💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › sam-dolgoff-the-critique-of-marxism.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 13:55:07. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: The Critique of Marxism
Author: Sam Dolgoff
Date: 1983
Language: en
Topics: Marxism, critique, the State, class struggle, economics
Notes: First published by **Soil of Liberty**, Minneapolis, 1983

Sam Dolgoff

The Critique of Marxism

From the original:

The author has meant this pamphlet to be provocative, The Soil of

Liberty staff is not in complete agreement with everything in the

pamphlet but felt it should be printed. We welcome comments for future

magazine issues of Soil of Liberty.

This pamphlet is the second published by Soil of Liberty. The first,

“The Relevance of Anarchism to Modern Society”, is also by Sam Dolgoff

and is available for 55¢, including postage. Bulk rates are available.

Sam has been active in the anarchist movement since the 1920s and

presently lives in New York City.

Soil of Liberty also has a book service and a catalog will soon be

available. Magazine subscriptions are $3 -$4 a-year. Address is on the

back cover.

Foreword

This summation is written in response to young people seeking

clarification of the main issues involved in the classic controversy

between Marxists and anarchists. The subject matter is arranged in the

form of extracts from relevant sources. The anarchists as well as the

marxists speak for themselves in quotations culled from their works.

Since the non-anarchist critique of Marxism has taken a libertarian

direction, we have also included extracts from such writings.

Our critique excludes forgotten earlier writings disavowed by Marx and

Engels and deals only with their mature works. In his preface to Marx’s

Critique of Political Economy, Engels revealed that he and Marx had

“…abandoned the manuscript of The Ger*ma*n Ideology [1846] to the

gnawing criticism of the mice…” A Russian visitor, Alexis Vodin, who

interviewed Engels in 1893, wrote that Engels “was very embarrassed when

I expressed interest in Marx and Engels’ earlier writings…” (see David

Mclellan, Marx Before Marxism, 1970, p. 208) Only in 1927 was an edition

of the earlier writings published by the Marx-Engels Institute in

Moscow.

Passages marked in [brackets] are mine. Those marked in (parentheses)

are the writer’s. References are also marked in (parentheses).

Economic Determinism

Marxism is based upon the theory of Economic Determinism (or its

equivalent terms – Historical Materialism, Dialectical Materialism,

Materialistic Conception of History, Scientific Socialism, etc.).

Economic Determinism constitutes the essence of Marxism. It is defined

by Engels in this famous passage from his introduction to Marx’s

Critique of Political Economy:

“…all past history was the history of class struggles… these warring

classes of society are always the products of the conditions of

production and exchange, in a word, of the economic condition of the

time; [Engels’ emphasis] therefore the economic structure of society

always forms the real basis from which, in the last analysis, is to be

explained, the whole superstructure of legal and political institutions

[the state] as well as the religious, philosophical, and other

conceptions of each historical period.. .all moral theories are the

product, in the last analysis, of the economic stage which society

reached at that particular epoch… with the same certainty, can we deduce

the social revolution from the existing social conditions and the

principles of political economy… now, a materialist conception of

history has been propounded and the way found to explain man’s

consciousness by his being, instead of his being by his consciousness…”

[Marx formulates this more concisely]

“..,it is not the consciousness of men that determines their existence –

but their social existence which determines their consciousness…”

(Critique of Political Economy)

“…the course of history is governed by inner laws operating in spite of

the consciously desired aims of individuals...” (Engels, Ludwig

Feurbach, p. 48, emphasis added)

The Critique

Over a century ago Bakunin anticipated much the same arguments against

Marx’s theory of Economic Determinism as did later writers. He stressed

the point that causes and effects are continuously interacting and

replacing themselves. Causes become effects. Effects, in turn, become

causes. For example:

“…Marx holds that the political condition of each country is always..,

the faithful expression of its economic situation…. He takes no account

of other factors in history such as the ever-present reaction of

political, juridical and religious institutions on the economic

situation. He says poverty produces political slavery, the State, [but

ignores the fact] that political slavery, the State, reproduces, in its

turn, and maintains poverty as a condition for its own existence…. Marx

ignores completely … a multitude of ethnological, climatological and

historic causes,.., which independent of the economic conditions of each

country, [Bakunin stresses the ‘spirit of revolt’] exert a considerable

influence on its destinies and even on its economic development…”

(Letter to La Liberte – 1872)

J.M. Cameron, English historian and sociologist:

“…it is not true that in history we are faced, first, with men

associating together in economic life, and then with men worshipping the

gods, inventing moral codes, .and justifying this or that political

order…. We are faced with men engaged in all these activities at once.

If we approach history without preconceptions, we have no means by which

we can determine certain attitudes to be primary and others secondary.

All we know is that they co-exist. As sociologists and historians we

ought not single out certain phenomena and describe them as causes and

other phenomena as effects. The only assumption that accords with the

scientific is that we are faced with a developing whole the parts of

which are continuously interacting…” (Scrutiny of Marxism, p. 28; 1948)

The article entitled “Dialectics” in the Encyclopedia Britannia (1969)

also stresses the often decisive importance of non-economic factors in

the shaping of history, grossly underestimated by Marx:

“…many economic facts are just as much effects as they are causes

…changes in artistic tastes, in political institutions, in social

traditions and even religious doctrines influence consumption of

commodities and thereby become determinants of production and law is

just as much a determinant as it is a product of economic life. Thus a

maze of causal relationships results and with causes and effects

indistinguishable in many instances, no social program could be built on

this foundation….”

It may be objected that both Cameron and the Encyclopedia, are too

conservative and unfair to Marxism. But R.H. Tawney, a social thinker

and historian whose works are highly recommended by the Marxists, voices

much the same criticism of Marx’s theory of Economic Determinism:

“…that men should have thought as they did is sometimes as significant

as they should have acted as they did… there is an evolution of ideas as

well as organisms, and the quality of civilization depends less on

physical qualities, than on a complex structure of habits, knowledge and

beliefs, the destruction of which would be followed in a year by the

death of half the human race… there is a moral and religious, as well as

material environment which sets its stamp on the individual… and the

effects of changes in this environment are no less profound….” (Religion

and the Rise of Capitalism, pp. 18-19)

Engels himself unintentionally (to be sure) pinpoints the major fallacy

of Economic Determinism:

“…causes [the economic structure of society] and effects, [the whole

legal, political, moral, etc. ‘superstructure’], are constantly changing

places and what is now or here an effect becomes there or then a cause

and vice-versa… truly, when a man is in possession of the final and

ultimate truth, it is only natural that he should have a certain

contempt for erring and unscientific humanity….” (Anti-Duhring, pp. 36,

29)

It follows from this that the fundamental dogma of Marxism, Economic

Determinism – “the final and ultimate truth”, is, according to Engels

himself, demonstrably false.

Economic Determinism: The Role of the Proletariat

Economic Determinism is a doctrine which in practice saps the

revolutionary vitality of the masses, conditions them to accept

capitalism and to co-operate with their rulers in their own enslavement.

To effect social changes, the workers must, according to Marx, adapt

themselves to the slow, progressive evolution of economic structures

because “no social formation ever disappears before all the productive

forces are developed for which it has room, and new higher relations of

production never appear before the necessary material conditions are

matured in the womb of the old society.” (Critique of Political Economy)

It takes a long time. “We say to the workers and the petty bourgeoisie;

‘suffer in bourgeois society which creates, by developing industry, the

material means for the formation of the new society which will free all

of you.’” [Marx on the lessons of the 1848 revolutions.] No matter how

great the suffering, the workers are promoting progress because “in the

evolution of society, ancient, asiatic, feudal and bourgeois modes of

production constitute progressive epochs in the economic systems of

society…” (Introduction to the Critique of Political Economy)

On the same grounds, Engels goes so far as to defend the institution of

slavery: “The introduction of slavery in Greece under the conditions of

that time, was a great step forward…, it was slavery that first made

possible the development of agriculture and industry and with it the

flower of the ancient world, Hellenism. Without slavery, no Greek State,

no Greek art and science; without slavery no Roman Empire; without

Hellenism and the Roman Empire as a basis, no Europe… without the

slavery of antiquity no modern socialism…” (Anti-Duhring, p. 203)

The consistent Economic Determinist could just as well argue on the same

grounds that since production had developed to a point where there was a

shortage of labor power, and since the shortage was made up by

converting prisoners-of-war into slaves, therefore, wars were necessary

and ultimately beneficial.

In his polemic against Proudhon (The Poverty of Philosophy, 1847, quoted

on p. 357 in Handbook of Marxism, International, 1935), Marx maintained

that slavery in America was still an economic necessity, arguing that

“slavery is an economic category, like any other. Slavery is just as

much the pivot of bourgeois industry as machinery or credit…, without

slavery you have no cotton, without cotton, you have no modern

industry…, without slavery, North America, the most progressive of

countries would be turned into a primitive country. Abolish slavery and

you will have wiped America off the map of nations.”

Question: How progressive is a country whose very existence depends on

slavery?

Franz Mehring, Marx’s official biographer, explains that “Marx not only

shows that machinery and large scale industry created greater misery

than any mode of production known in history, but that also in their

ceaseless revolutionisation of capitalist society they are preparing the

way for a higher social form… the machine which degrades the worker into

its mere appendage, creates at the same time the increasing productive

forces of society so that all members of society will enjoy a life

worthy of human beings, which could not be done before because

pre-capitalist societies were too poor.”

Since, according to the Communist Manifesto, the bourgeoisie is the

bearer of large-scale industry, it is in the interests of the workers to

help the bourgeoisie to seize power as soon as possible and as soon as

the bourgeoisie develops industry, to overthrow it. The workers should

co-operate gladly because “as long as the rising mode of production

furthers the general aims of society, it is enthusiastically welcomed

even by those who suffer most from its corresponding mode of

distribution. This was the case with the English workers in the

beginnings of large scale industry” (Engels, Anti-Duhring, pp. 167-8). A

deliberate brazen falsehood if ever there was one and a calculated

insult to the valiant English workers who fought for freedom with

unexampled courage. (See E.P. Thompson, The Making of the English

Working Class)

Mehring explains that “Marx and Engels aimed at utilizing the

Franco-Prussian War as thoroughly as possible in the interests of the

proletarian struggle for emancipation… Engels condemned the leaders of

the German Socialist Party, William Liebknecht and August Bebel, because

they abstained from voting war credits… The situation is: Germany has

been forced into a war to defend its national existence against

Bonaparte… Bonaparte’s war policy was directed against the national

unity Germany and, since the establishment of a united German state is

necessary for the ultimate emancipation of the workers, the war must be

supported. Bismarck [in prosecuting the war and unifying Germany] is

doing a share of our work.”

Engels wrote that “militarism dominates and is swallowing Europe. But

this militarism carries within itself the seed of its own destruction…

Military rivalry forces states to spend more and more money on armaments

thus hastening financial catastrophe…, compulsory military service makes

the whole people familiar with the use of arms… the people revolt

against the commanding military lords.., the armies of the princes

become transformed into the armies of the People; the military machine

refuses to work and militarism collapses by the dialectic of its own

evolution… gunpowder and other inventions not only revolutionized

warfare, but in revolutionizing industry, warfare represents an economic

advance.” (Anti-Duhring, p. 192)

In an 1872 letter to the anarchist Carlo Cafiero, Engels declared that

both Bismarck and King Victor Emanuel rendered immense service to the

Revolution by creating political centralization in their respective

countries. “…just as in economic evolution there is the tendency for

capital to concentrate in fewer hands and for the smaller capitalist to

be swallowed by the large, so likewise in political evolution it is

inevitable that the small states should be absorbed by the great….”

(Franz Mehring quotes Engels in Karl Marx, pp. 164-5)

In criticizing [the young, pre-anarchist – Ed.] Bakunin’s Appeal to the

Slavs — which called for the independence of the Slavic peoples and the

destruction of the Russian Empire, the Austro-Hungarian Empire and

Prussia, the Neue Rheinische Zeitung (Feb. 14 1849,-edited by Marx)

declared that “no Slavic people has a future for the simple reason that

they lack the indispensable political and industrial conditions for

independence… the stubborn Czechs and the Slovaks should be grateful to

the Germans who have taken the trouble to civilize them be introducing

them to commerce, industry, agricultural science and education… What

would Texas or California have gained if it would be in the hands of the

lazy Mexicans?”

It follows from the above quotation that militants who fight against

slavery and for racial equality, people who refuse to help the

bourgeoisie bosses, people who are against war and militarism, people

who are for the freedom and independence of small nations against

imperialist domination, are, according to marxist theory,

“dialectically” counter-revolutionists against their oppressors who are

unconsciously preparing the road for socialism.

Engels extols parliamentary political action and class collaboration —

”…the two million voters for the German Social Democratic Party plus the

young men and women non-voters who stand behind them… form the most

compact ‘shock troops’ of the international Proletarian Army.., if this

goes on, we shall at the close of the century win over the greater part

of the middle social layers, the petty bourgeoisie as well as the small

peasants, and we shall come to be the decisive power in the land…. The

capitalist parties perish because of the legal means set up by

themselves,… the Social Democratic revolution… is getting on first rate

while abiding by the law…” (pamphlet, “The Revolutionary Act”)

This catastrophic policy which led to the emasculation of the socialist

movement and its absorption into the capitalist State, rendered the

German socialist movement (numerically the strongest in the world)

impotent to resist the First World War as well as the rise of Nazi

fascism — historical tragedies whose magnitude it is impossible to

assess.

Nature of the State

That economic factors to a greater or lesser degree, depending on

circumstances, shape events is an indisputable fact. To assert, however,

that the ultimate cause of all social changes is to be found only in

changes in the mode and relations of production is a gross distortion

which cannot be sustained by the facts of history.

The marxist misconception of history stems primarily from erroneous

ideas about the origin and nature of the State and its preponderant role

in the shaping of the economic and social life of humanity.

According to the Communist Manifesto, “the executive of the modern State

is but a committee for managing the common affairs of the whole

bourgeoisie.” Bakunin maintained that the State is not merely an agent

of the dominant economic class, but that the State also constitutes a

class in itself and is the most powerful of all by virtue of its

monopoly of armed force and its sovereignty over all other social

institutions. In contrast to Marx, Bakunin argued that the State is not

only the product but also the creator and perpetuator of economic,

political and social inequality.

Bakunin’s critique has in this respect been sustained by modern social

thinkers. Sidney Hook states flatly that “the existence of the Soviet

Union refutes the theory of historical materialism … since the basic

economic changes were achieved through political action [the State].”

(Marx and the Marxists, p. 124) It was this development which led Rudolf

Hilferding, a noted Marxist economist, to revise his ideas about the

nature of the State: “…the Marxist sectarian cannot grasp the idea that

the present-day State power, having achieved independence, is unfolding

its enormous strength according to its own laws, subjecting social

forces and compelling them to serve its ends… Therefore, neither the

Russian, nor totalitarian systems in general, is determined by the

character of the economy. On the contrary, it is the economy that is

determined by the policy of the ruling power. An analogy to the

totalitarian State may be found in the era of the Roman Empire in the

regime of the Praetorians and their emperors….” (quoted by Hook in Marx

and the Marxists, p. 241)

In this connection the political scientist, Michel Collinet, observes

that “for Lenin, the Revolution is not the necessary consequence of the

productive forces, but of a militarized party of professional

revolutionaries who knew how to use an effective strategy to profit by

political occasions….” (Le Contrat Social, Jan. 1957)

The Marx-Engels notion that in primitive society the State originally

arose to “safeguard the common interests of tribal societies against

external enemies and later to protect the economic and political

position of the ruling class” is false. The contention that exploitation

arose through “purely economic causes… and not at all by the State… that

historically, private property by no means makes appearance as the

result of robbery and violence” is also false. (Engels, Anti-Duhring,

pp. 167, 171, 184)

Evidence to the contrary is overwhelming. All competent historians and

anthropologists, among them Edward Jenks, agree that:

“…the State, in its origin, was not an economic, but a military

institution… formed by conquest and plunder… unwilling themselves to

practice the patient arts of husbandry… the invading hosts settled down

like a swarm of locusts on their prey… the rich vineyards and fields of

Europe… No permanent State was ever built unaided by an invading host…

the State itself, though intensely military in character, imposes itself

on a solid base of permanent agriculture, which will supply its needs by

wealth drawn from the fruitful soil.., the primitive State was simply a

band of warriors under a military leader — Clovis, Rurik, Norman William

— but as time went on… as the band of warriors settled down as lords and

rulers of their fiefs, as hereditary successors to office and title

became recognized… the State began to assume in varied forms the

character of an institution, a piece of machinery which maintains a

perpetual existence, despite the death of kings and barons…” (Edward

Jenks, The State and the Nation, 1919, pp. 130, 131)

“…**the State is essentially military in character… its methods are

mainly non-productive… they do not produce values, but merely preserve

or destroy them.. From its earliest stages its policy has been

annexation or plunder of its own or alien communities… it creates

property by handing over the resources of the community to individuals

or small groups and this is, in effect, what the State had done by

creating individual and private property and protecting it with its

overwhelming power… the State received its return from this reckless

squandering of the resources of the community…” (Jenks, p. 237, my

emphasis)

“…the Roman Empire rests on force only, a brute force let loose by the

lowest appetites.., it bound every man to his occupation… chained him

and his descendants to the same post [occupation], established a real

caste system… the wholesale destruction of wealth created by the subject

peoples … Rome’s industry in the second and first centuries, B.C. had

been war and the spoliation of the vanquished… the fruits of conquest

were dissipated in a century…” (Ferdinand Lot, The End of the Ancient

World and the Beginnings of the Middle Ages, pp. 8, 65, 84, 85, 82)

We cite a few examples from the anarchist Gaston Leval’s excellent

analysis of Marxism which awaits translation into English:

“…the Visigoth dynasty [ruling much of Iberia and France after the Roman

Empire fell – Ed.] did not derive its origin from the institution of

private property nor from changes in the mode of production. It was the

creation of the ‘conquistadores’ who institutionalized the domination

and economic exploitation of the conquered peoples…”

“…what became France, was founded by Clovis [first king of the Franks –

Ed.], a bandit who murdered his rivals and with a savage horde of

warriors from the north routed the Romans and the Germans [Visigoths –

Ed]. With each victory he and his successors augmented their forces,

conquered more territories, and by plunder, rapine and extortion,

engineered the economic subjugation of the conquered peoples, dividing

property and the spoils of war among themselves. The true creators of

the State were the militarists and the politicians, not only in Spain

and France, but also in Flanders [Belgium], Germany, Russia and other

northern European countries, and in Italy….”

“…the State by its very nature, tends to have a life of its own. It is a

parasitic institution living at the expense of society… in Latin America

the Spanish and Portuguese ‘conquistadores’ seized the land of the

natives, plundered the urban communities, and by brute force, not by

changes in the mode of production, imposed feudal regimes which to this

day weigh so heavily on the economic and political institutions of so

many nations… to give land to its soldiers and officials, the invaders

changed the social structure of the conquered territories…”

To illustrate the predominance of the State, Leval points out that

during the post-war period in the newly established small States “there

already appeared Ministers, a repressive apparatus, jails, and

executioners… There already appear classes. The new classes do not owe

their existence to technological developments or changes in the mode of

production. They are brought into being by the newly created State — the

institutionalized political authority controlling or dominating the

economic and social life of the people…”

“…the economy of the newly established States, may deteriorate; mass

starvation and disease may decimate the population; but the ministries

grow. The police and armed forces multiply. The new bureaucracy

flourishes. A new powerful class exploits the peasants, levies taxes,

and suffocates the people in an avalanche of rules and restrictions…”

“…Rene’ Dumont, a renowned agronomist and sociologist, reports from

visits to some of the new States that the principal industry of these

new countries is governmental administration. In fifteen former French

colonies newly independent — economic production declined, but the

production of politicians grew. In Dahomey, the wages of the

governmental bureaucracy absorbs 70% of the national income. The

situation in Gabon is just as bad or worse, as it is in other countries

Dumont visited. As soon as a peasant learns to read and write he goes to

the city to become a functionary..,” (above quotes from Gaston Leval, La

Falacia del Marxismo, Mexico City, 1967, pp. 116, 117, 118)

Bakunin anticipated just such a development: “…in Turkish Serbia [after

independence – Ed.] … there is only one class in control of the

government — the bureaucracy. The one and only function of the State,

therefore, is to exploit the Serbian people in order to provide the

bureaucrats with all the comforts of life…” (Statism and Anarchy)

The State and Production

Marx and Engels praised the bourgeoisie for advancing the economy by

“lumping together… loosely connected provinces.., or small independent

states into one nation, with one government, one code of laws etc…”

(Communist Manifesto). This assumption, that political centralization —

the State, facilitates economic development is a dangerous illusion

refuted by massive evidence. The fact is that wars between States

devastated whole nations. The State wrecked the economy, stifled

initiative and held back progress for centuries.

The Class Struggle

In the Communist Manifesto, Marx and Engels declare that their

“theoretical conclusions are based on the class struggle.” That class

struggles are a factor in social change no one will deny. But the dogma

that “the history of all hitherto existing society is the history of

class struggles” (Communist Manifesto) is false.

Gaston Leval demonstrates that “wars between migratory hordes and

sedentary populations, nations and States, count in history more than

class wars — particularly in Europe and Asia… In Spain, recall the six

centuries of war against the Arabs. Read the literature of the 10th to

the 16th Centuries to realize how little part the class war played as

compared to religious and racial factors; how little the class war

figured in the conquest of Sicily and almost all of Italy, Flanders and

part of France by the Spanish armies; the international religious wars

between Christians and Mohammendans; or the conquest of Latin America by

Spain — the people of Spain sided with the kings…”(La Falacia del

Marxismo, pp 121-2)

Contrary to the Communist Manifesto, the Plebians did not constitute a

revolutionary class. In the centuries of the Roman Empire, both the

Patricians and the Plebians approved the enslavement of

prisoners-of-war, who were drafted to reinforce the armies of Caesar,

Lucullus, and Pompeii. Although the Patricians represented the big

landholders and the Plebians the small farmers; the Plebians were not

interested in the abolition of privilege or the establishment of a new

economic order. “Their sole concern,” writes Rudolf Rocker, “was to

participate in the privileges of the Patricians and to obtain an equal

share in the spoils of war.” (Nationalism and Culture, p. 379)

As compared to the catastrophic impact of wars in this century, even the

most protracted struggles between workers and employers are of minor

significance.

Marx surely underestimated the importance of nationalism in shaping

history. He thought that nationalism would be superseded by class

struggles because the proletariat would become class conscious in the

process of struggle.

In this connection Lewis Mumford disagrees with Marx:

“When Marx wrote in the 1850s, nationalism seemed to him to be a dying

movement… it had in fact, taken on a new life… with the massing of the

population into national States which continued during the 19th Century,

the national struggle for political power cut at right angle to the

class struggle… the struggle for political power now became a struggle

between States for command of exploitable areas… after 1850, nationalism

became the drill master of the restless proletariat who identified

themselves with the all-powerful State” (Technics and Civilization, pp.

189, 190, 191)

Marx and Engels believed that “modern industrial labour subjection to

capitalism, in England, France, America and Germany, has stripped the

proletariat of every trace of national character. Law, morality,

religion, are to the proletariat so many bourgeois prejudices.”

(Communist Manifesto)

The trouble with this argument is that workers still nurse these

prejudices and act accordingly. What a worker thinks and feels may

determine his or her reaction to events more than what he or she does

for a living.

With the coming of World War I (which according to Marxist theory should

have signalled the long delayed collapse of capitalism), the proletariat

– ”the only really revolutionary class” (Communist Manifesto), became

rabid nationalists, and even the German Socialist Party deputies in the

Reichstag patriotically voted war credits.

In opposition to Marx, Bakunin argued that the bourgeois-minded workers

in the advanced industrialized countries are not going to make

revolutions [This is incorrect—Bakunin was often sceptical about the

upper layer of workers in all countries, and never rejected the Western

working class– Ed.].

History proved Bakunin right and Marx wrong. The most notable

revolutions of this century have been those that broke out in Russia and

China. Nor did the October Revolution, as Lenin expected, initiate a

series of proletarian upheavals in the advanced countries of Western

Europe that were deemed ripe for the Social Revolution.

Marx attached slight importance to psychological factors in revolution,

but Bakunin insisted that revolution was impossible for people who had

“lost the habit of freedom.” He left more room for people’s will, their

aspiration for freedom and equality and “the instinct of revolt” which

constitutes the “revolutionary consciousness” of oppressed peoples.

Rudolf Rocker writes that:

“…in France, crafts and industries were brought under the regimentation

of the State… rigorous regulations and methods of work were decreed for

all industries… an army of officials took care that no one deviated even

by a hair’s breadth from established norms. Tailors were told how many

stitches to make in sewing a sleeve into a coat; the cooper, how many

hoops to put around a barrel. The State not only decreed the length,

width and colour of woven fabrics but specified the number of threads in

each weave. Violations were punished by confiscation of goods; in

serious cases, by destruction of material, tools, workshops, etc… Just

as agricultural production under serfdom declined sharply; so did the

Royal ordinances and regimentation wreck industry and bring France to

the brink of ruin…”

“As in France, English industry too, was subjected to severe

restrictions. The Court was interested only in filling the Royal

treasury. Under the reign of Charles I, the monopoly for the manufacture

of soap was sold to a company of London soap boilers and a special

ordinance forbade any household to make soap for its own use. Rights to

exploit tin and coal deposits in the north of England, glass and other

industries were sold to the highest bidders…”

“When England acquired its colonial empire, immense territories were

sold to monopolists for ridiculously low payments from which they

derived enormous profits in a few years… Queen Elizabeth sold exclusive

rights to commercial companies to trade in the East Indies and all lands

east of the Cape of Good Hope and west of the Straits of Magellan.

Charles II gave exclusive rights to exploit Virginia to his

father-in-law. Rights were sold to the Hudson Bay Company for 20% of the

profits, etc…” (Nationalism and Culture, 1937, pp. 125, 126, 430, 431)

Peter Kropotkin denounced:

“…revolutionaries who glorify the State… the modern radical is a

centralist, Statist and rabid Jacobin, and the Socialists (Marxists

included) fall in step. Just as the Florentines at the end of the 15th

Century knew no better than to call upon the dictatorship of the State

to save themselves from the Patricians; so the socialists only call upon

the same gods, the dictatorship of the State to save themselves from the

horrors of the economic regime, created by the very same State!”

“The role of the nascent State in the 16th and 17th Centuries was to

destroy the independence of the cities; to pillage the rich guilds of

the merchants and artisans; to concentrate in its hands the external

commerce; to lay hands on the internal administration of the guilds and

subject internal commerce and all manufacturing to the last detail to

the control of a host of officials and in this way, to kill industry and

the arts; taking over the local militias and the whole municipal

administration; crushing the weak in the interests of the strong by

taxation and ruining countries by wars and the lands were either simply

stolen by the rich with the connivance of the State or confiscated by

the State directly…”

Kropotkin calls attention to the:

“…shameless waste of the Ministers and the Court; the monstrous profits

of the private concessionaires who collected indirect taxes and similar

profits by the innumerable official collectors who channelled the direct

tax into the treasury…. Industry in the 18th Century was dying… all the

State was capable of doing was to tighten the screws for the workers;

depopulate the countryside; spread misery in the towns; reduce millions

of human beings to a state of starvation and impose industrial

serfdom,., already, at the close of the 14th Century, an edict by Edward

III, King of England, decreed that ‘every alliance, connivance,

meetings, enactments and solemn oaths made or to be made between

carpenters and masons [or any other trades] are null and void’.., in

1801 the French government itself undertook to appoint mayors and

syndics in each of the thirty thousand communes…” (The State: Its

Historic Role, pp. 41-43, 46-47)

Engels justified the tyranny of the State on the ground that “forcible

measures of Louis 14th, made it easier for the bourgeoisie to carry

through their revolution”. But the bourgeoisie, in the name of the

“common will” fought the absolute monarchy for the exclusive right to

exploit the workers; just as they crushed the revolt of the workers and

the sans culottes during the French Revolution a century later. Marx and

Engels conceded that the bourgeoisie “established new classes, new

oppress-ions… in place of the old ones…” (Communist Manifesto). But

their inability to learn from historical events that no State can ever

play a revolutionary role, persists to this day.

Marx’s whole theory of history and economic laws led him to predict both

the inevitable collapse of capitalism and the dictatorship of the

proletariat. But capitalism has not only been able to survive. It has

actually become more entrenched by adopting, in various degrees,

social-democratic reform measures; thereby absorbing the labour and

socialist movements into the structure of the State capitalist economic

system (-sometimes designated “welfare state” or “welfare capitalism

“)The political scientist Michel Collinet points out that “if the

cyclical crises of capitalism are, as Marx predicted, a source of misery

and insecurity; it is also a fact that after more than a hundred years,

it has not led the working class to make a [PROLETARIAN] Social

Revolution. The terrible economic depression of 1929, profoundly divided

and demoralized the workers and their political parties who claim to

represent them… in Europe the crisis aggravated nationalism and brought

on the fascist racist reaction. In America, the ‘New Deal’ of Roosevelt;

in France, the popular front… strengthened capitalism…” (Le Contrat

Social, January 1967. I have inserted and emphasized the PROLETARIAN to

establish the point that neither the largely agrarian Russian nor the

Chinese Revolution were really proletarian.)

The Marxist Max Schachtman, in his introduction to Franz Mehring’s

biography of Karl Marx, admits the “incontestable fact that the class

struggle has not… led to the rule of the working class that was to be

transitional-to a classless society — the perspective that Marx himself

held to be his unique contribution — cannot be explained away…” And Max

Eastman in his introduction to an anthology of Marx and Engels writings,

likewise objects that “the very first sentence of the Communist

Manifesto, ‘the History of all hitherto existing society is the history

of class struggles’ shows the disposition to read one’s own interests

into the definition of facts…”

Marx and most authoritarian socialists did not give much thought to the

forms of organization that might translate into reality the ideal of a

free, stateless society. The dialectical method which Marx employed in

working out his theory of Dialectical Materialism is essentially a

philosophy of perpetual conflict between opposing tendencies or forces

interrupted by temporary adjustments. There is conflict, but society is

also a vast interlocking network of co-operative labour and the very

existence of mankind depends upon this inner cohesion.

In this connection, Paul Avrich emphasizes that “mankind, in fact, owes

its existence to mutual assistance. The theories of Hegel, Marx and

Darwin notwithstanding, Kropotkin held that co-operation rather than

conflict lies at the root of the historical process…” (Introduction to

the 1972 edition of Kropotkin’s Mutual Aid: A Factor in Evolution)

Marx’s failure to appreciate this truth permeates his grossly distorted

conceptions.

Marx on Capitalism: The Dialectical Falsification of History

Marx’s notion that the “bourgeoisie has created more colossal productive

forces in scarce one hundred years than all preceding generations

together…” (Communist Manifesto) is a gross distortion. Lewis Mumford’s

classic study, Technics and Civilization, an objective assessment of the

relationship of capitalism to technology, corrects Marx on this point:

“While technics owes an honest debt to capitalism, as it does to war,

capitalism and technics must be clearly distinguished at every stage …

the machine took on characteristics that had nothing essential to do

with the technical process or the forms of work… it was because of

capitalism that the handicraft industries in Europe and other parts of

the world were recklessly destroyed by machine products; even when

machine products were inferior to the things they replaced.., the

machine has suffered from the sins of capitalism.., contrariwise,

capitalism has taken credit for the machine…”

“Although there is a close historical association of modern technics and

modern capitalism, there is no necessary connection between them*.*

Capitalism has existed in other civilizations, which had relatively low

technical development, and technics made steady improvements from the

10th to the 15th Century without the special incentives of capitalism…

between the 10th and the 18th Century all the technical preparations for

capitalism had already taken place…” (emphasis added, pp. 26, 27, 28)

Which refutes the silly remark that “no earlier century had even a

presentiment that such [capitalist] productive forces [existed]…”

(Communist Manifesto)

A few examples to refute that falsehood:

John U. Nef:

“…the most startling progress of the physical and mathematical sciences

in the 16th and early 17th centuries occurred in parts of Europe that

did not participate directly in the speeding-up of industrial growth in

England and Northern Europe…” Nef describes the “boom in mining and

metallurgy between the late 15th and early 16th centuries… when much of

continental Europe was built or rebuilt in the new Renaissance style of

architecture…” Nef also documents the “remarkable industrial development

especially striking in Northern Italy, parts of Spain, the southern low

countries and southern Germany…” (The Conquest of the Material World,

pp. 326, 42)*

Peter Kropotkin:

“All modern industry came to us from these free cities [of the Middle

Ages]. In three centuries, industries and the arts attained such

perfection that our century has only been able to surpass them in speed

of production, but rarely in quality or the intrinsic beauty of the

product… in each of its manifestations, our technical progress is only

the child of the civilization that grew up within the free communes… All

the great discoveries made by modern science; the compass, the clock,

the watch, printing, maritime discoveries, gunpowder, the laws of

gravitation, atmospheric pressure, of which the steam engine is a

development, the rudiments of chemistry, the scientific methods already

outlined by Roger Bacon and applied in the Italian universities… Where

do all these things originate if not in the free cities? In the

civilization which was developed under the protection of communal

liberties… in the 16th century Europe was covered with rich cities…

their caravans covered the continent, their vessels ploughed the seas

and the rivers…” (The State: Its Historic Role, p. 29)

“The cities of the 13th century [writes Lewis Mumford] were far brighter

and cleaner and better ordered than the new victorian towns. Medieval

hospitals were more spacious and more sanitary than the hospitals of the

victorian towns. In many parts of Europe the medieval workers had a

demonstrably higher standard of living than the drudge tied triumphantly

to a semi-automatic machine…” (Technics and Civilization, p. 183)

Kropotkin indignantly refutes the false allegations of the “historians

and economists who teach us that the village commune, having become an

outdated form of land possession which hampered progress, had to

disappear under the action of ‘natural economic forces’…” Kropotkin

denounces the Marxian “socialists who claim to be ‘scientific

socialists’ who repeat this stock fable… this odious calculated lie…

History abounds with documents to prove that the village commune was in

the first place deprived of all its powers by the State, of its

independence, and that afterwards the lands were either stolen with the

connivance of the State or confiscated by the State directly… Have we

not learned at school that the State had performed the great service of

creating, out of the ruins of feudal society, national unions which had

been previously made impossible by the rivalries between cities?”

Kropotkin calls attention to the fact that the “Dialectical

Materialists” do not even begin to appreciate the:

“…communalist movement that existed in the 11th and 12th centuries… this

movement with its virile affirmation of the individual; which succeeded

in creating a society through the free federation of’ towns and

villages, was the complete negation of the unitarian centralizing Roman

outlook. Nor is it linked to any historic personality or central

institution… Society was literally covered with a network of sworn

brotherhoods; of guilds for mutual aid… it is even very doubtful whether

there was a single man in that period, free man or serf, who did not

belong to a brotherhood or some guild, as well as to his commune… In the

course of a hundred years this movement spread in an impressive

harmonious way throughout Europe covering Scotland, France, the Low

Countries, Italy, Germany, Poland, Russia. In these cities [communes]

sheltered by their conquered liberties, inspired by free agreement and

free initiative, a whole new civilization grew up and flourished in ways

unparalleled to this day.” (The State: Its Historic Role)

Since Kropotkin developed these ideas in 1897, further research by

reputable historians and political scientists has confirmed his

analysis. Edward Jencks wrote:

“…the typical village of the middle ages in Western Europe and indeed,

of people in a corresponding stage the world over, was not like the

typical village of modern France or England, merely a locality in which

neighbours who carry on their work independently happen to live, but a

community, carrying on its work as a single body of co-partners governed

by customary rules, to which all must conform, it was not competitive…

the self-governing municipality, or borough, was the highest achievement

of the patriarchal principle; and after a dark period of repression, it

gallantly took up the struggle against the newer ideas of absolute rule

which produced the institution of the State…. it was founded on the

undying principles of brotherhood, freedom and voluntary co-operation,

as opposed to subordination, regimentation or compulsory service…” (The

State and the Nation, pp. 94, 116, 118, 137, Jenck’s comments concern

patriarchal society in transition to the free cities or communes

discussed by Kropotkin)

R.H. Tawney suggests that:

“it may do well to remember that the characteristic… of the medieval

guild was that if it sprang from economic needs, it claimed at least to

subordinate them to social needs… preserve a rough equality among the

good men of the mystery [association]; check economic egotism by

insisting that every brother shall share his good fortune with another

and-stand by his neighbour in need, resist the encroachments of a

conscienceless money-power; preserve professional standards of training

and craftsmanship, and to repress by a strict corporate discipline the

natural appetite of each to snatch advantages for himself to the

detriment of all… much that is now mechanical was then personal,

intimate and direct, and there was little room for organization on a

scale too vast for the standards that are applied to individuals, or the

doctrine that silences scruples and closes all accounts with the final

plea of economic expediency…”

“…the most fundamental difference between medieval and modern economic

thought is that while modern economic thought normally refers to

expediency, medieval economic thought starts from the position that

there is a moral authority to which considerations of economic

expediency must be subordinated… the fact that the socialist doctrine

should have been expounded as early as the middle of the 14th century is

a reminder that economic thought contained elements much more modern

than is sometimes suggested…” (Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, pp.

31, 32, 42, 43)

Thorough research by highly qualified historians leads to the

inescapable conclusion that capitalism is not, as the marxists insist,

the indispensable progressive precondition for the transition to

socialism. Actually, capitalism usurped the creative achievements of

mankind and reversed the libertarian trend of society, the better to

subjugate the people to the greed of the capitalists and the despotism

of the State.

Indisputable evidence also demonstrates that capitalism is not

inevitable and that there is a libertarian alternative: a flexible

society permeated by the principles of individual and collective

freedom, solidarity, self-management, federalism and free agreement. The

potential for such a society existed in the village communities,

brotherhoods, guilds and Free Cities [communes] of the Middle Ages.

Kropotkin did not, as is charged, idealize the Free Cities. In analysing

medieval society he took into account “the internal conflicts with which

the history of these communes is filled… street riots… blood spilled…

reprisals, etc…” But Kropotkin did prove that “all the elements, as well

as the fact itself, of large human groupings, freely constituted, were

already there…” (The State …) Writing thirty years later, Tawney too,

found that “the rise of the Free Cities was one of the glories of

medieval Europe and the germ of every subsequent advance in

civilization…” (Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, p. 55)

Conclusion

Marx’s theories have not been sustained by events. His system could be

best designated as “The Dialectic Falsification of History.” There are

no “laws of history” and progress from one stage of development to

another is not inevitable. Marxism is no longer relevant to the growing

number of people who are alarmed by the unprecedented proliferation of

the economic and military powers of the modern State and the concomitant

regimentation of the individual. Nationalization of property and means

of production, even in a “socialist” State, as advocated by Marx and

Engels, does not fundamentally alter the basic inequality between those

wielding power and those subject to it. Even Marxists no longer believe

that the State will “wither away”. Freedom is not merely the reflection

of the mode of production but the essence of life. The dogma that

science, philosophy, the arts, ethics and free institutions only mirror

the economic mode of production is giving way to the conviction that

these phenomena have an independent share in the shaping of history. A

theory for the renewal of society that attaches little or no importance

to these supreme values does not merit the respect of freedom-loving

people.