💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › sidewinder-what-is-orthodoxy.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 14:11:55. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: What is Orthodoxy?
Author: Sidewinder
Date: 2009
Language: en
Topics: Anton Pannekoek, economism, false consciousness, Lenin, Marxism, Rosa Luxemburg, scientism
Source: Retrieved 11/10/2021 from https://web.archive.org/web/20170713122231/http://anarchism.pageabode.com/sidewinder/what-orthodox-marxism

Sidewinder

What is Orthodoxy?

A spectre is haunting the Left, the spectre of orthodox Marxism. In

order to fully exorcise this pernicious spirit it is necessary to first

understand it's true nature. The orthodox interpretation of Marxism

arose after Marx's death through the work of Engels and the founders of

the German Social Democratic Party (SPD), most significantly, Karl

Kautsky

Kautsky eventually became the undisputed "Pope" of the orthodox

interpretation of Marxism within the SPD, after the excommunication of

the reformist heresy of Eduard Bernstein. Orthodoxy (literally: right

thinking) discovers its formulations through the process of opposing the

first heresy that threatens its continued existence. By this process,

orthodoxy to a degree preserves, like the negative image of a key

pressed into wax, the imprint of the heresy or heresies it originally

defined itself against, long after those heresies have passed out of

existence and been forgotten. Often then, the deconstruction of an

orthodoxy most fruitfully begins with the study of the heresy it

suppressed. However, for the purposes of brevity, we will skip the

examination of Bernstein's revisionism and move directly to outlining

the core framework of orthodoxy itself.

Reduced to its most basic framework, we can characterise orthodoxy as

having three core pillars and a fourth, compensatory element. The three

core pillars remain relatively constant in all the different branchings

off the orthodox tree, but the fourth compensatory element changes and,

as such, constitutes the main difference between the different branches.

If we use the metaphor of a restaurant table on an uneven dining

terrace, the fourth element is the folded beermat that is placed

underneath the shortest leg to bridge the gap and damp down the

instability of the rocking table. Of course, if a table has only three

legs, this problem does not arise, similarly, the three core theoretical

pillars of orthodoxy are made unstable by the fourth leg of the table -

the contingent reality of the situation of the day, resting on the

uneven rocky terrace of history.

The three core pillars are 1) Economism, 2) Scientism and 3) False

consciousness.

Economism or economic determinism is a hard version of the

base/superstructure interpretation of Marxism, that is, this (in)famous

passage from The Poverty of Philosophy -

"Social relations are closely bound up with productive forces. In

acquiring new productive forces men change their mode of production; and

in changing their mode of production, in changing the way of earning

their living, they change all their social relations. The hand-mill

gives you society with the feudal lord; the steam-mill, society with the

industrial capitalist."

Is read as meaning "social relations are determined by productive

forces"[1]. This notion that social relations in general and the

relations of production in particular, are determined by the forces of

production, can lead in the extreme case, to technological determinism.

That is, that technological advance revolutionises the forces of

production, which in turn revolutionises society. This kind of thinking

is more widespread than Marxism or the Left, and has persistent appeal

amongst the skilled scientific, technical and engineering strata of

capitalist society. Witness the number of plant biologists who still

seem to think that one more increase in crop yields will banish world

hunger and poverty, or the "net nerd" enthusiasts who believe that the

internet is going to magic humanity into a new age of digital freedom.

It is also the root of a peculiar blindness which leads the sufferer to

miss the fact that technology is neither politically or socially

neutral, but determined by the struggles and contradictions of our

society.

Scientism is the unshakeable conviction that Marxism is more than a

theory, it is a science of society and the "laws of motion" of

capitalist society, in an analogous fashion to engineering science being

the science of engines and the laws of motion that govern them. The most

obvious thing that must be pointed out about this deeply held conviction

that Marxism is a science, is that it is deeply unscientific. Popper's

criticism of orthodox Marxism that it's belief system had more in common

with a religion than a science, is not entirely without merit. The other

aspect of Marxism as the science of the laws of motion of capitalist

society including its inner contradictions, especially the so-called

"Law of the Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall", combined with

economism, leads to historicism. Historicism is the idea that there is a

direction to history, that society is progressing towards a particular

goal. It was a common idea in the 19th century, linked to ideas of big-P

Progress, going back to the Enlightenment. It was also part of the

teleological (tr: goal-directed) schema of Hegel, Marx's philosophical

mentor. However, Kropotkin is another example of how hard old

revolutionaries find it to resist the temptations of the "scientific

inevitability" of the triumph of the revolution, even without a

background in German Idealist philosophy. Historicism and a belief in

the "objective" economic laws of development, tend to lead to the

downplaying of class struggle as an active force in making history. At

first sight, this may seem a surprising feature of any kind of Marxism,

given that "all history is the history of class struggle" is one of

Marx's more well-known quotes[2], but it is a definite tendency of

orthodox Marxism.

The third pillar of orthodoxy is the notion of false consciousness.

Again for the sake of brevity, we will skirt around a full treatment of

Marx's notion of ideology and class consciousness, save in noting that

he made a distinction between class in itself (an sich) and class for

itself (für sich), the latter concept being that of a body of people

united by a conscious recognition of their common interests as a class

and their common interest in overcoming capitalist relations. It was

also clear that the class consciousness associated with class for itself

was a precursor for revolution. Combined with historicist notions that

the "objective laws" of capitalist development are headed inevitably

towards revolution and is building it's own grave diggers in the

proletariat, the lack of such a wide-spread, consistent revolutionary

class consciousness amongst actual workers of the day creates a problem.

This is a classic is/ought question. Why does the consciousness the

workers ought to have differ so much from the one they actually do have?

False consciousness is the solution to this problem. The workers

development of the scientifically-determined "proper" consciousness is

being blocked by an obstacle - a false consciousness that is taking up

the room that the correct consciousness should be developing within. Of

course this solution is itself a riddle - what are the origins of this

usurping false consciousness and how is the correct consciousness to be

restored to its rightful place?

Thus the three core pillars of orthodoxy, destabilised by an

inconvenient reality, require a fourth, bridging element - a fix to the

false consciousness riddle, to bridge the gap between what is and what

ought to be.

In the SPD of Kautsky, the solution to the riddle of false consciousness

was found in a reading of Marx on ideology and the famous fetishism of

commodities, that inferred that the social relations of market exchange

in capitalism separated the sphere of production from the sphere of

exchange, thus hiding the reality of social production beneath the

appearance of private economic intercourse, mystifying the overall

social reality from the ordinary worker, re-invented as consumer. In

Kautsky's view, only bourgeois specialists with the education and time

to study the new social science of Marxism could bring the proper

consciousness back to the workers, from the outside as it were. The mass

membership parliamentary party was the proper pedagogic vehicle for

"scientific" specialists, such as himself, to school the workers in the

correct way of viewing the world and developing their capabilities while

waiting patiently for "the objective conditions to be ripe" for the

glorious day. In the meantime the worker should dutifully pay party and

union subs, study hard, support the party's social clubs, vote for the

party at the elections and, above all, not do anything rash until their

leaders told them the time was right and what their new orders were.

Already within German socialdemocracy there were some dissenting voices

who, while rejecting the Bernsteinian revisionist heresies, were growing

less convinced that this strategy of "actionless waiting" was the

correct response to the requirements of the political struggles of the

day. Let's focus on the two most well-known - Rosa Luxemburg and Antonie

Pannekoek (who was the originator of the "actionless waiting" tag for

the Kautsky strategy). Both of their challenges were prompted by the

upsurge of syndicalist unrest that followed the Ruhr Miners strike and

Russian Revolution of 1905, the Charter of Amiens in France and so on.

Above all, how to react to the popular syndicalist slogan of the General

Strike (or Massenstreik as it was termed in German). The divisions that

emerged from the debate that raged over the Massenstreik within the SPD

in 1906 were later deepened by the European crisis that culminated in

WW1.

The spectre of a spontaneous working class uprising naturally fills the

bourgeoisie with existential terror. Good bourgeois that he was, Kautsky

had a visceral horror of working class spontaneity. Consequently he was

violently opposed to the idea of the General Strike, particularly as the

onset of a proletarian uprising and revolution.

Luxemburg had a more instinctive impulse to move part-way towards

granting the working class some spontaneous agency, albeit one that

would still be ultimately reliant on the leadership of the Marxist party

in order to finish the job worker's spontaneous action had started. But,

in face of the rising inter-imperialist European crisis, Luxemburg was

led to re-examine Marx's work on accumulation and reproduction of

capital and actually revise it in order to come up with a theory of

Imperialism. To this degree, Luxemburg not only questioned the

parliamentarism and anti-spontaneism of Kautskyite orthodoxy, but

actually had the temerity to begin undermining the core orthodox

principal of Marxism as an infallible and complete "science". Despite

the undoubted nerve it took to take this step (particularly as a woman

in a thoroughly unreconstructed male-dominated movement), Luxemburg did

not stretch to breaking with the SPD until she was forced out, the

attempts to take the initiative in the chaos of defeat, revolution and

counter-revolution, were too little and too late. Despite her initial

critical noises about the direction Lenin and the Bolsheviks were

taking, she did not have enough time to establish a branching of

orthodoxy distinct from Leninism or Kautskyism. Her legacy is also

compromised by the opinion of many non-orthodox theorists that her

unique theoretical contribution to Marxism - The Accumulation of

Capital, is based on an underconsumptionist argument that is basically

wrong.

Antonie Pannekoek, however, went further than Luxemburg in breaking from

Kautskyism. Not only did he support spontaneous workers actions such as

wildcat strikes and the general strike, but he grew increasingly

critical of the role of the SPD in opposing and putting down worker's

strikes. Eventually this lead him to see the SPD and their tame unions,

as being a barrier to class self-activity and hence their development of

revolutionary class consciousness. In Pannekoek and his fellow Council

Communists, the Kautskyist answer to the riddle of false consciousness

is inverted. Here it is the outside bourgeois "revolutionary

specialists" who are the source, not of the correct consciousness, but

the false consciousness. The solution to the problem of false

consciousness then, the fourth element, is the politically independant,

rank and file controlled worker's organisations aiming to build worker's

councils - the bodies that will be the new agency of class power and the

transformation of society. Of course this is in radical opposition to

both Kautskyite orthodox socialdemocracy and it' Leninist offshoot both,

but it still retains the three basic pillars of orthodoxy - economism,

scientism and false consciousness - only the fourth, bridging element

has changed. The mass parliamentary party has been replaced by the rank

and file workers networks and the workers councils.

The case of Lenin is probably more familiar to readers than the others,

and has been dealt with extensively elsewhere. Suffice it to say that

Lenin was the last person to break with Kautskyist orthodoxy and was at

a loss to explain the "betrayal" of his hero at the outbreak of WW1.

Lenin's full acceptance of the Kautskyist notion that worker's could not

transcend "trade union consciousness" without the intervention of

bourgeois intellectuals bringing them the proper consciousness from

outside, as stated in "What is to be done?" has been remarked upon many

times before. In this context we should see that Lenin's modification of

the fourth element from mass parliamentary party to a covert, compact

vanguard party of professional revolutionaries was simply a tactical

adaptation to the changed conditions of Russia - i.e. relative

backwardness and absolutist repression - as was explicitly stated as

such. Hence why Lenin is incapable of explaining Kautsky's "betrayal" on

any factor other than the subjective one - a "failure of leadership".

Here, ultimately, lies the progression of Leninism and it's remaining

descendants, principally Trotskyism, from the mass party tactic. Now the

fourth, bridging or substitutive element is a voluntarist subjectivism.

For the Leninist or Trotskyist, all problems of revolution can be

reduced to "the leadership question". In the face of actual situations

which force orthodox Marxists to remember that they are supposed to be

revolutionaries, the subjective element, completely eradicated from the

orthodox universe by its "objective laws", must, like Freud's return of

the repressed, return even stronger and yet not related to any

materialist analysis of consciousness itself, as an autonomous agent.

The final actor in our brief survey of post-Kautskyist orthodoxy is

Amadeo Bordiga. His case is a little different from Luxemburg, Pannekoek

or Lenin, as he was less directly influenced by German socialdemocracy,

Italian socialism having it's own separate tradition going back to the

Italian wing of the First International. Bordiga is often called "more

Leninist than Lenin", however, the anti-democratic extremism of

Bordigism conceals a subtle but important difference. For Bordiga it is

not the party, whether mass or vanguard, that is the bridging element,

but the programme itself. The programme is the solution to the problem

of false consciousness. The development of the correct revolutionary

consciousness of the proletariat is carried out by its most conscious

minority who formulate the revolutionary programme. Once formed, the

programme then represents the answer to everything. It is the correct

revolutionary consciousness, written down in a proper scientific manner.

Hence calls for democracy within the party or in the relationship

between the party and the rest of the class can only be confusionist,

and thus, objectively counter-revolutionary. Bordiga himself was from

working class origins but had educated himself and worked his way into a

career as an agricultural engineer. To him notions such as the

Kautsky/Lenin thesis that the working class were reliant on outside

forces to intermediate scientific knowledge were self-evident nonsense.

Still and all, he held to the core notions of economism (if anything he

was the most deterministic of all), scientism (hence the disdain for

democracy) and false consciousness (any deviation from the programme).

In many ways, although an outsider compared to the SPD mainstream that

formed Luxemburg, Pannekoek and Lenin, Bordiga was the most orthodox of

them all.

In the post-war period, all of the dissendents from the "official"

communist movement of the Comintern linked parties, whether from

Trotskyist, Council Communist or Bordigist origins remained trapped

within the orthodox framework, despite their different bridging

solutions and attempts to locate the origins of the failure of the

Russian Revolution. Attempts to escape from rigid orthodoxy by going

back to early dissidents like Lukács and the re-discovery of the

writings of the early Marx on alienation, tended to lose themselves

ineffectively in abstruse philosophy or simply end up falling back unto

one or other of the micro-tendencies of the orthodox ultra-left. The

Situationists, in the heady environment of the wave of struggles of the

late 60s, were the first to raise the flag for a post-orthodox Marxism

with their manifesto in which they rejected both economism and

scientism. However, their escape was incomplete, entranced as they were

by the false consciousness problem. Unable to fully recognise the

objectivist origins of this concept or overcome it on anything other

than with a superficial, idealist critique that was not itself able to

overcome the apparent separation of circulation and production, they

ended up falling back into the orthodox councillist politics of

Socialisme ou Barbarie, albeit that they had formally broken their

organisational ties some time before. Similarly a lot of the so-called

"New Left" of the late 60s was clouded with variants of Maoism or

Guevaraism, which, as an alternative to orthodoxy, was as much an

advance as giving up Poker for Snap.

However, in Italy things were stirring. With the rise of the operaisti,

Marxists at last encountered a new formulation that went beyond the

cage-like framework of orthodoxy. The concept of class composition

finally transcended the is/ought problem of false consciousness,

economism was overturned with a renewed emphasis on class struggle as

the motor of capitalist development, not some transcendent "objective

laws of motion". Technology was no longer a neutral power, but a weapon

deployed in the class war by bosses against workers, but one which could

harm the wielder as well as the target and was not immune from being

taken off the bosses and turned back against them. Naturally these

developments were met with howls or protest from the orthodox faithful,

Stalinist, Trotskyist and ultra-left alike, and indeed they still are.

But the requirements of brevity have already been sorely tested, even

stretched beyond all recognition, so we must leave it there for now.

[1] At this stage it should be pointed out that the tradition is when

critiquing a certain reading of Marx, to counter perceived misreadings

by other, contrasting quotes from Marx. We are not going to do this

here, for the sake of brevity let's just take it as read that the

orthodox reading of Marx is not the only one available.

[2] Like most popular quotes, this isn't entirely accurate. The actual

phrase (at the beginning of the Communist Manifesto) is "The history of

all hitherto existing society is the history of class struggles" (Die

Geschichte aller bisherigen Gesellschaft ist die Geschichte von

Klassenkämpfen). But, whatever, see previous note.