💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › william-morris-development-of-modern-society.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 14:46:37. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Development of Modern Society
Author: William Morris
Date: 1890
Language: en
Topics: Arts and Crafts, history, libertarian socialist
Source: Retrieved on 20 April 2011 from http://www.marxists.org/archive/morris/works/1890/development.htm
Notes: This version is taken from the original Commonweal, scanned and proofread by Ted Crawford with markup by Graham Seaman. Appeared serialised in Commonweal, Volume 6, Numbers 236–240, 19 July-16 August 1890.

William Morris

Development of Modern Society

Part 1

All the progressive races of man have gone through a stage of

development during which society has been very different to what it is

now. At present there is a very definite line of distinction drawn

between the personal life of a man and his life as a member of society.

As a rule, the only direction in which this social life is felt is in

that of his nearest kindred — his wife, children, parents, brothers and

sisters. This is so much the case that we to-day have given to the word

relations (which should mean all those with whom a man has serious and

continuous dealings) a fresh meaning, and made it signify only those

near members of kinship aforesaid. For the rest most civilised men

acknowledge no responsibility. Though the word State is in everybody’s

mouth, most people have but the vaguest idea as to what it means; it is

even generally considered as a synonym to the Government, which also

indicates either the heads of one of the political parties, or the vague

entity called by Carlyle the parish constable — in other words, the

executive power of the ruling classes in our society. So little do we

feel any responsibilities to this hardly conceivable thing, the State,

that while few indeed feel any loyalty towards it, most men do not

realise it sufficiently even to feel any enmity against it — except,

perhaps, when the tax-gatherer’s hand is on the knocker.

Now all this is so far the result of a long series of history, which I

must just hint at before one comes to the condition of the workman

during its different stages, — a series of events which tended to give

to the word property the meaning which it now has; a series of events

which tended more and more to consider things as the important matter of

consideration rather than persons; which I may illustrate by the fact

that nowadays the law looks upon the estate as of more importance than

the user of it, as for instance in the case of the estate of a lunatic,

which it will defend to the utmost against all attacks, and treat as if

it had a genuine life and soul capable of feeling all injuries and

pains, while all the time the lunatic is under restraint.

I will now contrast this entire ignoring of the community (for that will

be a better word than State to use at present) with the conditions under

which men lived in earlier ages of the world, and through which, as I

have said, all the progressive races have passed, some of them so early

that when we first meet them in history they are already passing out of

it into the next development. In this early period the individual is so

far from feeling no responsibility to the community, that all his

responsibilities have relation to the community. Indeed, this sense of

responsibility, as we shall see later on, has only been completely

extinguished since the introduction of the present economical and

political system — since the death of feudality, in short: but in the

period I am thinking about it was a quite unquestioned habit. The unit

of society, the first, and in the beginning the only bond, was the

narrowest form of clan, called the gens. This was an association of

persons who were traceably of one blood or kinship. Intermarriage

between its members was forbidden, or rather was not even dreamed of: a

man of the Eagle gens could have no sexual intercourse with an Eagle

woman, nor thought of it. All property was in common within the gens,

and descent was traced, not through the father, but through the mother,

who was the obvious parent of the child. Whatever competition (war, you

may call it, for competition was simple in those days), was outside the

group of blood relations, each of which felt no responsibility for other

groups of their members. But the fact that intermarriage was impossible

within these groups brought about a larger association. Since an Eagle

could not marry an Eagle, the Eagles must either get their wives by

violent robbery in a haphazard fashion from outsiders, or have some

other society at hand into which they could marry, and who could marry

into their society. It used to be thought that the violent robbery was

the method, but I believe the second method was the one used. There were

groups of neighbours at hand who were recognised as belonging to the

same stock, but who were not too near in blood to make marriage

impossible. Between these groups there was affinity, therefore; the

Eagles could intermarry with the Owls, the Sparrows, the Cats, or what

not, according to a somewhat intricate system, and this quite without

violence. And also between the clans or gentes who composed these tribes

there would be no war, and the use of whatever land they fed their stock

upon or cultivated (for in some places or ages this gentile-tribal

system lasted well into the agricultural period) was arranged peaceably

in a communal method.

Now the tribe in which a common ancestor (worshipped as a god) was

always assumed, and was generally a fact, tended to federate with other

tribes who still felt that they belonged to a common stock, who thus

formed an association called by our ancestors the thiod, or people; an

association much looser, of course, than that of the gens or tribe, but

like those, founded on an idea of common kindred; founded on the

personal kinship of all its members to the god-ancestor, and not on

locality or the holding of certain property or position. The offices of

the body, under whatever names they went, were appointed by the

tribesmen for their personal qualities to perform definite duties. There

was no central executive body; every freeman had certain necessary

duties to perform, a shadow of which still exists in our jury, who were

originally the neighbours called together to utter their finding

(without direction from a judge) as to how such a one had come by his

death, what was to do between two neighbours who could not agree, and so

forth. If a man was injured, it was the duty of the members of his gens

or clan to take up the injury as an injury to the community. This is the

meaning of the blood-feud of which we hear so much in the early

literature of the North, and of the Celtic clans, and a survival of

which still exists among out-of-the-way folks. The practice of the

vendetta in Corsica, e.g., does not indicate that the Corsicans are a

specially vindictive people; it is a survival of the tribal customary

law: its sentimentalising by novelists and poets is a matter of

ignorance — naturally enough, I admit. “Government” or administration,

or whatever else you may call it, was in this condition of society as

direct as it ever can be; nor had government by majority been invented —

e.g., if the clans could not agree to unite in war, the war could not go

on, unless any clan chose to go to war by itself.

I am conscious of not explaining fully the difference between such a

state of society and ours; but it is indeed difficult to do so now, when

all our ideas and the language which expresses them have been for so

many ages moulded by such a totally different society. But I must, at

least, try to make you understand that the whole of the duties of a

freeman in this society had reference to the community of which he

formed a part, and that he had no interests but the interest of the

community; the assertion of any such private interests would have been

looked upon as a crime, or rather a monstrosity, hardly possible to

understand. This feudal union of the tribes is the last state of society

under barbarism; but before I go on to the next stage, I must connect it

with our special subject, the condition of productive labour.

With the development of the clans into federated tribes came a condition

of organised aggressive war, since all were recognised as enemies

outside of the tribe or federation; and with this came the question what

was to be done with the prisoners taken in battle, and, furthermore,

what was to be done with the tribe conquered so entirely as not to be

able to defend its possessions, the land, which it used. Chattel slavery

was the answer to the one question, serfdom to the second. You see this

question was bound to come up in some form, as soon as the productive

powers of man had grown to a certain point. In the very early stages of

society slaves are of no use, because your slave will die unless you

allow him to consume all that he produces; it is only when by means of

tools and the organisation of labour that he can produce more than is

absolutely necessary for his livelihood, that you can take anything from

him. Robbery only begins when property begins; so that slavery doesn’t

begin till tribes are past the mere hunter period. When they go to war

they only save their prisoners to have some fun out of them by torturing

them, as the redskins did, unless, perhaps, as sometimes happened, they

adopt them into the tribe, which also the redskins did at times. But in

the pastoral stage slaves become possible, and when you come to the

agricultural stage (to say nothing of further developments) they become

necessary till the time when privilege is destroyed and all men are

equal. There are, then, three conditions of mankind, mere gregarious

organised savagery, slavery, and social equality. When you once have

come to that conclusion you must also come to this deduction from it,

that if you shrink from any sacrifice to the Cause of Socialism it must

be because we are either weak or criminal, either cowards or tyrants —

perhaps both.

Well, this last stage of barbarism, that of the federated tribes, gave

way in ancient history, the history of the Greeks and Romans, into the

first stage of civilisation. The life of the city, and in mediaeval

history into feudalism; it is under the latter that the development of

the treatment of the conquered tribe as serfs is the most obvious;

serfdom being the essence of mediaeval society proper, and its decay

beginning with the decline of serfdom. But, undoubtedly, there were

serfs in the classical period; that is to say an inferior class to the

freemen, who were allowed to get their own livelihood on the condition

of their performing certain services for them, and with a certain

status, though a low one, which raised them above the condition of the

chattel-slave, whose position was not recognised at all more than that

of his fellow labourer, the horse or the ass. The Helots, for example,

were the serfs rather than the slaves of the Spartans, and there were

other instances both among the Greeks and the Romans of labourers in a

similar position.

However, chattel slavery as opposed to serfdom is the characteristic

form of servitude in the ancient city life. In that life you must

understand the idea of the merging of the individual into the community

was still strong, although property had come into existence, and had

created a political condition of society under which things were growing

to be of more moment than persons. But the community had got to be an

abstraction, and it was to that abstraction, and not to the real visible

body of persons that individual interests were to be sacrificed. This is

more obvious among the Romans than the Greeks, whose mental

individuality was so strong and so various, that no system could

restrain it; so that when that system began to press heavily upon them

they could not bear it, and in their attempts to escape from its

consequences fell into the mere corruption of competitive tyranny at an

early period. The Romans, on the other hand, without art or literature,

a hard and narrow-minded race, cultivated this worship of the city into

an over-mastering passion, so fierce and so irrational that their

history before their period of corruption reads more like that of a set

of logical demons bent on torturing themselves and everybody else, than

a history of human beings. They must be credited with the preservation

of the art and literature of Greece (though with its corruptions and

stultification as well), and for the rest I think the world owes them

little but its curse, unless indeed we must accept them as a terrible

example of over-organisation. Of their state one may say what one of

their poets said of their individual citizens, when they were sunk in

their well-earned degradation, that for the sake of life they cast away

the reasons for living.

Part 2

But further, you must not fail to remember that the aspirations and

nobility of sacrifice of the ancient city life were for [a] limited

class only. In the old tribal life the slaves were not an important

class, and also had easements, and even a kind of position which we do

not associate with slave life, scarcely even with serfdom; as one may

see in Homer, who, writing at a time when the tribal society was rapidly

merging into city-life, gives us, for example, such a picture of a slave

as Eumœus, who had at any rate plenty of pigs to eat, and also had a

slave of his own “bought with his own wealth.” But as the power of

production increased and commerce with it, such laziness and pieces of

unthrift went out of fashion, and though when a slave was valuable as a

grammarian, a schoolmaster, an astronomer, or what not, his position was

not intolerable; yet the general condition of slaves is best indicated

by such facts as that they could not contract marriage, their evidence

in a law case could only be taken under torture, and so forth. Among the

Romans the idea of slavery was understood according to the pitiless

logic characteristic of that people, e.g., the debtor when delivered

over to his creditors as a slave, could be divided among them in the

most literal manner; they could cut him up in pieces and carry away each

his dividend to do what they pleased with.

The equality, therefore, of the classical period, that splendid ideal of

equality of duties and rights, only applied to the freemen of the clan

as in the earlier times; but, as aforesaid, those outside the pale of

that equality were of much more importance than they had been. At first,

both in Greece and Rome, a great deal of the field-work was done by the

freemen; the family were only helped in it by the slaves. Also a great

deal of the handicraft was done either by poor free citizens, who could

not afford to possess slaves, or by the strangers (metœci), who had no

political rights, but were nobody’s property; though even then the great

mass of production was performed by the man or woman out of the

labour-market, in which the selling of a human being was more obvious

than it is at present. But as society in general grew richer, and the

occupations fell more and more under the division of labour system,

slave labour increased very much, till in the last days of the Roman

republic the proportions of slave to free labour relatively to the

handicrafts and agriculture had quite changed. The land, the ownership

of which had been common in the early days, and the use divided among

the citizens, had now got into the hands of big and very big landlords,

who cultivated them wholly by slave-labour, superintendence and all, the

livelihood being doled out to these poor devils on strict commercial

principles, such as regulate the feed of a horse or cow, or an English

labouring man. The despair of men so treated shook the Roman State in

one tremendous slave-mutiny, that of Spartacus, and tormented society

for centuries in countless minor mutinies by sea and land, till in the

novels of the later Græco-Roman civilisation (which are doubtless mere

imitations of earlier works), adventures with organised bands of

brigands and pirates form the stock incidents of the tale.

All this had been developing from the hey-day of Greek civilisation, but

it did not blossom fully till the rise and growth of a monied

middle-class in Rome had exaggerated and confirmed all the evils that

were sure to be born out of a system of privileged freemen, who as they

got richer got idler and more corrupt, and chattel-slaves, who as their

masters got more corrupt, lost more and more of the alleviations of

their lot which they had in earlier times; probably because their

masters worked with them and lived pretty hardly like themselves, and

could feel that instinctive sympathy which fellowship in labour instils

into a man. Indeed, that loose easy-going generosity, that good-nature,

in a word, of which there are indications in the Homeric poems, and

which is found in fuller measure though in a more brutal form in the old

English Tory squire ideal, you must not expect to find in the highly

cultivated Greek citizen, who was mostly a prig; or in the energetic

public-spirited Roman, who was mainly a jailer.

By the time I have been speaking of, Roman civilised society had come to

be composed in the main of a privileged class of very rich men, whose

business was war, politics and pleasure; and money-making as an

instrument of these enjoyments; of their hangers-on forming a vast

parasitical army; of a huge population of miserable slaves; and of

another population of free men (so-called) kept alive by doles of food,

and contented with peoples palaces in the form of theatrical and

gladiatorial shows. That is, the free citizen had become an idler,

either a rich luxurious one, or a pauper, and the work was done by men

under the most obvious form of compulsion.

Thus was classical society, founded on the corruption of the society of

the tribes by the institution of private property, brought to a

dead-lock, the history of which is indeed a dreary page of the world’s

story. Art and literature are not forgotten, not buried, but for want of

courage and invention are allowed to walk about like galvanised corpses

of what was once so gloriously alive. Virtue? Does it exist at all? In

high places there is none of it, nay, not even a sense of the lack of

it. Virtue is to be found only in such places as the ranks of wild

sectaries, outcasts from society. Warlike heroism? Time was when

Hannibal a conqueror beset the city, and the stout-hearted citizens

coolly bought and sold the use of the land he encamped on, and the

greatest general that the world has seen drew off hopeless. Time was

again and a Gothic chief lay before Rome preparing for its storm, and

his estimate of the valour of the Roman citizens when the envoys

appealed to his prudence and asked him not to drive such a huge

population to despair, was given in the words “The thicker the hay, the

easier to mow.” In short, virtue had been used for acquiring power and

riches; the bargain had been made, the riches spent, and the virtue

gone; nothing was left. So it has been, so it will be, while violence

and greed are the foundations of prosperity.

Such was the result of the organisation of Rome. If the ancient

civilisation had been alone in the world then, if there had been nothing

strong and progressive outside the world of civilisation, as is now the

case, what would have happened? Who can say? Probably a more complete

break up than that which followed on the downfall of Rome. As it was the

world was delivered from its deadlock by the advent of the tribes of the

North and the East, who were, when the Romans first showed consciousness

of them other than by meeting them in battle, as specially in the pages

of Tacitus, in a condition not differing much from that of the Latins

themselves when they first began to wall round the hills beside the

Tiber. They were, in fact, in their later days of tribal society. The

story of the way in which they over-ran the empire and furnished fresh

blood to its worn-out population is well known enough. I can only wish

that we had the story as told by the conquerors to set beside the

naturally querulous one of the conquered, who, of course, did not like

the process of their being improved out of existence. The story would

then have been less empty of local and individual interest than it is

now. In any case, however, the broad facts remain, which resolve

themselves at last in the foundation of the feudal system; which was, in

the main, the development of the customs of the Celtic, Teutonic, and

Gothic tribes, customs which differed little from each other, and not

much from those of the classical peoples before their development of the

city and its life. In all parts of Europe remote from the influence of

Rome this development was simple and traceable enough, but where the

Germanic and Celtic races took the place of the Roman dominion and

colonies, it was natural enough that they should wear the dress, so to

say, of the older institutions, which in many cases they never quite

shook off, though in essence they were everywhere the same.

The Teutonic and Gothic invaders of the empire had not got to the stage

of city life, and did in fact miss that stage altogether. The feudal

system was based not on the city and its wards, urban and rural, as was

the case in ancient society, but on the country district, the manor and

its townships. When our Anglo-Saxon forefathers first conquered

Romanised Britain, they did not know what to do with the cities they

won; they let them lie in ruins, and went to live down the dales on the

borders of the streams in their homesteads, just as their ancestors had

done in the clearings of the great central forest of Europe.

Part 3

In these country districts, both in England and elsewhere, they held for

a long time to many of their old tribal customs; the jury of neighbours;

frank-pledge, or the responsibility of the district for the conduct of

its dwellers; the oath of compurgation; the courts in the open-air; the

folk-motes of all the freemen meeting directly (not by delegates) and

armed in token of their freedom. Over all this, which still existed in

the beginning of feudalism, and never quite disappeared until its wane,

the regular feudal system was super-imposed. Serfdom took the place of

thralldom; the King and his house-carles, or private body-guard, gave

way to the King the head of the conquering tribe, who was the vicegerent

of God, and granted the holding of lands to his tribesmen on condition

of service from them, many of whom in their turn granted lands to others

on similar terms; the performance of certain duties or service in return

for the undisturbed holding of land, and having in consequence a

definite recognised position, being the essence of mediaeval society. I

may remark in passing that the theory of property is quite different

from that of our own days, in which the holding of property has been

changed into a definite ownership which has no duties attached to it.

Now, I ask you to understand that the attainment of position or status,

was the one aspiration of those who were in an inferior position during

the Middle Ages. Even the serfs, many of whom at first were not very

distinguishable from mere chattel-slaves, gained status by becoming

adscripti glebae, men attached to the manor on which they lived, and

under the protection of its lord, to whom they had to render certain

definite services in return; and there was a tendency from quite early

days for these serfs to raise their position by becoming tenants of the

lord of the manor, and also by their individually getting themselves

received into a free town, and so emancipating themselves from

individual service. The mention of this last incident calls my attention

to the other members of the mediaeval hierarchy, the Free Towns and the

Guilds, who lay between the two poles of the landed nobility and their

serfs. And you must remember that though the development of these took

place somewhat late in the Middle Ages, they were both of them in

existence from its very first days, when the tribes first reconstituted

society after the break-up of the Roman Empire. Indeed, the growth of

the free towns resembled in many respects the growth of Rome in her

first days. The germs of them were always the agricultural district,

inhabited by such and such a clan or tribe, whose members in early days

were, or professed to be, akin to each other by blood, and held at least

their land in common. Now in such and such a case this clan of freemen

would gather to some more convenient part of their hundred, or district,

and would fence it to protect their houses and crafts, and so population

would grow thicker there; and they would hold a market there, and

attract to them traders and men who needed protection for their

handicrafts, though these would mostly be people outside the clan,

unfree men, taking no part in the administration of the place.

Thus there grew up gradually classes of privileged and unprivileged

within the towns, the former being the corporations of them, who, as the

feudal system grew, got their status recognised by the king or

over-lord, and who little by little freed themselves from the services,

tolls, and restrictions which the neighbouring military chief had

managed to enmesh them in as they passed out of their tribal freedom

into the feudal power. This freedom they principally bought from their

feudal lord, for their production was always expanding, since they were

in the main communities of workers; whereas the revenue of the lord

could not expand much, as it depended on the services of his serfs,

which were limited by the customs of his manors. Remember once for all,

that capitalism was unknown in those days, and the nobles could not live

by rack-rent and interest, which in these days procure them such

enormous incomes. So the towns, as their production expanded, bought

their privileges with money down, and began to grow wealthy and

powerful, and therewithal the ruling bodies in them, the corporations,

who now represented the freemen of the clan, began to be corrupt and

oppressive. They were no longer workmen, but were grown into a municipal

aristocracy, very exclusive and mainly hereditary. But at this point

these were met by the other associations I have named, the Guilds, which

had been growing up under them all this while.

I have said that the guilds existed from the earliest period of the

Middle Ages. I might have gone further, and pointed out their analogy to

the free towns in this respect that they were not unknown to classical

antiquity. In the early days of Rome, and before the labour of the free

artisan was swamped by the enormous flood of slave-labour, it flourished

in that city. In fact, it seems to me that these guilds are an answer to

the imperative claim for useful association which human nature makes; as

one form of society which once served its purpose duly fails men, they

are forced to form others, even while the old form exists and has become

mere authority and an instrument of oppression. The old kinship clan

certainly grew together for mutual protection and help of a band of

equals; as that degenerated into a mere privileged caste of nobles, and

became worse than useless for its original purpose, men formed other

associations that had no bond of kindred, but a bond of mutual interest

amidst the disorder of a rough period of transition. And once more we

come across the guilds in quite early days of the new European society,

and it is remarkable how much the purposes of these early guilds answer

to those of the primitive kindred clan. To a great extent they were what

we should now call benefit societies: they engaged to redeem their

members from captivity; to set them up in business again if they were

ruined; to pay their fines if they came into the clutch of the law. They

were also clubs for good fellowship, and also (which again makes their

analogy to the old clans the closer) drew their members together by the

bond of religion, providing the sacrificial feast while our fore-fathers

were still heathen, and paying for masses for the souls of their members

when Christianity had become the popular religion; and there are

instances of the chief work being defence by the strong hand, as in the

case of protection against the Norse pirates in the tenth century. In

short, it may well be said that from the first the history of the guilds

is the true history of the Middle Ages. And we will remember, too, that

they were in their early days in direct opposition to the authority of

the period, which saw in them, as it was well warranted in doing, a

threat of rebellious progress against the robbery of the poor and

industrious by the rich and idle. In the Middle Ages, apart from those

old Roman guilds, which were of handicraftsmen, this was the first

character which the guilds took; leagues of the individually powerless

freemen against the accidents of oppression, legal and illegal, held

together by a religious bond according to the custom of the times.

Part 4

To these about the eleventh century were superadded another set of

guilds, whose main object was the protection of trade, and which soon

became powerful, and establishing themselves in the towns, drew together

with the corporations, the freemen of the towns, and were fused with

them. They shared in the degeneration of the municipal aristocracies,

which reached its height in the beginning of the thirteenth century, and

with them were attacked by the third and last set of guilds, whose

office was the organization and protection of the handicrafts. These of

course had been growing up with the growth of the towns, and the

increasing capacity for production, and at the time I mention were

organized pretty completely, and embraced, I think, the whole of the

handicrafts.

The greater part of the thirteenth century was taken up by the struggle

between these new and quite democratic guilds, which were entirely

composed of workmen; that struggle was partly a peaceable one. The

municipalities could not quite keep the guilds from all participation in

the government of the towns; their officers gradually crept into the

corporations, and they began to influence the administration; but this

peaceful revolution was supplemented by very hard fighting, especially

in the north of Germany. The upshot of this double struggle was the

complete victory of the workmen over the municipal aristocracies, and by

the end of the thirteenth century the craft guilds, who no doubt had

been fostered all along by the increasing productivity of labour, had

the towns entirely in their power; but, although the municipal

aristocracy had lost its privileged official position, the old families

had not lost all their influence, and still formed a kind of

middle-class nobility; this is exemplified clearly enough by the

incidents in the struggle between the great town of Ghent and its feudal

superior, the Earl of Flanders, in which men like James Van Artavelde

and his sons clearly had a position akin to that of powerful rich men at

the present day. The old struggle also was not forgotten; throughout the

men of the mean crafts are on the revolutionary side; while the great

crafts, led by the mariners, i.e., the shippers, merchants, and so on,

are loyalists.

This victory of the handicraftsmen brings us to the apex of the Middle

Ages. Let us therefore stop a little to contrast the condition of labour

at that period with its condition under the height of the classical

period, and see what it has gained. The classical period gives us a

class of privileged persons actually idle as far as any good purpose

goes, supporting a huge class of parasites, and an enormous pauper

population fed on charity, and all this founded on the labour of mere

chattel slaves, who were fed, clothed and housed according to the

convenience of their owners, just as beasts of burden were, but whom

they had to buy with hard cash just as they had their horses and mules.

There was a certain amount of labour done by freemen, or non-slaves

rather, but that did not come to much, and I think we may class these

few freemen among the parasites of the rich. The government of all this

was aristocratic at first (tempered by the money-bag aristocracy), and

at last mere absolutism founded on tax-gathering.

In the fully developed Middle Ages, on the other hand, we have a

privileged class of land-holders deduced from the freemen of the

conquering tribe, absolutely idle, supported by their serfs, who for

their part are somewhat speedily turning into tenants, and so laying

part of the foundations of the later middle-class. Between these two

classes, which in the beginning of the Middle Ages were the essential

constituents of society, lies the great body of the craftsmen, now

gathered into towns administered by themselves, oppressed always, no

doubt, legally by taxes, and often illegally by war on the part of the

nobles, but free in their work except for such regulations as they have

imposed on themselves, and the object of which in the main was the

equitable distribution of employment, and the reward of employment

throughout their whole body. Capitalism does not exist at this time;

there is no great all-embracing world-market; production is for the

supply of the neighbourhood, and only the surplus of it ever goes a

dozen miles from the door of the worker. It must be added that every

freeman has the use of land to support himself on, so that he does not

depend on the caprice of the market for his bare necessities, and

whether employer or employed, he neither sells himself, nor buys others,

in the labour market under the rule of competition, but exchanges labour

for labour directly with his neighbour, man to man and hand to hand.

Now, you will probably agree with me in thinking that this was a much

better state of things for the worker than his condition under what have

been called the “free peoples of antiquity,” but whose freedom was

confined to the rich and powerful. One other thing I note in this

contrast, that whereas in the ancient world, the intelligence, the high

mental qualities, which have made the ancient days so famous, came from

the idle classes, who were in good sooth an aristocracy of intellect as

well as of position, in the Middle Ages, the intelligence lay with the

great craftsmen class, — and that again, I think, was a decided

advantage, both for them and for us; since it has given us, amongst

other treasures not so famous, but scarcely less glorious, the poems of

Shakespeare.

Now, on this high tide of mediaeval life supervened two things: the

Black Death, and the gradual decay of the guilds, both of which got the

times ready for the next great change in the condition of labour. I will

say little about the first, space not serving for it. I will only remark

first, that the Statute of Labourers of Edward III, which was one

consequence of it, and which has been so useful to enquirers into the

condition of labour at that time, represents in the account of wages and

labour-hours to be drawn from it, the state of things before the

terrible plague, not after it, since it was avowedly enacted against the

labourers in order to lower their wages to the standard of reward before

the Black Death.

Furthermore, I must say that all antiquarians must be fully conscious of

the decline in art that took place in Northern Europe, and in England

especially, after the reign of Edward III. Before the middle of the

fourteenth century the English were in these matters abreast with, and

in some matters ahead of, the Italians, and in the art of architecture

especially, produced works which have never been surpassed, and seldom

equalled. By the end of the fifteenth century our arts had for the most

part become rude, unfinished and barbarous, and lacking altogether in

that self-respect and confidence which the arts are always full of in

their fine periods.

Looking carefully at the gradual change, I conclude that the Black Death

was answerable for some of this degradation, but that the main part of

it was the natural consequence of the great change which was coming over

society. For during the next century, a new plague invaded Europe,

compared with which the slaughter of the Black Death was but a trifle.

That plague was the pest of Commercialism; capitalism aided by

bureaucracy and nationalism, began to show itself, and took away from

labour the hope of a happy life on the earth.

At the end of the fourteenth century, there were no journeymen in the

guilds; every worker in them was certain to become a master if he only

did his duty fairly; and the master was not the master in our sense of

the word, he was the man who had learned his craft thoroughly, and could

teach the apprentices their business, and all sorts of restrictions were

laid on him to prevent him becoming a capitalist, i.e., forcing men as

good as himself to pay him for his privilege of providing them with

work. But in the early days of the fifteenth century the journeyman

began to appear; there were men in the workshops who were known as

“servants,” and, who though necessarily affiliated to the guild, and

working under its regulations, would never become crafts-masters. They

were few and unimportant enough, but they grew in numbers, till, e.g.,

about 1480 the non-guildsmen of the merchant-tailors in London attempted

to form a guild under the old craft guild, just as those latter had

formed their guilds under the trades guilds. In this attempt they

failed, showing thereby how the times were changing, and how employment

for profit was raising its hideous head. This falling of the crafts

guilds from their old simplicity of equality, was doubtless a token

rather than a cause of the change. Capitalism was advancing from other

directions. The productivity of labour was increasing, though slowly;

more wealth was being produced, and men’s greedy desires grew with it.

The landed nobility began to see how they might recover their losses in

war, and become as rich in relation to other people as they had been

when the latter were so poor; and they were no longer contented, as they

once were obliged to be, to live on the rents of their land, whether

those rents were the enforced service of serfs, or the money rent of

tenants, both limited by the custom of the manor. The Peasants Rebellion

in England had foiled them in their attempt to rack-rent their tenants,

growing prosperous, by forcing them to pay serfs’ services on villeinage

tenures as well as tenant’s rent. But no matter; in spite of the high

wages and comfort of the craftsmen and yeomen, they were the powerful

people, since they were the makers and interpreters of the laws, and

since the meetings round the Shire Oak and the folkmotes of the freemen

of the Hundred, and other such direct local assemblies, had been

swallowed up in the representative assembly, the central parliament, the

King’s taxing machine. So they set to work to steal, not a purse here,

or a bale of goods there, or the tolls of a market in another place; but

the very life and soul of the community, the land of the country, which

was of the more importance, as in those days no direct rent could be got

out of anything save the land. They got the yeomen and tenants off the

land by one means or another; legal quibbling, direct cheating,

down-right violence; and so got hold of the lands and used their

produce, not for the livelihood of themselves and their retainers, but

for profit. The land of England, such of it as was used for cultivation,

had been mostly tillage where tillage was profitable; it was the

business of the land thieves to turn this tillage into pasture for the

sake of the sheep, i.e., the wool for exportation. This game not only

drove the yeoman and tenant off the land, but the labourer also, since,

as More says “Many sheep and one shepherd now take the place of many

families.” As a result, not only was a pauper population created, but

the towns were flooded by crowds of the new free labourers, whom the

guilds, grown corrupt, were ready to receive as journeymen. The

huckstering landlord and the capitalist farmer drove the workman into

the hands of the new manufacturing capitalist, and a middle-class of

employers of labour was created, the chief business of whose fathers was

to resist the rich, and the business of whose sons was to oppress the

poor.

Part 5

Thus fell the Society of the Middle Ages, by Capitalism establishing

itself on the ruins of Feudality, and the rise of a middle-class who

were either parasites of the nobility, themselves become commercial,

trading on the grossest monopolies, and exacting rack-rent, and

practically doing the state no service — partly parasites of the

nobility, or partly employers living on the profit wrung out of workmen

employed at a very low rate of wages. I have been giving the story of

the change as it happened in England. On the Continent the divorce of

the people from the land was not so sudden or complete, I think because

there was less resistance possible to the centralised bureaucracy here

than on the Continent. There, on the other hand, the rise of definite

nations with stiff political demarcations gave rise to most horrible

wars, which reduced the peasants to the last stage of misery, hampered

new-born commerce, and in the long run ruined the land-owning

aristocracy, and at last made the French Revolution both possible and

necessary. It is no exaggeration to say that Germany is only now within

the last twenty years recovering from the Thirty Years War which went on

at the end of the sixteenth and beginning of the seventeenth centuries.

But with the birth of capitalism and the world-market, the relative

importance of agriculture and manufacture began to alter; and that again

especially in England, a country so rich in coal and minerals, and so

well furnished with harbours on all sides. The new-born power of making

profit out of the employment of handicraftsmen had to be exercised and

developed. The craftsmen were in a changed position; they had been

completely masters of their own work with other resources, which forbade

the work mastering them; they were so no longer; they were working for

other people, driven by competition to sell themselves at a poor price

in the market. In short, they had become wage-slaves; but they were

still handicraftsmen working in an isolated way. They were not being

made the most of, and could only be the instruments of a timid scanty

commerce. If they could have remained thus I think that they would have

been less degraded then they became afterwards, and are now; but then

the last word of progress would have been said, the hope of revolution

would never have arisen.

What happened was very different. Capitalism was no sooner born than she

was forced to sow the seed of her decay and final destruction; she was

forced to develope [sic] the power of Labour to the utmost; that was

indeed her work. The mechanical invention of man had lain dormant since

the early days that had invented the plough, the cart, the row-boat, and

the simple machines that help man’s labour and do not supersede it, such

as the grist-mill, the potter’s wheel, the lathe, the simple loom, the

crane, etc.; that invention was now to wake up, but not very suddenly;

the fuller organisation of handicraft was to precede its abolition. I

say when Capitalism began to grow towards manhood at the end of the

sixteenth century, production was wholly by handicraft little organised.

The work of the seventeenth century was that gradual organisation by

means of the division of labour. In handicraft (supposing a man to take

no pleasure in his work, to be no artist) the single worker’s whole

intelligence is wasted on a piece of commonplace goods; a small part of

that intelligence will suffice, if the whole of some one else’s

intelligence is employed in organising. Therefore, set him, the single

man, at doing one small portion of that work, and you can soon dispense

with almost all his intelligence, while at the same time you will

quicken the habit of his hand, his mechanical power, prodigiously; in

short, you will at last make of him a very delicate machine, or part of

a machine, for performing the small piece of work you apportion to him;

but you must take care that the whole machine of him and his fellows

must be properly built up. This was the work of the seventeenth century.

In the eighteenth it was complete, and the unit of labour was no longer

a single man but a group of men.

Commerce was now, one would think, as well provided as she needed to be;

but happily she could not stop there, or there would still have been no

revolution possible for us. Now, indeed, she stirred up the sleeping

invention of man, and with the latter half of the eighteenth century

began that marvellous series of inventions, which one would have thought

should have set mankind free from the greater part of his labour, but

which, as it is, has done, on the face of it, little more than make a

new and enormously rich middle-class, and multiply the working

population many times over in order to provide them with due

wage-slaves, who work not less, but more than they did in the days

before the organisation of labour, and get not higher wages, but lower

for their more burdensome labour.

My briefly told tale is over now, for I need not go through the

often-told story of the fly-shuttle, the spinning jenny, the

steam-engine, the power-loom, and the rest of it. I will only remark

that the last development of machinery is to make the factory itself the

machine, of which these wonderful machines, and the men that manage them

(the most wonderful of all) are only parts. There remains only on this

side of human life, production to wit, one thing to do as long as

machine production lasts (which I prophecy will not be for ever). That

one thing is this: The machines were invented that some men might work

harder and others softer than they used to do, and they have well

fulfilled their purpose; but though they have in that process seized

hold of the bodies of the hard-working ones, the wage-slaves, though the

factory has their bodies in its grip, it has not got hold of their

intelligence, and does not want it, nay, sedulously keeps it out.

Suppose that intelligence to wake up and to say, The hard work and the

soft work, let us no longer keep these two separate for two classes of

men, but throw them together and divide them equally amongst all, so

that there should be no classes! In that case would not life in general,

the only holy and sacred thing we know, be purified and made far holier

by taking away from it the sorrow and misery that come of anxious

seeking for toil, and the need for accepting the sickening burden.

Surely that is so. Surely there is nothing in the machines themselves

and the invention of man which created them, that they should forbid the

true use of them, the lightening the burden of human labour.

That is what we Socialists under the machine and factory system are

striving for at present, leaving the consideration of what is to be done

to the machines and factories to future ages, who will be free to

consider it, as we are not. Freedom first at any price, and then if

possible happiness, which to my mind would be the certain result of

freedom. Or are we free? I have told you what was the condition of the

civilised world in the days of the late Roman Republic, and the

Absolutist Empire which followed it. What is its condition now that we

have gone through chattel-slavery and serfdom to wage-slavery? It can be

told in nearly the same words.

A privileged class partly composed of a landed nobility, partly of a

money-bag aristocracy; a parasite class, ministering to their pleasures

and their corruption, drinking of their cup, eating of their dish,

flattering them and flattered by them but despised by them, and (woe is

me!) sharing in their crime of living on the misery of the poor. And

those by whose labour they live? A huge population of miserable and

hopeless labourers, to whom are superadded a crowd of paupers, far less

joyous than the old Roman ones, fed by the fears, the remorse — the

charity we call it — of the rich; and a few, a very few, free workmen,

who as they work not for the workers, but the idle, must be turned back

again to herd with the crowd of parasites aforesaid. Who can dare to say

that this is not true of our society? And how does it differ from that

of Roman corruption? Can its end be otherwise then — or worse?

Remember this, that in the days of that Roman corruption there was

valiancy outside it which was ready to help the then world by

destruction and new life combined; its enemies were the friends of the

world, and were as good in their way as the early classical peoples had

been in theirs, and I say they were outside that society, but at hand

for its regeneration. All that the last two thousand years have used up;

there is nothing outside civilisation that we can turn to for new birth;

whatever there is to help us must come from within.

How are we to get at that? you will say. The answer to that question is

the fact that we admit that the workers of to-day are wage-slaves. Those

that feel themselves slaves must have been driven to desire freedom.

But, again, what is the freedom which we desire? For the word has been

used so often that men have forgotten its meaning. I think the answer is

the freedom to develope our capacities to the utmost without injuring

our neighbours. And how can that be done? By each of us working for the

welfare of the whole of which we each form a part, and feeling sure that

only so can we each of us fare well. Shall we not then have to give up a

great deal in order to reach this point? Yes, we who are trying to bring

people to that point will have to, but when people have reached it,

they, when Socialism is realised, will turn round and find that their

loss has only been imaginary. The rich man will have lost riches, i.e.,

dominion over others, and find that he is happy; the intellectual man

will have given up his claim to be worshipped by the masses, and will

find that he is understood by them and loved by them — and the poor man,

what has he to give up? He will have to give up his chance of becoming

rich — a valuable possession truly — and he will find that he is not

rich, but wealthy; that is, that he has whatever a man healthy in mind

and body can wish for, and that poverty has become an evil dream but

half remembered.

In short, even now, while the realisation of Socialism, though it is

already going on, is neither desired nor understood by most men, the

mere breath and rumour of its coming can at least hold out to true men

who will join our ranks one gift at least — that they shall be glad to

live and not afraid to die. And is that not a wonderful contrast to the

spirit of the life of those who are still living placidly, because

ignorantly, amidst the dishonesty of our present society? wherein how

many there are, and those not always the poorest or most ignorant, but

men of culture, men of genius, who do at once hate life and fear death.

Friends, join us in helping to throw off this bugbear, so that you may

be no longer wage-slaves or their masters, or their masters’ parasites.

So shall we be our own Goths, and at whatever cost break up again the

new tyrannous Empire of Capitalism.