ.â
While patriarchal societies favour strong single currencies, matriarchal
societies opt for dual currency systems â one currency for long-distance
trade, and another for local exchange.
While patriarchal societies favour strong single currencies, matriarchal
societies opt for dual currency systems
Mikhail Shlyapnikov and his koliony still have a long way to go before
they make it into the history books. The humble kolion is, after all,
not subject to demurrage. But the connection between this farmer and the
land around him makes him a part of a larger financial history of
alternative currencies.
The kolion is the strongest currency: its exchange rate is unchangeable
and fixed to eggs, geese and other goods produced by Shlyapnikov. Oil
prices and the rouble exchange rate can affect the kolion indirectly via
the prosperity of the participants of exchange. But there is no direct
link. And the significance of koliony lies in creating autonomy from the
harmful system of speculation.
As Rustam Davletbaev, the creator of shaimuratiki, writes: âKoliony have
exposed a very serious problem â the absence of responsibility of
economic institutions of the state â the Central Bank, Ministry of
Finance and the Ministry of Economic Development when it comes to the
periodic economic and financial crises faced by Russia, and their
consequences.â
To put it simply: if the Central Bank is responsible for economic
growth, then why does it shrug off negative currency fluctuation,
aspects of crisis and a fall in GDP so easily? Why does no one take
responsibility for the fall in citizensâ living standards? Why do these
structures fail to provide the conditions necessary for our citizens to
implement their rights to life and work? Perhaps itâs time to change
something?â
The pathos of that âitâs time to changeâ should give us reason for
optimism. Just like Shlyapnikov, Davletbaev understands all too well the
indifference of those âresponsibleâ for the state of affairs in a remote
village.
If one looks at the Russian economy today through the eyes of Silvio
Gesell, there is nothing sadder than the total control of people who
receive profits from rents rather than labour and real exchange.
This is why we should give the creators of the koliony and shaimuratiki
their due, and those who try to spread the seeds of cooperation and
economic alternatives on (otherwise infertile) Russian soil.