đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș anarcho-on-paul-krugman.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 07:24:18. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-07-09)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: On Paul Krugman Author: Anarcho Date: October 15, 2008 Language: en Topics: Paul Krugman, economics, liberalism Source: Retrieved on 28th January 2021 from https://anarchism.pageabode.com/?p=161 Notes: A few comments on Paul Krugman winning the so-called Nobel Prize for Economics. He may be left-of-centre and a Keynesian, but his economics are sadly very much neo-classical in nature.
As should be well known by now, Paul Krugman won this yearâs (non-)Nobel
prize in economics for his work on trade theory.
Krugman is pretty much your standard neo-classical Keynesian, but he is
left-of-centre and since the 2000 election campaign has spent much time
exposing struggle the Bush Administration and its enablers. For example,
while in the 1990s he refuted right-wing attempts to show that
inequality was not rising in America while thinking that nothing could
really be done about it, in the 2000s he has raised addressing this
issue to forefront.
Unsurprisingly, given this, the awarding of the prize has proved some
right-winger to proclaim him as a âleft-wing hackâ and an
âanti-capitalistâ, even a âsocialistâ, and whinge about the political
biases of the Swedish Central Bank â obviously only (non-)Nobel prizes
to right-wingers count! This gnashing of teeth by the right has,
rightly, been a source of much amusement on the left.
Personally, I can think of worse people to give it too â and so have the
Swedes. So we have Milton Friedman and von Hayek âhonouredâ in the 1970s
while Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor and Michal Kalecki were ignored
(but, then, they all rejected neo-classical economics and where, to
varying degrees, socialists). Kaldor, for example, destroyed von Hayekâs
business cycle theory (what he ostensibly got the prize for) twice in
the 1930s, before moving on to be the scourge of Friedmanâs Monetarism.
Kalecki only managed to independently develop the key concepts of Keynes
General Theory and published first. Robinson exposed key problems with
neo-classical economics, not least the problems with marginal
productivity theory. A few years back, they gave it to Edmund Phelps
whose ideas have been used to tame the working class via his notion of
the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (they should have
given it to Karl Marx, as it clearly echoed his analysis, or Kalecki who
predicted the impact of full employment in eroding capitalist power in
the workplace).
In terms of his trade theory work, it is rooted in the (flawed)
neo-classical mainstream. As Steve Keen noted in passing, âthe
representative agent was a kludge invented ... to get around the problem
that, in general, the preferences of individuals could not be aggregated
... representative agent macroeconomics amounts to assuming that the
economy consists of a single individual, producing and consuming a
single commodity. However complex might be the reasoning used by such
aficionados as Paul Krugman, the realm of applicability of this theory
is that of Robinson Crusoe, living off coconuts before the arrival of
Man Friday.â (Debunking Economics, p. 212). Only radical economist
Stephen A. Marglin (in his new recent book The Dismal Science), as far
as I am aware, has presented a thought experiment on how free trade
would impact on an economy with classes and it is worth reading.
Given how free trade based on Ricardoâs theory of comparative advantage
is one of the most popular ideological positions of mainstream
economics, it may come as a surprise how few (none!) countries have
industrialised by means of it (and Iâm including Hong Kong). In this,
the relatively unknown Federick List has been repeatedly proven to be
right. As such, Krugmanâs work, however innovatory it is, is building
upon weak foundations.
Krugman really is pretty much a mainstream neo-classical economist. This
can be seen when he notes in his introduction to economic textbook âthe
prevalence of oligopolyâ and admits it âis far more common than either
perfect competition or monopoly.â However, âthe analysis of oligopoly
turns out to present some puzzles for which they is no easy solutionâ as
âthe analysis of oligopoly is far more difficult and messy than that of
perfect competition.â Why? âWhen we try to analyse oligopoly, the
economists usual way of thinking â asking how self-interested
individuals would behave, then analysing their interaction â does not
work as well as we might hope.â Rest assured, though, there is not need
to reconsider the âusual wayâ of economic analysis to allow it to
analyse something as marginal as the most common market form for, by
luck, âthe industry behaves âalmostâ as if it were perfectly
competitive.â (Paul Krugman and Robin Wells, Economics, p. 383, p. 365
and p. 383) Which is handy, to say the least.
Which brings me to why I decided to write this blog entry. A few years
ago, I read Krugmanâs dismissive review of William B. Greiderâs One
World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism (The
Accidental Theorist). He uses it to âillustrate a paradox: You canât do
serious economics unless you are willing to be playful. Economic theory
is not a collection of dictums laid down by pompous authority figures.
Mainly, it is a menagerie of thought experiments â parables, if you like
â that are intended to capture the logic of economic processes in a
simplified way.â And he presents one:
âImagine an economy that produces only two things: hot dogs and buns.
Consumers in this economy insist that every hot dog come with a bun, and
vice versa. And labor is the only input to production ... Suppose that
our economy initially employs 120 million workers, which corresponds
more or less to full employment ... Now, suppose that improved
technology allows a worker to produce a hot dog in one day rather than
two. And suppose that the economy makes use of this increased
productivity to increase consumption ... This requires some reallocation
of labor, with only 40 million workers now producing hot dogs, 80
million producing buns.
âThen a famous journalist arrives on the scene. He takes a look at
recent history and declares that something terrible has happened: Twenty
million hot-dog jobs have been destroyed. When he looks deeper into the
matter, he discovers that the output of hot dogs has actually risen 33
percent, yet employment has declined 33 percent ... Global capitalism,
in short, is hurtling toward crisis. He writes up his alarming
conclusions in a 473-page book; full of startling facts ... and
punctuated with occasional barbed remarks about the blinkered vision of
conventional economists ...
âMeanwhile, economists are a bit bemused, because they canât quite
understand his point. Yes, technological change has led to a shift in
the industrial structure of employment. But there has been no net job
loss ... In our hypothetical economy it is â or should be â obvious that
reducing the number of workers it takes to make a hot dog reduces the
number of jobs in the hot-dog sector but creates an equal number in the
bun sector, and vice versa.â
From this parable, this thought experiment, Krugman draws the obvious
conclusion that technological change need not be feared, that the market
will ensure that workers are redeployed to new industries. He dismisses
the objection that this âthought experiment [is] too simple to tell us
anything about the real worldâ by arguing that âif for âhot dogsâ you
substitute âmanufacturesâ and for âbunsâ you substitute âservices,â my
story actually looks quite a lot like the history of the U.S. economy
over the past generation.â He proclaims that Greiderâs mistake was
âsystematically cut[ting] himself off from the kind of advice and
criticism that could have saved him from himself. His acknowledgements
conspicuously do not include any competent economists ... To test-drive
an idea with seemingly trivial thought experiments, with hypothetical
stories about simplified economies producing hot dogs and buns, would be
beneath his dignity. And it is precisely because he is so serious that
his ideas are so foolish.â Hence the conclusion: âIt is an insight that
you can gain only by playing with hypothetical economies â by engaging
in thought experiments.â
I was not convinced at all when I first read this a few years back. I
still reject it and since Krugman is in the news, I thought now would be
a good time to actually write it down. I do not deny the importance of
thought experiments and simplified models, but if you simplify reality
too much then any conclusions to be drawn from the experiment will be
deeply flawed. Simply put, an unrealistic model will produce misleading
results.
My objections lie in the obvious fact that Krugmanâs little story
ignores time, class and market power. This is not that unexpected, given
that neo-classical economics was developed to combat socialist economic
analysis and so focused on individuals rather than institutions and
social relationships. Instead of the classical theory of value, which
was utilised to show the dynamics of an economy over time (and
inadvertently showed that labour was exploited by capital),
neo-classical economics started with a fixed amount of goods and so took
a snapshot of the economy as its starting point. With production
ignored, price was determined by effective demand (something classical
economics did not deny happened in the short term). So, neo-classical
economics is based on ignoring time â at best it compares two different
snapshots while ignoring what happened in between.
This impacts into the next two ignored factors, class and market power.
Krugmanâs model, as is clear, is based on workers with no mention of
bosses. The assumption is that a capitalist economy is one of
self-employment, one without capitalists! Given that there are classes,
with returns to both capital and labour, in any real capitalist economy,
this simplification becomes simply misleading. Productivity gains,
regardless of neo-classical assumptions, need not be shared equally
between classes. There is a struggle over who gets what.
This brings me to my next objection: the ignoring of market power. Mass
unemployment in an economy will mean that employed workers will be
fearful of standing up to their bosses. They will be well aware that
there are others waiting to take their jobs and, as a result, we would
expect wages to fall as well as ensuring that productivity growth
accumulates into the hands of their bosses (unsurprisingly, the evidence
is that unemployment coexists with low, not, high wages). This increase
in market power of the boss caused by unemployment would increase
inequality while making wages decrease or stagnate. Eventually, workers
in the affected sectors would find work elsewhere, but during the time
that took to happen all workers would have had their economic power
eroded, weakening unions, decoupling productivity growth from wage
growth and so on.
So, yes, over time employment would equalise over the two sectors of the
economy but the balance of class power, the levels of inequality within
the society and so would be fundamentally different. This is all ignored
by Krugmanâs simplistic model.
Krugman pointed to the âpast generationâ in American history. The
alternative model proposed here is, basically, exactly what did happen
in America (and elsewhere) since the 1970s. Ironically, Krugman laments
precisely these developments in his new book (The Conscience of a
Liberal). There is, he now argues, âno question that US tradeâ with
Third World countries âwidens inequalityâ and âreduces job opportunities
for less-skilled American workers.â (p. 135) Which is an improvement on
his previous orthodox defence of globalisation in the 1990s. He also
points to âchanges in institutions, such as the strength of labor
unionsâ (p. 136) as another factor in widening inequality, arguing that
the unions had a âdirect effectâ on equality by their own wage
agreements and an indirect one, as they âraised the wages of
less-well-paid workers moreâ as the union contracts were âreflected in
the labour market as a whole.â (p. 149) Significantly: âIf gains in
productivity had been evenly shared across the workforce, the typical
workerâs income would be about 35 percent higher now than it was in the
early seventies.â (p. 128) Instead, wealth has flooded upwards to the
top 10% (or even less).
As he said: âIn the end, of course, ideas must be tested against the
facts.â I know that in neo-classical economics time, power and class are
all ignored but they exist. Once these factors are taken into account,
Krugmanâs âJust-Soâ story can be seen for what it is. Particularly as
his own subsequent work can, in part, be used as evidence for another
thought-experiment which does not abstract from essential elements of
any real capitalist economy.
So if this award gets more people reading Krugmanâs exposures of the
Bush Junta and his well documented accounts of the explosion of
inequality in America then, I would suggest, it would be for the best.
Hopefully, though, they will see past the limitations of both his
(neo-classical rooted) economics and his New Deal-style politics to
something more radical in terms of both analysis and solutions to the
social question.