đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș carne-ross-the-leaderless-revolution.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 08:46:47. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-07-09)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: The Leaderless Revolution Author: Carne Ross Date: 2011 Language: en Topics: leaders, leadership, popular power, 21st century, revolution, anti-authoritarianism Source: Retrieved on 19th December 2020 from http://libgen.rs/book/index.php?md5=8877897B2AE16D60BD39F2FEE512DDBB
Things do not seem to be going as planned. The system is broken. Meant
to bring order, it foments instead disorder. We need something new.
The end of the Cold War was supposed to presage the triumph of democracy
and with it, stability. Globalization was supposed to launch everyone
upon an eternally rising wave of prosperity. Some called it âthe end of
history.â But history has instead opened another, unpredicted, chapter.
While the opening of markets in India and China has released hundreds of
millions from poverty, globalization has also triggered violent and
uncontrolled economic volatility. Trillions of dollars shift from asset
to asset (or from debt to debt), sometimes faster than a human can press
a computer keyâfor it is an algorithm that controls the trade. Banks and
whole countries crash, almost without warning. Meanwhile, the gap
between a tiny number of the very rich and everyone else has accelerated
rapidly, in every region and in every country.
The profits of this modern economy flow to a minuscule minority that
holds the wealth closely. Everyone elseâthe middle class and the
poorâhave seen their incomes stagnate over the last decade or so. And
stagnation in reality means decline, as food and energy prices, driven
by rising shortage, have risen faster and faster. And for those in the
bottom 10 percent, incomes have declined in absolute, as well as
relative, terms. Though they live cheek by jowl with the rich and share
the same cities, the poor are getting poorer. In New York City, one in
five children is dependent on food stamps for survival.
In every profession and trade, global competition means that jobs and
careers once thought of as safe are no longer. Industries that have
stood for generations can collapse in a few years. Only two classes can
now look forward to a secure retirement: the rich and those working for
government.
The promise of capitalism seems more and more hollow. As its benefits
are ever more unevenly shared, it has created a culture that cherishes
much that is worst in human nature. Too much modern work is demeaning or
humiliating, or simply boring. Little offers meaning.
In the exhausting yet often banal race to get ahead or at least to make
ends meet, there is little time for others, for the community that seems
ever more fractured, or for an ever more poisoned planet. Nature is no
more, there is only what we have made of it. As The Economist recently
put it, we live in the Anthropocene era: an Earth primarily formed by
man.
Despite the dismal familiarity of these problems, credible solutions are
hard to come by. Celebrities launch simplistic âsingle issueâ campaigns,
absurdly claiming that an e-mail to a representative will solve the
problem. Each new cohort of politicians offers to fix this malaise, but
they are less and less believed including, one suspects, by themselves
(for they too can sense the mounting unease). Indeed, the political
class now appears more part of the problem than the solution. Even
politicians now complain about âpoliticians.â
In Britain, politicians and media crow over the humbling of press baron
Rupert Murdoch, but barely admit that both estates were grossly
corrupted by him, and for decades. In Washington, needless political
bickering has managed to worsen Americaâs debt problemâand increase the
cost paid, eventually, by all Americans. âWashingtonâ has become
synonymous with ugly partisan argument and deadlock.
In democratic systems, it has become evident what is more obvious in
autocraciesâpower is monopolized by the powerful. In the U.S., corporate
lobbyists far outnumber legislators (there are now lobbyists for the
lobbying industry). Legislation is sometimes created simply for
political parties to extract rents from corporate interests. Big
business donates to all parties, careful to ensure that their interests
are protected whichever prevails. For it is still money that wins
elections, and it is still large corporations that contribute the most.
In the 2008 âcredit crunch,â irresponsible and untransparent lending by
banks and inadequate legislation (loosened by well-funded lobbying of
both U.S. parties) combined to wreak massive and lasting damage on the
world economy, affecting the poorest most of all. But despite this
disaster, there is little sign of effective rules, national as well as
global, judged by impartial experts as effective.
Banks lobby country by country to water down regulation, arguing that
national competitiveness will be underminedâeven though all the biggest
banks operate in many markets at once. And at the international level,
as so often is the case, governments are unable to agree on anything but
the lowest common denominator, and even then often fail to implement
itâas is clear with the so-called Basel III rules, which are claimed to
bring banks back under control. In another equally important forum,
after years of elaborate multitracked negotiations involving thousands
of delegates in hundreds of meetings, there remains little prospect of
international agreement on the necessary measures to limit carbon
emissions.
And of the mounting evidence of this fundamental ineffectiveness and
indeed corruption, the most striking piece of all is that the wealthy
pay less tax, proportionately, than the poor. Returns on investment,
such as hedge funds, are taxed at a far lower rate than the income tax
levied on ordinary wage earners. Striking too is that complaints about
this gross inequity are almost never to be heard in our supposedly
representative parliaments.
So what is to be done? Voting for someone different at the next election
seems a pathetically inadequate responseâand it is. In Manhattanâs
Zuccotti Park where the Occupy Wall Street protests are centered, few
are demanding different politicians or new laws. Instead, the protesters
are showing, by the nature of their movement, a new way: debates and
decisions that include everyone, a culture of collaboration and sharing,
and a belief that there are many, not one, changes necessary to make a
better world. No one claims the right to lead this movement: There are
many voices that want to be heard. But although Occupy Wall Street is a
sharp cry of anger echoed by many across the U.S., and indeed more
widely around the world, the protest alone will not be enough.
What is needed is a much more fundamental, wholly new method of doing
things. No longer should we look for change to emerge from untrusted
politicians, arguing in distant chambers. As turkeys will not vote for
Thanksgiving or Christmas, these institutions will not reform
themselves. We have to accept the painful reality that we can no longer
rely on government policy to solve our most deep-seated and intractable
problems, from climate change to social alienation. Instead, we need to
look to ourselves for the necessary action.
There are four simple ideas at the heart of The Leaderless Revolution.
Together, they suggest a radically different approach to conducting our
affairs.
The first is that in an increasingly interconnected system, such as the
world emerging in the twenty-first century, the action of one individual
or a small group can affect the whole system very rapidly. Imagine the
world as a sports stadium, where a âwaveâ can be started by just one
person, but quickly involves the whole crowd. Those most powerful are
right beside us; and weâin turnâare best placed to influence them. A
suicide bomber acts, assaults his enemy and recruits others all in one
horrible action: a technique with such effect that it has spread from
Sri Lanka to Lebanon, Iraq and Afghanistan, Bali, London and New York
within a few short years. But the same lesson is taught, with greater
force, by peaceful acts, a truth shown by Mahatma Gandhi as well as the
heroic young women, some still unknown, who refused to move to the back
of the bus in the 1950s and 1960s American South. Modern network theory
shows how one action can rapidly trigger change throughout the whole
system. One person becomes a group, then becomes a movement; one act
believed in and repeated by others becomes material, dramatic change.
The second key idea is that it is action that convinces, not words. New
research is now demonstrating what good theater directors have always
known: Show, donât tell. The actions of those people closest to usâand
not government policy or even expert opinionâare the most influential.
This means that Internet petitions are not likely to bring about
fundamental change, although they might make the signatory feel better
(which may indeed be the purpose). Likewise, social media may help
organize and inform larger groups in ways that have never been available
before, but unless this organization is used for a purposeâto do
somethingâit is worthless.
In contrast to asking for or voting for someone else to do it, action
can address the problem directly. There is an education intrinsic to
actionâyou have to learn about the problem to solve it, for most
problems are complex. This education reverses the infantilization and
ignorance that authority encourages: You need not worry about the
details, because we will take care of it. Equally, it demolishes the
common notion that ordinary people are somehow incapable of making
intelligent decisions about their own circumstances. Again, evidence
shows this to be an arrogant fallacyâpeople know their own circumstances
best of all.
The third key idea is about engagement and discussion. Again it is a
simple idea: Decision making is better when it includes the people most
affected. In the current Western model of representative democracy, we
have become accustomed to the idea that politicians, elected by us,
should negotiate among competing interests and make the necessary
compromises to produce consensus and policy. In Washington today, it is
painfully clear that this is the opposite of what is actually happening,
while in Europe political consensus around the social democratic model
is breaking down. The far right is emerging once more as a significant
political force, in reaction to the largely unpredicted and sometimes
violent changes that the world is now experiencing. In times of
uncertainty, the false appeal of those who loudly proclaim certainty
gains luster.
In Brazil, Britain and New Orleans, a better way of deciding our affairs
together is emerging (and it is not the Internet, or on the Internet).
It resembles democracy in its earliest and purest daysâpeople gathering
together, not in chat rooms, to make real decisions for themselves, not
voting for others to decide on their behalf, or merely ventilate their
frustrated opinions in town hall meetings or on the World Wide Web. When
lobbyists fill what used to be called the peopleâs parliaments and
congresses, this alternative âparticipatoryâ democracy offers something
unfamiliar yet extraordinary.
When large numbers of people make decisions for themselves, the results
are remarkable: Everyoneâs views are heard, policies take all interests
into account (as all lasting policy must), and are thus fairer. Facts
and science are respected over opinion. Decision making becomes
transparent (and thus less corrupt), respectful and less partisanâpeople
who participate in decisions tend to stick to them. More responsibility
and trust in society can only come about by giving real decision-making
responsibility to people. If you do not give people responsibility, they
tend to behave irresponsibly, and sometimes violently. Happily, the
converse is also trueâgive people power and responsibility, and they
tend to use it more wiselyâand peacefully.
This hints at the fourth idea that suffuses the argument throughout The
Leaderless Revolution: agencyâthe power to decide matters for ourselves.
We have lost agency. We need to take it back. We have become too
detached from the decisions most important to us; we are disconnected,
alienated, including from each other. This has contributed to a deeper
ennui about modern life: What is it all for? Where is the meaning? What
is the point? And in the solution to this crisis, which is both personal
and political, something profound may be available.
If we take back agency, and bring ourselves closer to managing our
affairs for ourselves, then something else may also come about: We may
find a fulfillment and satisfaction, and perhaps even a meaning, which
so often seems elusive in the contemporary circumstance.
These four ideas form the core of the philosophy of The Leaderless
Revolution. Adopt these ideas, above all act upon them, and things will
change. The book is intended as a guide and not a prescription. It sets
out a method of doing things and taking action, and not what the outcome
of this method should be. That is for everyoneâacting togetherâto
determine, and no single individual can pretend to know it, let alone a
writer tapping away on a laptop. No one can claim to know what others
truly want. These needs and concernsâand dreamsâcan only be expressed
through action, shared decision-making and discussion with those most
affected, including those who might disagree. But this method is the
essence of a new form of politics, indeed a new way of living together
on our crowded planet.
How might these ideas play out in practice? While the aspirations of
this philosophy are grand, the steps needed to embody it are simple:
small steps, things that everyone can do, every day.
It is no small struggle merely to live out the ideals that you aspire
to. The first step, and perhaps the most important, is to work out what
your ideals are. The slogan âBe the change you wish to seeâ is often
associated with the environmental movement, but it applies more
universally. At the simplest level, you cannot expect a political goal
of âequalityâ if you treat people unequally or tolerate that treatment
for others. People are not mere factors of production (or
âutility-maximizing consumersâ), as economists would depict them. By
altering our conduct and thus impact, we may incite change in others far
away, with surprising force and speed.
One essential of any method of change is this: Consult those most
affected. Those suffering from the problem (which may include you) will
know far more about its dimensions and likely solutions. People will
reject strident argument; they rarely reject informed interest. When I
served as a diplomat, I was subjected to both. The reader will already
know which had the more effect.
And itâs important, in all this, to reject the easy sanctimony of the
so-called Golden Rule: It exhibits a profound solipsism if not
arroganceâthat we can know the requirements of others. Instead, the
maxim should be to ask others what they want, and not assume. They
always know, and now, thanks to the Internet, we can hear their voices,
all over the world, with more clarity and vigor than ever before. If in
any doubt, addressing those in most suffering is a good place to start,
as Karl Popper once suggested, for unlike âhappiness,â suffering is all
too easy to recognize and measure.
So much for the personal; now, how to change the workplace?
Here, the dominant model is the private company whose primary and
overriding purpose is to maximize profit. The volatile flow of âhot
moneyâ from poor to well-performing stocks in the stock market, usually
based on very short-term actual or predicted returns, reinforces this
tendency. Meanwhile, a culture has arisen where bosses pay themselves
hundreds of times more than their average employees, sometimes
regardless of performance. And government ownership has been proven a
disastrously inefficient alternative. But there is another way to run a
business, less often mentioned.
Consider cooperative companies, like Britainâs retail chain John Lewis,
that share ownership, as well as agency, in the company. All partners
(not âemployeesâ) share in the profits and, notably, in decisions about
the companyâs future. Differences in pay between the bosses and the
others are far lower. Yet this company has been an enduring success,
profiting and growing year after year in the most ferocious of markets.
It has lasted nearly a hundred years.
Such enterprises are not created by government legislation, or by the
inevitable machinations of the market. They are established by the free
choice of their owners and foundersâpeople who choose to follow and
propagate a different way of doing things, without abandoning the
entrepreneurship that drives innovation and growth. And by their very
nature, and embodiment of values other than mere profit seeking, these
companies produce benefits that are today rarely associated with the
modern company: equality, solidarity and a satisfaction of real
involvementâas well as sustained economic stability. Contrast this with
the feelings most wage slaves associate with their employers. Typically,
one New York store owner told me that his biggest management problem was
to create a sense of âownershipâ in his business. But it is absurd to
hope for âownershipâ among employees who do not own any part of the
business.
Then there are the banks. The current system drives banks to lend
recklessly in boom times as they are forced to compete for profit and
share price, or else face buy-out. A more robust system might consist of
depositor-owned banks offering mutualized loans, where risk is spread
transparently[1] There is no intrinsic reason why such a bank should not
be set upâindeed there are already suchâbut it takes a decision by a
brave group to take the first step, and decisions by depositors to
reward institutions driven by values other than pure profit. This is a
politics of personal action: at home, with each other, and in the
workplace, incorporating the political goals we desire into everything
we do.
In turn, consumers can reward these companies with their dollars. There
are websites that offer competitive alternatives to the products of
companies that exploit their workers or the environment. At the most
extreme, customers can organize a boycott of the most egregious
offenders, as depositors at one European bank did to protest the bonuses
paid to executives after a huge government bailout (the bonuses were
withdrawn and the government outlawed them for all bailed-out banks).
When youâre buying, youâre voting. Every act becomes political. Indeed,
it always was.
This simple method of action applies at the global level too. The
Internet is now witnessing the genesis of online movements, where people
sharing a common concern unite across borders to address it, not through
campaigns but through action. We all know intuitively it simply isnât
enough to fight genocide in Darfur or sex trafficking by clicking a
button.
In the 1930s, forty thousand foreign volunteers traveled to Spain to
fight fascism. Ten thousand never returned. These were extreme
circumstances but illustrate the debilitating late-twentieth-century
decline from acting to campaigning, a shift that has entirely suited the
powerful. It is now abundantly clear, as it ever was, that it is action
that makes a difference. If concerned about refugees from a distant war,
give refuge. Boycott the aggressorâs corporate partners. Build systems
of cooperation and action, so it is no longer necessary to rely on the
cumbersome reaction of our governments which, as I have seen as a
diplomat, too often act upon an artificial calculus of ânational
interestsâ that relegate human needs beneath those of the state or
commerce.
No one pretends that it is easy to set up these alternative systems, but
neither is it impossible. Like a modern day version of Voltaireâs
Pangloss, who endlessly repeated that âall is for the best in the best
of all possible worlds,â it is tediously restated that the current
status quo is immutable and, certainly, incapable of improvement. We are
encouraged to believe that no one has the power to change it. Thus
paralyzed, we are frozen into inaction. This paralysis of thought is the
greatest obstacle to overcome. Defeat it, and everything becomes
possible.
The Leaderless Revolution is not demanding the violent overthrow of
government, or anything else. Everything worth changing can be changed
without resorting to violence; this should be a gentle revolution, using
force more lasting and convincing than any violenceâour own actions and
convictions. The most extreme cases of savage repression or attack may
justify violence, and then only rarely, and only after all nonlethal
alternatives including isolation, boycott and sabotage have been
exhausted.
The Leaderless Revolution instead advocates the construction of an
alternative and better system, step by small step.
Power must be taken back to where it rightfully belongsâto those who
have, until now, let it be given away. No government will decree this.
No politician will declare their own irrelevance. But we do not need
orders from authority to take control. It can succeed at the simplest
level, as well as on a broader canvas.
Self-organization need not and should not be an antagonistic process.
Simply start talking to your neighbors. Identify shared concerns, and
take action. Establish forums to discuss common issues, moderate these
respectfully and inclusively, invite all those concerned to attendâand
to speak.
In this way, these new forms of organization will gain legitimacy, a
legitimacy of real popular consent, delivered through participation.
Soon politicians will start to refer to these new forums, then bow to
them, and one day perhaps, give way to them. An alternative system is
created.
At work, the same thing is possible. Unions once performed this
organizing purpose, and still can, if they are truly inclusive and
democraticâand not outlawed. But it can happen informally too. It can
start with a few people meeting weekly over coffee, but as it builds and
others join, those in charge will have to take notice. True power comes
not from the assertion of rules and threats, but from the aggregation of
honest and sincere voices, and their concerted heartfelt action. When
sustained, uncorrupted and driven by real concerns, such power is
ultimately irresistible. Thus is power taken back.
The Leaderless Revolution challenges the stale choice between free
markets or government control. There is a better way that celebrates and
releases the power of individual passion and enterprise, yet also
expresses that equally deep-seated but less-celebrated human trait:
concern for others, responsibility for the common good and a belief that
the most important things in lifeâcommunity, love, purpose, each
otherâcannot be bought, but have to be enacted, striven for, lived.
But before any of this, the fear that must be overcomeâfear of each
other, fear of ridicule or failure and, perhaps most inadmissible of
all, fear of our own considerable power, as yet unleashed. It is this
fear that authority plays upon, indeed relies upon: Only we can protect
you. But that claim is ever less plausible in the face of global forces
which are, increasingly, out of control, whether terrorism, climate
change or economic volatility. Indeed, governmentsâ attempts to impose
order, through force or legislation, not only seem ineffective but may
exacerbate the problems they are claimed to solve. Worse, they have
convinced us, who have in fact the greater power, that we are powerless.
We have been silenced by the pervasive belief that there is no better
system than the current one of profit-driven capitalism and
representative democracy, when in fact our democracy has been hijacked
by those with the largest profits. We have been intimidated by the
bullying repetition that the status quo represents the summit of human
progress to date, when in its inequality, its carelessness for our
planet and its inhumanity to our fellow humans, in many ways it
represents the worst. Our silence permits this outrage to continue, and
profound injustice to be perpetuated. And it is this silence that must
now be broken, through a thousand acts of construction to build a better
world, a thousand acts that declare that there is a much, much better
way of organizing and deciding our lives together. Though peaceful,
these are revolutionary acts.
And with those acts, a new vista may open up, a possibility for the
human endeavor far more exciting and inspiring than that offered by the
current way of thought. Economic progress is not the measure of who we
are, just as bickering politicians should not define our ability for
cooperation. We are far more than merely this. And this possibility
cannot be defined; it can only be enacted. This revolution can only
succeed, indeed can only begin, without leaders: led by usâin control,
at last.
Carne Ross
New York City
October 2011
Some stories from the young twenty-first century:
When the H1N1 âswine fluâ virus struck Mexico in early 2009, it took
only hours and days to spread to every continent in the world except
unpopulated Antarctica. Authorities struggled to contain the spread of
the disease. Desperate to prevent the import of infection, some
governments resorted to aiming remote thermometers at arriving air
passengers to measure their body temperature. The World Health
Organization, responsible for global coordination of the fight against
disease, admitted some months after the first outbreak that it had been
unable to keep up with the vast flow of data from national health
bodies. The virus, it later appeared, was spreading out of control.
One Sunday that same year, a preacher from a Sikh sect was attacked
during a service in Vienna, Austria. Sant Rama Nand was set upon by six
men armed with knives and a pistol and died early the next day. Within a
few hours, widespread riots had broken out across the Punjab, where the
preacherâs sect was based. By nightfallâsome six hours after Sant Rama
Nand had diedâseveral people had been killed in turmoil that had
convulsed Punjabi towns and cities. Thousands of Sikhs took to the
streets, clashing with police and setting fire to buildings and
vehicles. Major highways were blocked by bonfires of tires and sticks.
Trains were attacked in several places. The authorities had little or no
warning of the outbreak.
One afternoon in 2010, it took less than thirty minutes for the Dow
Jones Industrial Average to fall nearly a thousand pointsâthe biggest
one-day points decline in the Dowâs history. It took five months for
regulators to explain what happened. According to the Securities and
Exchange Commission report, the rapid plunge was triggered by a poorly
executed sale by one mutual fund company. The firm started to sell $4.1
billion of futures contracts through an algorithmic trade, mistakenly
taking account only of volume, not time or price. Buyers, including
âhigh-frequencyâ traders who make rapid high-volume purchases and sales
to exploit tiny price margins in a dynamic market, purchased the
contracts. As sales of the contracts accelerated, the sellerâs algorithm
responded to the increase in volume by unloading the contracts faster,
pushing prices down further. The liquidity crunch then spread to the
equity market. Many traders withdrew from the market. Some reverted to
manual systems but could not keep up with the spike in volume. As the
market dived, shares in some household name companies were sold for as
little as a cent. The SECâs report was widely criticized for offering no
effective prescription on how to prevent such disruption in future.[2]
In the summer of 2008, food prices increased dramatically across the
globe thanks, it seems, to a sudden surge in oil prices, although the
causes of the spike are not fully understood. One factor may have been
the introduction of subsidies for ethanol production in the U.S.
Congress. Another possibility, speculation. The rocketing prices caused
riots and political tension in Cairo and Indonesia and many other
countries and reinforced an already emerging trend that some have called
a âfood crunchâ of static global supply and rising demand.[3] The prices
of commodities such as rice and wheat jumped to record highs, triggering
food riots from Haiti to Egypt to Bangladesh and Cameroon and prompting
UN appeals for food aid for more than thirty countries in sub-Saharan
Africa.
In response to this phenomenon, companies and in some cases governments
in money-rich but âfood-poorâ countries, like South Korea and Saudi
Arabia, began to buy up land and agricultural rights in money-poor but
land-rich countries. The Saudi Star company plans to spend up to $2
billion in the next few years acquiring and developing 500,000 hectares
of land in Ethiopia, one of the poorestâand hungriestâin the world.[4]
Up to fifty million hectares of landâan area more than double the size
of Britainâhas been bought in the last few years or is under negotiation
by governments and wealthy investors, often enjoying state subsidies.
The South Korean company Daewoo bought the rights to as much as half of
Madagascarâs available agricultural land. This deal in turn helped
trigger a coup against the Malagasy government that signed the deal.
This coup produced political instability in Madagascar that continues to
the time of this writing.
Earlier in the century, an Egyptian architecture student living in
Hamburg was horrified by reports of Russiaâs brutal campaign against
separatists, mostly Muslim, in Chechnya in the Southern Caucasus, a war
whose atrocities were scarcely reported in the information-overloaded
citadels of the West. The Chechnya war confirmed his view of the global
oppression of Muslims. Mohamed Atta joined a local mosque where, it was
later learned, he was introduced to the concept of jihad, a personal
struggle for liberation.
Atta made his way to Pakistan, to join a terrorist network called âThe
Base,â or Al Qaeda, which had been foundedâand fundedâby a middle-aged
man who himself had been radicalized by the Soviet Unionâs occupation of
Muslim Afghanistanâas well as Americaâs military domination of his home
country, Saudi Arabia. In the Afghan mujahideen victory over the Soviet
occupation forces, Osama bin Laden found his inspiration to seek a
global jihad. Mohamed Atta was to become the pilot of the American
Airlines Boeing 767 which cannoned into the north tower of New Yorkâs
World Trade Center. Walking to work that dread morning, I heard his
aircraft fly overhead.
The singular act of the 9/11 attacks helped trigger the allied invasions
of two countries, and further massive, complex and unforeseeable change.
The attacks were brilliantly anatomized in the U.S. Congress 9/11
Commission Report, which took over eight hundred pages to describe the
antecedents and chronology of this one single, if remarkable, eventâand
that was concise.
More recently, the defaults of a few subprime mortgage holders
concentrated in just three American states triggered in a very short
space of time a global economic meltdown thatâamong many, many other
thingsâbrought down several long-established banks in the United States
and necessitated a $700 billion bailout of other banks. When confidence
in the ability of U.S. banks to meet their obligations collapsed, rapid
contraction of credit was contagious across the globe, destroying in
quick time both overleveraged banks, and the deposits of their
customers. Banks in Iceland fell overnight, eliminating at a stroke the
savings of depositors in the UK. The ramifications of that event
continue to delay Icelandâs entry into the European Union, while in
Britain the credit crunch, among other factors, has contributed to the
most severe austerity measures and government spending cuts in many
decades, including a 70 percent cut to higher education budgets. In Hong
Kong, thousands of small investors and pensioners suddenly lost their
Lehman âmini-bonds,â worth billions of dollars, when Lehman Brothers,
founded in 1850, fell in the U.S.[5]
The origins of the âcredit crunchâ were manifold and are debated still.
Greedy lending by banks, unwise borrowing by homebuyers, loosening
legislation from government, enacted with the worthy intention of
enabling broader home ownership: perhaps all of them played a part. But
some have suggested a more deep-seated causeâthe growing inequality in
America between the rich and everyone else, which drove the
income-stagnant middle classes to borrow ever more to maintain their
living standards amid rising costs.
Another intriguing factor has been barely noted. The statistical models
used by the banks to assess the risks of bundled mortgages were out of
date: Not only did they underestimate the volume and riskiness of the
increasingly popular subprime mortgages, the banksâ models also
underestimated interconnectedness within the housing and mortgage
markets, regionally and nationally. The preponderance of the âno money
downâ high debt-to-deposit subprime mortgages meant that only a small
dip in the economy made huge numbers of mortgages suddenly unaffordable,
and the buyers defaulted. The banks had underestimated the degree to
which one thing would lead quickly to many others. They underestimated
complexity.
Whatever the cause, no government was ready for the crash, which came
almost without warning. Then President George W. Bush said later that he
had been âblindsidedâ by the crisis, stating that he âassumed any major
credit troubles would have been flagged by the regulators or credit
agencies.â[6] The cascading and multiple effects of the âcredit crunch,â
many of which have yet to be felt, included the loss of tens of millions
of jobs across the globe, and an immeasurable but nonetheless notable
shift of power from West to East, as the U.S. relied ever more heavily
upon China to buy up almost a trillion dollarsâ worth of American
government debt to finance the government bailout.
The tortured, twisting paths of cause to effect in these stories of the
twenty-first century are discernible only in retrospect by separating
out these threads from the confusing ratâs nest of simultaneous
eventsâitself a somewhat artificial and falsifying exercise. But these
stories are not extraordinary. They are typical of a vastly
interconnected age, where billions and billions of people are
interacting constantly, a wholly unprecedented phenomenon which we are
only beginning to understand. These events were not predictable by most
conventional theories of politics or economics.
Some may see chaos in these events, or purely random cause and effect.
These events do not suggest the structured order of past experienceâof
units, be they states or individuals, behaving according to established
theories of international relations or neoclassical economics,
predictable for the most part, and comprehensible within our existing
models. But neither are they chaos, a random, meaningless mess. They are
something else. This is a new dispensationâcomplexityârequiring new
tools: the science of complex systems. Pioneers in many fields are using
techniques like agent-based modeling and network analysis to begin to
offer powerful new insights into this multiplying complexity.
But this new world requires something else beyond new tools of
interpretation. This world is defying the ability of existing structures
and institutions to understand and arbitrate events effectively. Even
senior government officials confess the decline of state power:â We are
in a world where governments, as a whole, have less power than they once
did,â a senior U.S. State Department official recently said, sensibly
concluding, âLetâs take the world as we now see it.â[7] Confidential
briefing papers prepared for the UN Secretary-General noted the
declining importance not only of the UN itself, but also of governments
in managing the worldâs most pressing political, economic and
environmental problems, observing cheerily that âOur planetâs ability to
sustain life, as we know it, is under enormous strain.â [8] As Parag
Khanna has commented:
Globalization is⊠diffusing power away from the west in particular, but
also from states and towards cities, companies, religious groups,
humanitarian nongovernmental organizations and super-empowered
individuals, from terrorists to philanthropists. This force of entropy
will not be reversed for decadesâif not for centuries.[9]
Timothy Garton Ash has called this world ânot a new world order but a
new world disorder. An unstable kaleidoscope worldâfractured,
overheated, germinating future conflicts.â[10] Governments failed to
predict the credit crunch, as they did 9/11. Their blunt methods to
manage both economic volatility and terrorismâas well as other global
problemsâare insufficient, and sometimes counterproductive.
Politicians argue that only if they are in power will decisions be the
right ones, and thus we must suffer tedious rounds of facile political
argument over enduring and deep-seated problems, when closer analysis of
these problems leads to the more disturbing conclusion that no
politician and no government, however wise, however right, is able to
solve them. Somehow we know this. Frustration with conventional politics
is rising everywhere, depressing voter turnout and fueling popular
anger. Politicians too can sense the mood, but are unable to offer any
prescription except more of the same politics, perhaps spiced with a
dangerous and hollow populism.
This new world requires something else beyond more promises, something
beyond new theories of interpretation, something that might, just might,
make us at last feel that the tools might fit the job. This new world
requires a new politics.
Climate change, terrorism, ceaseless wars in places that defy
understanding or resolution and where victory or defeat both seem far
away, a perpetual economic volatility.[11] These are now already
familiar problems of this young and turbulent century. They are easy
problems to define: borderless, a product of the new âglobalizedâ world.
But at the same time they seem intractable: There seems very little that
any individual can do about them.
Taking their allotted role, instead governments, and associations of
governmentsâthe UN, the EU, international conferences in Copenhagen or
Dohaâclaim that they have these problems in hand. Every day witnesses a
summit, a statement or a resolution claiming to address these worrying
ills. It is a never-ending video-feed of activity, tedious to watch in
detail, but nonetheless reassuring in its unceasing activity and torrent
of verbiageâat least, that is the intention.
âTrust us,â the statements say, âwe have these problems under control.â
But the evidence suggests otherwise, more and more insistently. Measure
the outputs, not the promises made. Take two familiar problems.
At the 2009 Copenhagen climate change summit, an intensive two-year
international negotiation involving hundreds of delegates from almost
every country, and thousands of pressure groups and lobbyists, produced
at its end a short two-page document which, in hastily drafted and
ungrammatical prose, offers only the most general statements of concern
about the problem of climate change and no binding commitments to limit
carbon emissions or to compensate those most affected by its manifold
impacts.
Despite the global membership of the negotiation, encompassing every
country in the world, the statement was hashed out in the last few hours
of the conference in a closed room session involving China, Brazil, the
U.S. and India. The needs of those most affected by climate change, like
low-lying island states or Bangladesh which are already losing land to
rising seas, were ignored.
The Copenhagen process had been formidably complicated, involving
multiple âtracksâ of negotiation in an attempt to address the many
different aspects of the problem of climate change, including forests,
technology transfer and protection of oceans as well as the âbig
pictureâ questions of carbon emissions and how to finance the costs of
adapting to the effects of rising temperatures. Despite the thousands of
hours spent negotiating these subsidiary issues over the previous two
years, none of them was addressed in the final text.
In CancĂșn, a year later, delegates successfully agreed that their states
wanted to limit global warming to 2°Câthe âdangerâ level, beyond which,
a recent paper in the scientific journal Nature warned, warming may
increase beyond any control. The conference was widely touted as a
âsuccess,â as the Mexican hosts managed to secure agreement on key
issues, including financing for climate adaptation in poorer countries.
But there was no agreement on how climate change might be
preventedâconcrete agreement on the carbon emissions targets that
scientists concur as necessary. As The Economist reported, CancĂșn was
successful in rescuing the UN climate negotiations âprocessâ; its value
in rescuing the climate was less clear.[12]
Recently, the UN Environment Program reported that even if states
fulfilled all of their commitments to reduce carbon emissions, including
those made at Copenhagen, the worldâs temperature would still most
likely exceed the 2°C âdangerâ level. Outside of predictions and
commitments, and in the real world of the Earthâs atmosphere, where
success or failure is truly measured, the concentration of carbon in the
atmosphere has continued to rise unabated. In 1992, at the time of the
first international gathering of governments to address climate
change,[13] the concentration of carbon in the atmosphere was 354 parts
per million by volume. By 2010, it was nearly 10 percent higher, an
unprecedentedly rapid increase.
Meanwhile, in the global economy, the years that immediately followed
the 2008â2009 credit crunch witnessed innumerable G8, G20, UN and Basel
Committee discussions attempting to agree on new standards and rules to
prevent a recurrence of the devastating crash. But within the confusing
barrage of statements and commitments on new task forces, committees and
âwatchdogs,â nowhere to be found was the one simple
measureâsubstantially higher capital/debt requirements for banksâthat
almost all disinterested analysts believe would actually prevent a crash
happening again. And there was a reason for this absence.
While globalization intensifies apace, its rigors and stresses ever more
evident, its rewards seem to accrue mostly to a minority: the top 1
percent of the population in the U.S. took home nearly 25 percent of all
income, the highest percentage since 1928.[14] Middle-class incomes are
declining, but living expenses are not. Meanwhile, for many of the
poorest, life has actually gotten worse.
Across the globe, more than one billion still live on less than one
dollar per day; two billion live on a pathetic two dollars per day. And
while it is easy to ignore the miseries of life in Somalia and
Bangladesh, it is more astonishing that in New York City one in five
children is dependent on food stamps for survival, while Goldman Sachs
bankers enjoy bonuses of some $700,000 each and hedge fund traders throw
parties costing hundreds of thousands. In 2011, as leading bankers
declared that the âyears of apologyâ should be over,[15] one study
showed that seven million of the poorest Britons had seen their living
standards decline by a massive 10 percent over the previous decade.[16]
In 2009, one in seven Americans was living in poverty, the highest
proportion of the population for fifty years. In some parts of America,
life expectancy is actually declining thanks to poverty, though health
care spending per capitaâaveraged across the populationâis higher here
than anywhere on earth.
As the whole world, except North Korea, adopts the capitalist model,
such inequality is rising everywhere, both between and within countries.
In China, the introduction of free market economics has freed hundreds
of millions from poverty. But at the same time it has created the worst
inequality in Asia, apart from Nepal, until very recently an autocratic
monarchy: Official estimates suggest 1 percent of Chinese households
enjoy 40 to 60 percent of total household wealth.[17] In India,
politicians obsess about headline GDP growth rates, and the richest
build billion-dollar skyscraper houses, but hundreds of millions remain
in abject poverty and malnourishmentâthe calorie intake of the poorest
has remained stagnant for over a decade, and more than half of Indiaâs
children under five suffer stunting and poor brain development.[18] Even
in the supposedly egalitarian Nordic countries, the gap between rich and
poor is growing fast. Worldwide, a new trend has emerged, barely
noticed: Beyond a certain level of development, those at the top benefit
enormously, those at the bottom often actually do worse, while the
income of the bulk of the population stays more or less stagnant.
It is little wonder, then, that this model is so confidently extolled as
ideal by those who benefit from it. So often are the virtues of this
system avowed that it has taken on the characteristics of a moral
system, where anything done in the name of that system, however gross,
is morally justified as part of the necessary mechanics of the market.
The future offers an unsettling vision of ever greater competition for
markets and scarce resources. The ferocious contest of the global
marketplace is like being chained to an accelerating treadmill, under
constant pressure to cut costs and invent new products, trapped by a
ceaseless desperation to attract customers who themselves are ever less
satisfied, hopping from product to product (as surveys reveal) craving a
satiationâa fulfillmentâthey can never find. As billions join the global
labor force, no job is secure, no industry is stable, no profession may
not one day face obsolescence.
While economic insecurity is on the rise, so too is a more insidious and
equally permanent anxietyâpolitical insecurity and violence. As U.S.
officials with great candor admitted after 9/11, we are in a âLong Warâ
with global terrorists, and it seems to be getting longer. The war with
Al Qaeda is spreading across the worldâs geography, as its affiliates
metastasize. The invasion of Afghanistan whose rationale I delivered to
the UN one winter morning,[19] wholly justified to remove the government
brazenly hosting our attackers, has succeeded not only in perpetuating
civil war in Afghanistan but has also triggered the spread of
instability and extreme violence to the border areas and across
Pakistan, where now every major city has seen repeated suicide attacks
of horrific violence.
In the âhomeland,â violent jihadists may be found not only among
immigrants and visitors, but from the ranks of our own population:
âJihad Jane,â who was radicalized in her Philadelphia suburb; the U.S.
Army doctor who killed thirteen and wounded thirty at Fort Hood. A third
of all charged U.S. terror suspects are American citizens.[20] Contrary
to the received wisdom that economic underdevelopment is the fount of
terrorism, former CIA case officer Marc Sageman found in a study of 172
Al Qaeda terrorists that the majority were middle to upper class, well
educated, married with children, and occupied professional or
semi-professional positions, often as engineers, architects, scientists
and doctors. In Britain, suicide attackers who killed fifty-six and
injured several hundred on the London Underground and buses on July 7,
2005, came not from Saudi Arabia but from Dewsbury and Leeds. The
would-be murderers who tried to detonate a nail bomb in a London
nightclub in 2007 included a highly trained and British-born National
Health Service doctor.
Thanks to the spread of technologyâwhich can be as simple as cell phones
and fertilizerâand information on the Internet, it is now
straightforward for small groups of extremists to kill large numbers. In
Japan, police discovered that the Aum Shinrikyo sect had the capability
to produce the deadly nerve gas sarin in aerosol form. Had they chosen
to use this method, the fanatical group could have killed many hundreds.
Instead, they chose to deploy the less toxic liquid form of the agent,
but still killed scores and horribly injured many more.
In Oklahoma, Terry Nichols and Timothy McVeigh killed five hundred and
injured thousands with a truck bomb assembled at a cost of less than
$5,000. After mounting attempted attacks in 2010 to detonate package
bombs on several airliners, the Yemeni branch of Al Qaeda (AQAP)
announced that âOperation Hemorrhageâ was part of a new approach
eschewing major attacks, and instead setting out to cause âdeath by a
thousand cuts,â stating that âTo bring down America we do not need to
strike big,â and adding that the total bill for the parcel bomb
operation was a mere $4,200, but that it âwill without a doubt cost
America and other Western countries billions of dollars in new security
measures. This is what we call leverage.â[21]
Some 700,000 to 800,000 light weapons are produced every year, adding to
the vast stock of weapons already in circulation, as many weapons remain
in use decades after their manufactureâTaliban fighters carry AK-47s
produced in the 1960s or earlier.[22] Countries like Austria, Canada,
the UK and U.S. join North Korea, China and Russia as the largest
producers of these weapons, the primary means of conflict worldwide. The
annual authorized trade in such weapons exceeds $6 billion a year.[23]
The Small Arms Survey now reckons that globally there are nearly 900
million light weapons, some of ever greater sophistication: sniper
rifles deadly at two milesâ range; man-portable missiles that can down
airliners; mines that can sink cruise liners. In Mexico, drugs
traffickers have used submarines and antitank missiles in their wars
with each other and the authorities.
But it is not only the growing ubiquity of weapons and terrorismâwhatâs
in the backpack of that man down the railroad car?âthat threaten our
sense of safety and well-being. In Britain, the millions of CCTV cameras
broadcast their own message of our lack of trust in one another. Some
cameras now bear loudspeakers to broadcast their correctional message to
the âantisocial.â In some city centers, authorities deploy noise-making
devices whose deterrent screech can be heard only by the young, like
dogs or rats already designated as âtroublemakers.â Police are beginning
to deploy unmanned drones with high-resolution cameras to monitor car
traffic and the population, as defense companies push for military
technology to be adopted in policing. Some of the drones carry
loudspeakers with which to relay instructions to the civilian
populace.[24] It is reported that the London 2012 Olympics will be
monitored by Royal Air Force âReaperâ unmanned combat air vehicles
(UCAVs), hitherto deployed in Afghanistan to attack insurgents.
Meanwhile, in the United States, nearly four thousand federal, state and
local counterterrorism agencies monitor the population, while thirty
thousand officials are employed solely to monitor telephone and other
communications, creating, in the words of The Washington Post, âa new
level of government scrutinyâ of its citizens. Thousands of Americans
are included in a vast database, including many who have never been
accused of any wrongdoing.[25]
But the intrusiveness of such measures does little to lessen the evident
tension in public spaces, nor deter random, almost casual violence. In
2008, Kevin Tripp had an argument with a stranger in a supermarket
check-out queue in South London. The argument escalated. Tripp was
punched to the ground, suffering serious head injuries. He died later in
the hospital. In Baltimore in 2010, one man killed another with a chunk
of concrete during an argument over a parking space.
Research data show that community life in Britain, and America, is
deteriorating. Measuring the number of people in an area who are single,
those who live alone, the numbers in private rented accommodation and
those resident for less than a year, researchers found that all
communities in Britain were âless rootedâ than they were thirty years
earlier.[26] Comparing data from a census taken in 1971, researchers at
the University of Sheffield found substantially higher levels of
ârootlessnessâ and âanomieâ in contemporary communities. Commenting on
this data, the research leader, Professor Daniel Dorling, said, âEven
the weakest communities in 1971 were stronger than any community now.â
Ninety-seven percent of communities studied had become more fragmented
over the last three decades. âThese trends may be linked to higher
likelihoods of fearfulness because we are less likely to see and
therefore understand each othersâ lives.â
In the U.S., over a similar period, the rate at which Americans invite
people to their homes has declined by 45 percent. In his classic study
Bowling Alone, Robert Putnam reported indices of discohesion and social
fragmentation rising across the board. For instance, membership of
chapter-based organizations, where members attend regular meetings and
participate in social activities like the Rotary Club, the Masons, the
NAACP, Boy and Girl Scouts, etc., halved in the last fifty years. Others
report that Americans are alsoâunsurprisinglyâlonelier. Between 1985 and
2004, the number of Americans who said they had no close confidants
tripled. Single-parent households are on the rise, and the U.S. Census
estimates that 30 percent more Americans will live alone in 2010 than
did so in 1980.[27]
As if these data were not dismal enough, it seems too that the very
ground on which we stand is less firm than before. Mankind foolishly
believed that nature, once conquered, would remain quiescent in our
plans. Rising sea levels have already required the evacuationâforeverâof
several low-lying islands. In Australia, forest fires rage with a new
and terrifying ferocity, consuming whole towns. Even the skeptical
notice greater volatility in the weatherâeverythingâs hotter and colder,
and wetter and windierâthan it used to be. This too is consistent with
scienceâs predictions. This volatility feeds a deeper disconnection
between man and his environment. For the first time ever, more people
now dwell in cities than the countryside. The urban majority now barely
encounter what their forebears took for granted: trees, fresh air,
birdsong, silence. Lives are lived out in a frantic, noisy hecticness;
fulfillment is distant, with peace and escape dreamed of, sometimes
purchased, but all too rarely experienced.
This list is so depressing that together these problems offer a sheer
and intimidating cliff face, upon which there appears no handhold, no
purchase at all. The temptation is simply to switch off, tune out,
escape.
And indeed advertising offers us a tantalizing vision of that escape, a
ceaseless promise to leave the burdensome everyday and wander into
sunlit uplands: âGo forth!â says one advert for jeans, with an evocative
image of a young man shirtless in a field of waving grass. These
messages claim not only to sell us jeans but to solve our all too
obvious, if never to be admitted, existential crisis: That all thisâthe
modern condition of prosperity, a sort of peace, a sort of freedomâis
simply not enough. The yearning for more, for distraction, never quite
goes away however much is purchased, however many holidays are taken.
This hunger is all but explicit in the advertising (Go forth! Find
yourself! Choose freedom!), but can never be confessed in a culture
where our argumentsâcapitalism, democracyâare supposed to have won, and
provide a convincing, empirically justified answer to all objections,
except the one we cannot admit to.
But in this existential crisis, the first fragile handhold upon the
cliff face of intractable problems is revealed. The answer to both
crises is, in fact, the same. And it is simple. It is embodied in one
word: agency. Agency over eventsâthe feeling of controlâis a gross
absence in the contemporary condition. Recapturing it is available
through one simple mechanism: action. Action to reassert control over
events in our lives. And this in a nutshell is the simple essence of the
philosophy to be offered here. We lack control; we need to take it back.
The incredible and seismic changes of the late twentieth and early
twenty-first century have forced dramatic and sometimes revolutionary
changes in almost every realm of human activityâfinance, technology,
cultureâsave one, politics. In this most crucial forum, the institutions
and habits acquired in different times have endured, even when their
effectiveness is less and less evident. On the contrary, the evidence is
accumulating that these inherited bodies and rules are less and less
able to comprehend and arbitrate the forces now swirling around us.
Something else is desperately needed. That necessity has been
articulated by many but none has offered a solution except more of the
same, politics as usual: pathetic calls for more âpolitical willâ to
address this or that problem; celebrity-endorsed âsingle issueâ
campaigns for the public to pressure their representatives to address
one particular crisis over others; superficial online campaigns to
address some deep and poisonous malaise, like starvation or child
slavery. Some believe that technology alone will deliver the necessary
revolution, but here too it is clear that technologyâs effects are often
as malign as benign, serving the dictatorial as much as the democratic.
A more fundamental shift is needed.
One telltale sign is the increasing number of politicians who now
promise to âchange politicsâ itself. In 2008, it was Barack Obama; in
Britain, it was the Conservative/Liberal Democrat coalition of 2010
which promised to change the very nature of the system. In America, the
change-the-system sentiment is now expressed by the Tea Party movement,
with its demand to âtake back our government.â And just as surely, the
Labour Party in Britain, now in opposition after thirteen years in
government, will develop a new claim, that it too will âchange the
systemâ if only voters give them a chance. The pattern is a clear one.
Politicians can smell the frustration, and must respond to it, but are
surely doomed. With each electoral cycle, the disillusionment appears
greater, data show that voters chop and change parties with greater
frequency, while turnout falls steadily in all democracies, with only
the occasional upward âblip,â like the sputtering of a dying fire.
This revolution is as profound as it is simple. Evidence and research
are now suggesting that the most important agent of change is ourselves.
At a stroke, the prevailing notion that the individual is impotent in
the face of the worldâs complex and manifold problems is turned on its
head. Instead, the individual is revealed as a powerful motor of change,
offering the prospect of immense consequences for politics and the
world, and, no less, for themselves.
I once believed in the capability and rightness of enlightened
government so fervently that I went to work for it. I was a British
diplomat, in an institution and a system which was founded on a deep
belief that state officials like me could understand and arbitrate the
world effectively, for the benefit of the less informed masses. I no
longer believe this. This disillusionment came not from ideological
conversion, but experience.
In my work on many of the worldâs most worrying problems, including
climate change, terrorism and the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq (I was
responsible for both issues for the UK at the United Nations), it became
slowly clear to me that government was unable, by its very nature, to
comprehend and manage these forces effectively. Why will become clear,
but in short I realized, dimly and slowly, a profound and intrinsic
deficit of governments: that they are required to take what is
complexârealityâand turn it into simplistic pronouncements and policy,
the better to convince the population that government has matters in
hand. People in government are not bad or stupid, on the contrary; but
the contract between people and government forces them to claim
something which no sensible person should claim, that
governmentâanyone!âcan understand and predict the massive complexity of
the contemporary world, and manage it on our behalf. Every politician
must claim to the voters that they can interpret the world, and produce
certain effects, just as the officials working for them must pretend
that they can too. I know this because I did it.
I saw how in looking at places like the Middle East, and by extension
the whole world, governments were forced to reduce hugely complicated
and dynamic situations into simplistic models, us and them, security
versus threat, just as they were required to project the manifold needs
of their own diverse peoples into simple and artificially invented sets
of âinterests.â Such a process is inherently false, requiring
governmentsâand officials like meâto create stories and policies that
offer clear, straightforward and therefore often very simplistic
solutions. Then, to justify these stories, their officials must seek out
the facts to suit the policy, the very opposite of a more valid
empirical methodâwhere we observe the world, then respond accordingly.
Governments have it the wrong way around.
I gladly took part in such processes, writing speeches and talking
points, and arguing in vicious negotiation to claim that Saddamâs Iraq
was a threat, that his regimeâs overthrow would deliver stability and
spread democracy across the Middle East. On Afghanistan, I wrote embassy
telegrams from a Kabul freshly liberated from the Taliban, explaining
how democracy âAfghan styleâ would bring peace and prosperity to the
Afghan people, conveniently overlooking the reality that much of
Afghanistan remained unliberated from the Talibanâs grip and that the
democratic government we proclaimed was in fact largely our own
creation, our own fantasy of what democracy should look like, rather
than necessarily what the local people really wanted. After fifteen
years as a diplomat, I was highly skilled in writing cables and reports
and policy submissions that endlessly reaffirmed our version of events,
often without the benefit of any knowledge from the ground at all. In
five years working on Iraq, not once had I set foot in the country, yet
at the UN. I was called Britainâs Iraq âexpert.â I was not alone in such
ignorance, nor in the arrogance that, despite it, government could
declare with confidence what was happening or what might happen in such
places. Only after much subsequent slow and sometimes painful reflection
did I come to these broader conclusions about the intrinsic amorality,
but also incapability, of government.
I watched dramatic forces at play in the world, and felt rising
frustration at the seeming inability of government, or indeed anyone, to
offer meaningful and plausible solutions. As political violence spread,
and the credit crunch exploded, I watched desperate politicians, some of
them friends, as they argued to pretend that they might understand,
might control these forcesâterrorism, the stresses of globalization, the
deteriorating natural environment. I watched the growing angry chorus in
public gatherings and on the Internet, demanding action, change,
something, with ever more belligerent rhetoric, but never themselves
offering solutions beyond a rejection of the current cohort of lousy
politicians.
And I pondered change itself, how to react to this vastly complex world
in a way that might work, that might provide the satisfaction of finding
real traction upon the ghastly sheer cliff face of problems. And I
realized that perhaps the worst deficit of government itself was this:
In claiming to arbitrate the worldâs problems, unintentionally it
encourages our own inaction and detachment. And in that detachment, rage
and frustration has fermented dangerously. In the disembodied anonymity
of the Internet, or the vapid chatter of commentators and newsreaders,
and in the ceaseless demand for government and politicians to actâdo
something!âI saw how our opinions have become yet more polarized, an
alienation from each other exacerbated by the mobility and rootlessness
of modern economies. The problem is always someone elseâs, never ours,
to solve.
And yet it is actionâand only actionâthat changes things. Whether in the
history of the battle for civil rights in Americaâs South or the
Franco-Russian wars, or in the contemporary research of social
scientists and network theorists, the same and ancient truth is
repeated: It is the action of individuals which has the most effect on
those around them, on their circumstances, and thus the whole world.
Whether in Gandhiâs salt march to free India from colonial rule, or a
group of men trying to stop muggings in their neighborhood in New York
City, it is the expression of conviction through action that has the
most powerful impact upon each other, our surroundings, and indeed our
own well-being. The scale of the worldâs difficultiesâthe sheer cliff
faceâand the magnitude of globalization produce a paralyzing sense of
impotence and frustration. But in fact, a world that is more
interconnected than ever before, where each person is only a few links
away from anyone else, means that actions in our own microcosmos can
have global consequences.
These stories and ideas will be explored in this book: facts, research
and stories that together suggest a radical philosophy of how to create
a better world, one that more closely reflects the current reality than
the easy but dangerous assumption that we can leave it all to government
to fix. This philosophy could fit under the broad school of thought
known as âanarchism,â a term commonly associated with violence and
nihilismâmore what it is against, than what it is for. And mere
opposition to government, authority and hierarchy is clearly
insufficient as a solution. This book has a more positive vision,
presented in detailed principles to guide action. It is not proposing a
violent overthrow of government, but a much gentler revolutionâin the
way we think about the world, and how weâourselvesâmight therefore
respond to it. Changing our own approach is critical: embodying our
political beliefs in every action. Changing the self may change the
world. In all the haze and chatter, rediscover what you truly believe
in, then act. And following that transformation, another necessary
shiftânegotiating directly with one another, rather than leaving it to
distant institutions. In contrast to the paralysis of modern
legislatures, too often dominated by the interests of the powerful
rather than the mass, collective decision making, whether in New Orleans
or Brazil, has emphatically shown the benefits of shared debate and
responsibility: respect for one another, for facts, but above all
agreement upon better, fairer and more enduring solutions.
In a world where government influence is in inexorable decline, and
other transnational forces assert themselves, some beneficent but some
malign, there is little choice but to take on the burden of action
ourselves. If we do not, others surely will, whether criminal mafias
with worldwide reach, global terrorist movements or multinational
companies and banks with no concern but their own profit. This book
offers some simple pointers to what that action might
compriseâconviction, action, consultationâwith some inspiring stories of
how these principles have worked before. But this is no historical
survey; it is an attempt to look at the world as it actually is, not as
we or governments might wish it to be, and design a plan of action to
respond. It is above all a manifesto about how to actâmethodânot a
prescription of what end-state or utopian system to seek. No book can
offer solutions to every problem, though there are several suggestions
here. But that how is the key, for, as we shall see, the method is the
pointâthe means are the ends. For in that method, there are
extraordinary prizes to be wonânot only the accomplishment of the
desired goal, but a greater sense of cooperation, respect and community
with our fellow human beings, and a deeper sense of our own satisfaction
and purpose, needs that are all but ignored in the current obsession
with material well-being, status and celebrity. It is a humble and very
practical manifesto, though its ideals are transcendent.
In the current crisis there are small but glimmering signals that point
the way forward. These signals are but rarely noticed by those who
defend the current order, but the lessons of this new philosophy are all
around us, if we care to look. You wonât find this teaching in the
academy, or in economistsâ predictions or politiciansâ speeches.
When American troops entered Iraq in 2003, they were briefed to expect a
conventional army consisting, as such armies do, of tanks, artillery and
infantry. Saddam Husseinâs army had once contained more Main Battle
Tanks, a primary unit of the conventional army, than all the armies of
Western Europe put together.[28]
The lead elements of the American and British armies, then, were
surprised to find that most of the opposition they faced comprised not
tanks and howitzers, but men in pickup trucks, bearing rocket-propelled
grenades (RPGs) and machine guns. These bands would attempt to ambush
the advancing allied columns, launch the RPGs, then flee. They were not
often successful. Indeed, so desperate and dangerous to their
participants were these attacks that they resembled nothing so much as
the Japanese kamikaze suicide attacks familiar from the Pacific theater
of the Second World War. These fedayeen fighters, as they came to be
known, did not appear to belong to particular Iraqi army units, or if
they did, their members had abandoned their uniforms and badges that
denoted their unit allegiance.
The allied invasion proceeded with remarkably little substantial
opposition. The American tanks at the head of the advance reached
Baghdad almost as fast as they could drive. The capital quickly fell,
the statues of the hated dictator were toppled and the allies assumed
control of the country, taking possession of the main government
buildings abandoned by Saddamâs cohorts and thus, they believed,
control.
It was only in the days that followed that the real military opposition
to the invasion began to assert itself. The first suicide attack had
taken place during the march on Baghdad. The attackerâan Iraqi army
officer dressed in civilian clothesâdrove a taxi to a checkpoint near
the central city of Najaf and, as American soldiers approached,
detonated the vehicle. Four soldiers were killed.[29] Iraqâs then vice
president, Taha Ramadan, warned that there would be many more such
âmartyrdom missionsâ: He was right, though the attacks that followed
were not under government orders; his government would soon disappear. A
few days later, two women suicide bombers killed three coalition
soldiers north of Baghdad.
Over the days and months that followed, the number of suicide bombings
rose dramatically. In one month in 2004, there were several attacks
every day. As Dexter Filkins reported in The New York Times, âin the
first five years, more than nine hundred people detonated themselves in
Iraq, sometimes several in a single day. That was before you counted the
car bombs when the driver got out before it exploded. There were
thousands of those.â[30]
Suicide bombers used cars, trucks and motorbikes; often they came on
foot, sometimes on bicycles. During the âsurgeâ of American troops in
2008, attackers launched fusillades of massive âlob
bombsââexplosive-filled gas cylinders propelled by crude rocket
enginesâfrom flatbed trucks parked alongside U.S. bases. The operators,
their intent clearly suicidal, were inevitably annihilated, but only
after unleashing hours of bombardment. Such were the ferocity and
effectiveness of the attacks, and the alliesâ inability effectively to
stop them, that they began to undermine the will of the U.S. to remain.
Even before Barack Obamaâs election as president in 2008 when during the
campaign he had promised to withdraw U.S. troops from Iraq, the
administration of George W. Bush had declared a date when the soldiers
would leave.
In Afghanistan, allied war planners preparing the 2002 invasion had
expected a more irregular resistance. The Taliban who ran the country
were more militia than a conventionally organized army, more AK-47 than
Main Battle Tank (though they did have a few tanks, at least before the
allied airstrikes began). Their tactics had been honed in decades of
fighting against other Afghan militias and conventional military forces
during the Soviet occupation in the 1980s.
Adept at ambush and hit-and-run attacks, the Taliban fighters were
extremely hardy and able to endure long periods without logistical
support. After trekking over Afghanistanâs harsh terrain, they would
launch an attack with RPGs and machine guns, and occasionally a heavier
weapon like a mortar or small artillery piece, then melt away into the
unforgiving countryside. The Taliban were not known, however, to use
suicide attacks. During the Soviet occupation of Afghanistan, there were
no known instances of such tactics, except very occasionally by foreign
mujahideen fighters, some of whom later became infamous as Al Qaeda.
When I was posted to Afghanistan as a diplomat shortly after the allied
invasion, the defenses of our embassy reflected this assessment of the
Talibanâs military capabilities. The embassy was located in a compound
surrounded by high, thick walls. Atop the walls was another high fence
of sturdy netting, designed to prevent the flight of RPGs into the
compound.
In the early days, during and after the allied invasion, this military
assessment proved correct. But after a while, as in Iraq, things began
to change. The harbinger had taken place on September 9, 2001, an event
overshadowed by the attacks shortly afterward in Washington and New
York. Suicide bombers posing as a television film crew assassinated the
anti-Taliban mujahideen leader, Ahmed Shah Massoud. Setting up the
camera to film him, the âcameramanâ blew himself up, and fatally wounded
Massoud, who died a few hours later. Indicative of the changing and
multinational nature of that conflict, the bombers were Tunisian; the
camera had been stolen in Grenoble, France.
There were other antecedents. The Tamil Tigers used suicide attacks
extensively against the Sri Lankan army (and, sometimes, civilians) in
their fight for a separate Tamil homeland in northern Sri Lanka.
Hezbollah cadres used bomb-laden cars and explosive-bearing individuals
to attack Israeli army patrols and convoys during Israelâs occupation of
southern Lebanon. To those watching elsewhere, the technique appeared
crucial in dislodging an enemy which otherwise enjoyed a massive
military advantage: Israelâs conventional strength in tanks and aircraft
was far superior to Hezbollahâs. Israel withdrew from Lebanon in 2000,
demoralized by the suicide attacks it could not effectively prevent.
But it was the suicide attacks in Iraq that seemed to have the most
influence. As such attacks mounted in Iraq and increased the discomfort
of the allies, suicide attacks became more frequent in Afghanistan,
where before they had barely featured. Allied troops, and even trucks
carrying humanitarian supplies, were forced to form convoys, protected
by tanks and armored vehicles. Not a single major road was safe to
travel.
In both Iraq and Afghanistan, the use of suicide bombings produced its
own consequences. American and allied forces were forced to adopt
aggressive defensive tactics to prevent attacks, including challenging,
shooting and destroying people or vehicles that approached allied
patrols too closely and ignored (or failed to hear or understand) the
warnings given them.
The consequences of these tactics can be imagined and were realized in
civilian deaths and growing antipathy to âthe occupiers.â Eleven members
of the same Iraqi family were shot dead in their car approaching
coalition troops, just days after the first suicide attack in March
2003.[31] The effects on the troops obliged to adopt these tactics can
also be imagined. As in Iraq, debates grew about the wisdom of a
long-term allied military presence in Afghanistan. One reason for the
spread of the technique of suicide attacks was all too clear: It worked.
This was a new phenomenon. Normally, the deployment of particular
military techniquesâaerial bombing, mass armored assaultâwas a function
of hardware: the availability of tanks or aircraft, and carefully
constructed strategy. These factors themselves are functions of others:
economic development and the degree of organization within both the
military and society as a whole. The spread of suicide bombings was
different. They were spreading like a virus. If their appearance was
correlated with anything, it was not the degree of economic development
or military organization, but their opposites.
Some analysts suggest that common to suicide attackers is their
strategic objective to remove occupiers from desired territory;[32] some
that religious ideology, and in particular Salafi jihadism, is the
driving force.[33] Whatever the debate about motives, there is agreement
that the incidence of suicide attacks has dramatically increased
everywhere over the last two decades, and particularly the last few
years. Suicide attacks were not confined to religiously motivated
terrorist groups like Hezbollah, the Taliban or Al Qaeda; in Turkeyâs
Kurdish regions and Sri Lanka, the technique was used by groups driven
primarily by secular, and indeed nationalist, ideology.[34] Whatever the
motivation, the empirical resultsâof casualties caused, and political
effects in consequenceâwere demonstrable.
This recent trend had earlier precedents. Japan employed kamikaze
attacks only during the last stages of the Pacific war, when all chance
of strategic victory had evaporated. The Japanese leadership did,
however, encourage the attacks, after initial experiment, for the very
same reason: They worked. During battles such as that in Leyte Gulf, the
U.S. Navy lost scores of vessels to kamikaze attacks. A later survey
showed that kamikaze missions were four to five times more likely than
conventional missions to damage or sink their targets.[35]
Just as todayâs suicide attackers are often characterized as fanatical
and therefore irrational, the kamikazes have been similarly dismissed as
the product of death-loving samurai cultlike thinking that gripped the
Japanese military elites. But for them, too, there was a logic: The
higher the price exacted upon U.S. forces approaching the Japanese
homeland, the more, they hoped, America would hesitate to attack the
home islands, and would instead sue for a peace more favorable to Japan.
Just as in Iraq, Lebanon and now Afghanistan, suicide attacks were
permitted by a culture that celebrated death in combat, but also, and
above all, because they had a palpable and successful political effect.
By 2005, the use of suicide bombings had spread to Bali and Britain,
which suffered major suicide attacks on the London Underground and buses
that year. The U.S. of course had already seen such attacks on September
11, 2001. In Mumbai in 2009, suicide attackers killed nearly two hundred
people and wounded more than three hundred in a three-day rampage of
shooting and murder. Suicide attacks are now commonplace across North
Africa and the Middle East, Pakistan and the Horn of Africa, and have
spread elsewhere, including sub-Saharan Africa, Turkey, the Caucasus,
Indonesia and the Indian subcontinent and even Iran, where in 2010,
suicide bombers killed thirty-nine.
Despicable as some may find it, suicide bombing has been perhaps the
most influential political-military technique of the late twentieth and
early twenty-first centuries: In conflicts that are about different
ideologies, territories and religions, fighters have adopted the
technique without prejudice. In its horror, suicide bombing offers up an
insight into something important, something about how change happens,
and how we as people work, and thus how things might be changed for the
betterâbut without killing people. Curiously, that lesson is apparent
too in sports stadiums.
At many a baseball game, it takes only one, or a small group, to stand,
raise their arms in an attempt to start a wave (they may whoop or cheer
at that point). Sometimes the attempt is ignored, but at other times it
might initiate a coordinated yet spontaneous motion of tens of thousands
of people around the stadium. Itâs frivolous, fun, but also oddly
moving: âWeâre in this together.â
In his book Herd, marketing guru Mark Earls explains why people buy what
they do, or rather how they are influenced by the person sittingâor
whoopingânext to them. Earls cites the sales phenomenon of the Apple
iPod. He describes how the color of the headphone cable was a crucial
factor in the deviceâs dramatic sales success. The unusual white color
of the cords attracted peopleâs attentionâand enabled them for once to
see the brand choices of their peers even though the product itself
remained hidden: The cables made the otherwise private choice visible.
The innovative features of the product were of course a vital factor in
the ultimate decision to buy the iPod, but it was the white cords that
triggered the chain of events that led to the purchase.
Earls suggests that most of our lives are âquotations from the lives of
others,â as Oscar Wilde put it, a phenomenon evident in the spread of
agricultural mechanization across Americaâs Midwest in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth century, when farmers bought tractors
when they saw their neighbors had them; or the names we give our
children and the music we listen to. All of these trends, Earls asserts,
are shaped by social influence first and foremost, and not by our own
independent decisions or the inherent appeal of the thing being chosen.
Hitherto, economic theory has suggested that rational choiceâa weighing
up of the costs and benefitsâis the primary basis for decision making,
and particularly purchase decisions. But it turns out that nothing more
complicated than mimicry may be a better explanation of why people buy
what they do. As one correspondent to the New Scientist put it, man
should not be named Homo sapiens, âwise man,â but Homo mimicus, âcopying
man.â
Conventional economic theory claims that humans calculate by numbers,
assessing rationally the profit and loss of any transaction. But it
appears that even in deciding our finances, like taking on or abandoning
a mortgage, the behavior of others is influential. The herdlike
popularity of subprime mortgages is already well documented. More
recently, the practice of abandoning properties whose mortgages cost
more than the value of the house has spread âlike a contagion,â
according to a recent study, as both its economic rationale but also,
crucially, its social acceptability have grown: âItâs okay to walk
away.â[36] Researchers found that borrowers were 23 percent more likely
to default on their mortgage once their neighbors had done the same.
This mechanism is evident elsewhere. The British government commissioned
research to find out how to persuade people to adopt more
pro-environment behavior, for example to limit their carbon emissions.
The research found that government was itself an ineffective device to
encourage behavioral change: People did not trust government and
believed it was using climate arguments as an excuse simply to raise
taxes.[37] (Indeed, this distrust is one reason why government may be
ineffective in promoting the change necessary to protect the
environment.) Instead, the research found, the government would need to
recruit more influential agents to persuade people to act. These were
not scientists, officials or experts, all of whom were nevertheless more
trusted than government. Those with the most potential to influence
othersâ behavior were, the researchers concluded, our next-door
neighbors. Indeed, it appears from another study that people take more
notice of each otherâs actions than they do of formal rules.
Researchers at the University of Groningen in the Netherlands tried to
see whether the well-known âbrokenwindows theoryâ of policing actually
worked: the concept that if police aggressively target minor crime, such
as littering and vandalism, they will reduce overall lawlessness,
including major crime, like assault and mugging.[38] The researchers ran
various experiments to find out how contextâthe environment people
encounterâaffects behavior, including law-breaking. The researchers were
trying to understand how disorderly behavior spreads.
In one experiment, they tested whether people took more notice of a
clear legal prohibitionâa police sign telling people not to lock their
bicycles at a particular spotâor of whether other people were violating
the rule by locking their own bicycles there. To test this, they ran
scenarios with and without the sign, and the presence or absence of
other rule-violators: people illegally locking their bikes.
The studyâs results were clear. People were more inclined to violate the
rule and lock their bicycles illegally if they saw others doing the same
thing, regardless of what the police sign said. The studyâs authors
suggest that their evidence therefore confirms the brokenwindows theory.
As such, the study could be taken as affirmation of an assertive
policing model where police act quickly and robustly to deal with minor
violations, and thus deter more serious crime. But the study also
implies a more subversive message. The Groningen experiments show that
norms are more important than rules: It is the actions of other people
that have the most influence on what we do.
Earls offers the wave as a metaphor for this model of changeâit is also
in its way an example. It takes no instruction or authority to initiate
the rolling wave of spectators standing up and lifting their arms at a
sports stadium. One or two people might try to start a wave. If others
around them follow, the wave can quickly ripple around the stadium,
involving tens of thousands of people in an utterly spontaneous yet
coordinated act. The point is a clear one: The person most important in
influencing change may be the person standing right next to you.
Suicide bombing and the wave thus offer strikingly similar lessons in
how to affect others. Intriguingly, both suggest that it is action in
the microcosmos, our own little universe, that matters most: what we do.
This is not the only parallel.
First, neither suicide bomber nor waver looks to anyone else, let alone
their government, to produce the desired effect. Simply, if you want to
start a wave, you do not wait for someone else to stand up. More
starkly, the suicide bomber is prepared to sacrifice their own body and
existence to attack their enemy. Horrible though it may be, it is truly
a politics of personal and direct action.
Second, the action is directly linked to the desired effectâin fact, the
action is that effect. Standing up in your stadium seat, though a small
action in a crowd of thousands, constitutes the start of a wave. In
contrast, voting for a wave to be started most emphatically does not
constitute the start of a wave. Detonating a bomb that kills your
attackers, as well as yourself as the necessary adjunct, may be viewed
by many of us as unconscionable but it does constitute resistance in a
very material andâoftenâeffective manner. Action and consequence are
connected without intermediation.
Third, both suicide bombing and waves can plausibly be replicated by
others, indeed in the case of the wave, that is the very point. One
reason why suicide bombing has proven so effective is that it requires
very little training to undertake and is relatively cheap compared to
other military tactics: Others can easily imitate the tactic. An
uneducated peasant can suicide-bomb as effectively as an experienced
infantryman. Indeed, it would be a waste of a trained soldier to expend
him so.
Fourth, the action offers the possibility of real and immediate change.
The wave, if initiated at all, is initiated immediately. This must be
very satisfying to the person who stands up to start it (I have never
done this). The suicide bomber, if successful, will destroy the enemy
vehicle or the people he or she is targeting. Though they will die in
the process, the effect they seek is as immediately forthcoming as their
own death.
And in one crucial respect, of course, suicide bombers and wavers are
very different. Unless coerced, which they sometimes are, suicide
bombers are motivated by a belief (some would call it fanaticism) so
great that they are willing to sacrifice their lives. This too helps
explain the uniquely persuasive power of suicide bombing. Along with the
bomb belts portending the deaths of themselves and their victims,
suicide bombers carry something else, undeniably: conviction.
And here is where we must abandon the example of the wave as too
superficial, for however fun, few would be much impressed by the
conviction of those participating in a wave. And it is conviction that
convinces.
Suicide bombers illustrate this truth with horrific violence, but
othersâGandhi, American civil rights protestersâhave shown the uniquely
persuasive force of nonviolence. In either case, it was conviction that
propelled the action; it was the action that recruited others to the
cause. Thus, an essential first step to produce any lasting influence
and change is the discovery of conviction.
This discovery is sometimes a personal realization; sometimes it is
conducted with others. For Gandhi, it began in South Africa when as a
âcoloredâ he was thrown off a whites-only train. In Alabama in 1955,
fifteen-year-old Claudette Colvin was riding the bus home from school
when the driver demanded that she give up her seat for a middle-aged
white woman, even though three other seats in the row were empty.
Claudette Colvin refused to budge. As she put it, âIf she sat down in
the same row as me, it meant I was as good as her.â[39]
Colvin was arrested. Two police officers, one of them kicking her,
dragged her off the bus and handcuffed her. On the way to the police
station, they took turns trying to guess her bra size. Colvinâs action
took place six months before the same was done by Rosa Parks, whose
refusal and arrest are the more celebrated, but together their actions
triggered a bus boycott. The court case occasioned by the boycott, at
which Claudette Colvin testified, effectively ended bus segregation. As
David Garrow, a biographer of Martin Luther King, Jr., commented, âItâs
an important reminder that crucial change is often ignited by very
plain, unremarkable people who then disappear.â[40]
Interestingly, network researchers have found similar effects. Contrary
to some recent popular books, such as The Tipping Point, it is not
necessarily a few key influencers who create viral trends; it can be
anyone.[41] In fact, Duncan Watts has found that predicting who is
influential in starting or shaping any particular trend is more or less
impossible. This may be bad news for advertisers trying to save money by
targeting their campaigns to a few key influencers, but in terms of
political change, it is very exciting. Anyone can initiate a profound
social change.
Whatever the insights of network theory or marketing gurus, political
change is rather different from buying iPods or downloading the latest
Lady Gaga single. Our beliefs about right and wrong are powerfully held;
to shift the convictions of others requires profound experience or equal
if not more powerful conviction, something rather more substantial than
clicking âlikeâ on a Facebook page. In a word, action.
These forces are rather harder to measure, though somehow we can tell
when such experience strikes or when we are moved by the actions of
others: You know it when you see it. Conviction can be found in myriad
different ways, but it can rarely be told: As in all good theater, it is
better shown.
To find true political conviction, beliefs that move us and others must
be tested, lived, embodied, just as suicide bombers, horribly, embodies
theirs. And for this to happen, itâs necessary first to confront a
painful reality.
It is comforting to believe that governments can provide for us, and
protect us. Governments want us to believe it, and we want to believe
them. Unfortunately, it is ever more evident that this comfortable pact
between us rests upon weak foundations indeed.
When a child is born in Britain, as in most other developed countries,
its parents must register his or her birth. It is not made clear why
this is necessary, but it is legally obligatory. At the local council
website, it is politely explained that a new parent is required to
register a birth; it is not statedâanywhereâwhy. You are, however, told
that you will receiveâfree of charge!âa short birth certificate. Failure
to register a birth is a criminal offense, and can incur a hefty
penalty.
It is an ornate and archaic ritual. The harried parent must put aside
diapers and bottles in order to attend the local register office, which
can be many miles distant. When the appointment takes place, the
registrar will enter parentsâ and childâs details into a thick ledger, a
heavy book weighty with portentousness. In my case, the registrar had a
bulbous fountain pen with which to inscribe the birth date, location and
other minutiae. She took an evident pleasure in wielding this
instrument, carefully unscrewing the cap and lovingly poising the pen
above the thick vellum page for a second, the better for her, and me, to
contemplate the gravity of the registration moment.
In Britain, government first instructed its subject populace to register
births, deaths and marriages in 1538. The purpose then, of course, was
to monitor the population in order to maximize the collection of tax.
Today, if it is stated at all, the implied rationale for such
registration is the protection of the citizen.
The presence of government at these cardinal moments of lifeâits
beginning, its end, the entwining of oneâs life with another in
marriageâis rarely questioned, but assumed. In this way, government
inserts itself into the very foundation and fabric of our lives. With
self-assessed taxes, the individual is required to declare to government
almost every significant event of their lives.
Reading the registration form for my children (they are twins), I
noticed an odd question: Was the child, at birth, alive or dead? I
questioned the registrar. She confirmed that, indeed, parents of
still-born children are required to register their births. The
deadlineâsix weeksâis the same as for the births of living children. If
the parents of a dead child do not meet that deadline, they too must pay
a fine.
âWe are the ones weâve been waiting forâ was a compelling slogan from
the presidential election campaign of Barack Obama. It captured
something about his promise of change, but also, more subtly, spoke to
our deeper anxieties about the troubled state of democracy today. It
yoked these two ideas together to evoke, in eight words, the suggestion
that collective mass action by us could alter things at last. The
problem, however, is that the slogan contains a profound but unaddressed
contradiction: Even led by a man as enlightened and sophisticated as
Barack Obama, government is not about mass collective action; only
getting someone elected is.
During the campaign, Barack Obama gave a speech in a sports stadium in
Denver. Invesco Field, named after its corporate sponsor, had been
chosen over other smaller venues in anticipation of the enormous demand
to hear him. Only John F. Kennedy had managed to fill a stadium at such
a moment. This time, over eighty thousand people filled Invesco Field,
while thousands of others watched on huge video screens outside the
stadium and millions watched the event on television around the world.
The New York Times published an extraordinary panoramic picture of the
stadium crowd, composed of several shots taken over a short period.[42]
The picture deserves iconic status: It has an almost religious quality,
like a fresco on a cathedral ceiling. The photograph shows a vast and
diverse crowd, young and old, black and white: an astonishingly vivid
snapshot of Americans animated as never before in this generation by the
election of one man, the first African-American with a chance at the
presidency, the first Democrat after eight years of George Bushâs
Republicanism. The picture is moving and awe-inspiring, a visual
testament to the political energy and enthusiasm Obamaâs candidacy
unleashed.
During Obamaâs campaign, reportedly over a million people volunteered to
work for his election. This was a larger number than recorded for any
previous campaign. Obama raised $650 million for his campaign, the
largest amount ever raised; and also, significantly, from the greatest
number of donors. However, only a small proportion of Obamaâs funding
came from small individual donors. The vast bulk of the largest
donations, as usual with contemporary politics, came from the rich and
corporate donors, including banks and corporations like Goldman Sachs,
Microsoft, Citigroup and Google.[43] After his election, the Obama
administration, following traditional Washington form, appointed over
two dozen of the largest donors to the Democratic presidential campaign
to choice overseas ambassadorships.
The Denver crowd and the extraordinary mass effort mobilized by Obamaâs
campaign spoke of a hunger for change and a willingness to contribute to
it without precedent. The enthusiasm did not end with his election: An
astonishing ninety thousand people applied for the three thousand or so
political appointments in his administration.
Epitomized in the slogan âYes, we can,â Obamaâs campaign played upon
peopleâs desire for change as well as, crucially, for involvement in
politics. Both during the campaign and since, Obama urged people to
become involved in their communities, to volunteer and themselves help
fulfill the political promise of his election. But in this message there
was unadmitted contradiction. For what Obama was asking for, first and
foremost, was not for volunteers to improve their communities, but for
volunteers to campaign for his election. As if to highlight this awkward
fusion of objectives, one groupâObama Worksâwas set up for people to
volunteer for local activities in the name of Obamaâs campaign. Obamaâs
campaign call to local action was a secondary if necessary moral
buttress to his primary appeal for votersâ support. The political end of
his campaign was not change itself, but for him to be elected to deliver
change; a subtle but crucial distinction, and the disjunction at the
heart of representative democracy.
The night of Obamaâs election, a great roar could be heard across Lower
Manhattan when his victory became apparent. But the party atmosphere
soon dissipated. After Obamaâs election and the excitement of his
inauguration, you could almost sense the air going out of the balloon.
With the governmentâs encouragement, volunteering fairs were held across
the country. And while attendance was high, it was noted that this
enthusiasm was less a function of a new surge of political activism, but
more one of the rampant unemployment of the post-election months. In
Brooklyn, a few hundred turned up to a volunteering fair, where
thousands had been hoped forâin a borough numbering millions. Tellingly,
the fair was described as seeking to exploit energy âleft overâ from the
campaign.[44] Obama Works went into âhibernation.â Since then, there has
been no revolution in volunteering and community organizing. The
conventional model of politics has remained largely unchanged. As usual,
attention focuses on the intentions and utterances of a very small group
of people in the White House and a slightly larger group in Congress,
where the betrayals, ethos and peccadilloes of a small number of
representatives and senators determine the nature of legislation imposed
on a country of three hundred million people. Everyone else is left to
rant about their doings on websites or, more commonly, simply get on
with their lives with a shrug of the shoulders. It seems like the ones
weâve been waiting for wasnât us after all.
Some attribute this passivity to the inherently idle and feckless nature
of ordinary people: Some politicians I know are inclined to this
supposition. But in truth, the reason is that conventional
representative democracy, where the many elect the few, rests on a pact
between voters and government: We vote, they act; we get on with our
lives, they protect. This is the pact in which the parent must enroll
their baby after birth. It endures until death. This pact is rarely
examined nor is it anywhere clearly or fully stated; it is rarely
admitted to, though its effects are profound.
The pact has several layers. At the most fundamental, the pact implies
that government will protect its citizens; it will provide for their
security and safety. In return, citizens agree to limit some of their
freedom: They accept the rule of law, and with it, various restrictions
on their behavior. To government is reserved certain extreme powers and
rights, which are denied the rest of us. These include the power to deny
freedom to others, to imprison and to punish. In some countries, like
the U.S., this includes the power to kill in the name of justice. All
192 member states of the United Nations have agreed to a code to govern
this right to wage war, the UN Charter. But the charter is a voluntary
document and infringing it does not invoke automatic punishment,
especially if the infringer is a powerful state.
Domestically, the governmentâs commitment to provide security means that
government takes responsibility to preserve peace, prevent crime and
disorder, and to save the populace in times of grave peril, say, after
military attack or natural disaster. So far, the pact is familiar, and
echoes the theories of political philosophers down the ages, from Locke
and Hobbes, and earlier still, Plato.
Less familiar is the second layer of the pact, one that is less often
mentioned than the first, but one with more insidious effect. In
addition to protecting the population, government makes a further
commitmentâto take care of societyâs problems, including education, in
some states health care services, care for the elderly and disabled,
protection of the natural environment, including now the globeâs
atmosphere, and above all, providing for growth and employmentâto take
care of the economy. This commitmentâand its consequenceâare almost
never explicitly stated: Government will take care of these problems, so
we donât have to.
Instead of admitting this pact, politicians instead declare policies and
promises to manage these problems, much as Barack Obama did at Invesco
Field. But by declaring governmentâs intention to address such problems,
a politician is sending a powerful if concealed message: If government
is willing and able to sort out these problems, we the populace do not
need to worry. In Barack Obamaâs case, the message was carried a step
further: I the politician need your active involvementâto campaign,
raise money, etc.âin order to get elected, then I will be able to
address these problems.
Indeed, Obama raised the stakes a notch further: The mass involvement he
was able to activate through his candidacy exploited the massive
political energy and frustration of the progressive electorate: the
millions who volunteered for his campaign. His implicit message was
âMobilize to elect me and I will deliver.â
But the effects of the pact can be witnessed in what followed the
election. The mass of volunteers who mobilized to campaign for Obama by
and large threw away their badges and stayed at home, their job done.
There was no dramatic upswing in volunteering for social causes. Even in
electoral politics, hard-core party activists found that the âObama
effectâ had little long-term benefit in recruiting volunteers to fight
elections at the more local level. The long-run trend in volunteering
for social causes remains, as Robert Putnam and others have attested,
resolutely downward.[45] In general, we are doing less and less. And
here is one message that issued unintended but with subtle and powerful
force from the millions watching that one charismatic man at Invesco
Field. That vast crowd is watching, not acting. For most of us, politics
is a spectator sportâwe observe, they do.
The trouble with the pact is that it is breaking down. National
governments are less and less able to tackle the transnational and
global causes of the various problems that confront us. At the most
basic level of the pact, government is unable to guarantee protection
against terrorist attack; it is unable to provide an effective response
to prevent climate change; it is unable to manage the global causesâand
effectsâof economic volatility. In society, government is unable to slow
the seemingly inexorable rise in âantisocialâ behavior, a trend
evidenced, for example, in mounting attacks on bus drivers, but apparent
in other innumerable ways including the subtle yet palpable tension in
our public spaces. CCTV cameras on every corner do little to curb this
discomforting trend, though they provide ample proof of our absence of
trust in one another.
As a result, trust in politicians, never high, is declining. In Britain,
a well-known television presenter called the prime minister âa cuntâ in
front of a studio audience. Such disrespect is now commonplace in many
established democracies. In America and virtually every democratic
country, there is widespread disillusionment if not disgust with the
political classes, and with politics itself. In Germany, polling before
recent Bundestag (parliament) elections indicated that 18 percent of
voters would vote not for regular politicians but for a comedian playing
a politician.[46] The election campaign was dominated not by discussion
of education or economic policy, but by a scandal over a politician who
had used her government car to be driven on holiday to Spain. Commenting
on elections widely seen as âboring,â one voter said, âThereâs just no
belief that anything is going to change.â[47] In Iceland, widespread
disillusionment after the catastrophic impact of the financial crisis
saw a professional comic elected mayor of ReykjavĂk. In the U.S.,
antipathy toward politicians manifests itself mostly, as in most issues
in America, in partisan terms: The other sideâs politicians are venal,
corrupt and self-serving; the manifest failings of ours are overlooked.
The disintegration of the pact is exacerbated by a further damaging
phenomenon: the deepening chasm between voters and their
representatives. The evolution of democracy has been, in general, one
from direct democracy to representative democracy; from people
collectively deciding their affairs, to electing others to do so on
their behalf. But as representative democracy has evolved, so too has
the distance grown between voters and the decisions that affect them.
In every national democratic system, individual participation has been
reduced to mere occasional voting to choose legislators or the executive
(in the British system, these are one and the same election; in the U.S.
and other systems, they are separated). Today, the executive, in cahoots
with the legislature, manages society and the economy and the countryâs
international affairs. These highly complex decisions are taken not by
the population collectively, but by a small executive often comprising
only a few hundred people. This pyramidal, top-down structure produces
several inherent and thus inescapable features.
The competition to become one of the elite is intense and antagonistic,
and sometimes violent. It costs an estimated $1.5 million to win a seat
in the U.S. House of Representatives; in the Senate, $9 million.[48]
Once in power, legislators join lobbyists in ferocious competition to
gain the executiveâs attention and influence their decisions. The
evidence for this is clear in the growing professionalization of this
process, both of politicians and the industry established to influence
them. In Britain, many politicians have spent their whole professional
lives practicing nothing but politics, starting as researchers to
Members of Parliament, then graduating as MPs and sometimes government
ministers. David Cameron, elected Britainâs prime minister in 2010, has
never had any job outside of politics, unless one counts a brief stint
working in public relations. The leader of the opposition, Ed Miliband,
likewise. In Washington, every politician claims to be an âoutsiderâ as
they try to ride the antipolitics wave, but in reality very few are.
The contest to secure political influence has become increasingly
professionalized and has assumed the characteristics of an industry,
with professional associations and its own group interests: There are
now lobbyists representing the interests of lobbyists. In Washington,
the number of registered lobbyists has more than doubled since 2000, to
nearly thirty-five thousand in 2005.[49] While the recession may have
thinned their ranks, the ratio of lobbyists to legislators remains,
incredibly, hundreds of lobbyists to every member of Congress.
At the European Union in Brussels, an increasingly dominant source of
legislation affecting economic interests worldwide, no one seems able to
give precise numbers of professional lobbyists; most estimates, though,
place the number at about fifteen thousand. A former commissioner for
the EUâs most expensive and wasteful policy, agriculture, described
Brussels as a âparadiseâ for lobbyists.
One reason for the proliferation of business lobbyists is all too clear:
It pays to invest in influence. BP helped Liberal Democrat European
Parliament member Chris Davies draft climate change legislation that
secured a âŹ9 billion subsidy from European taxpayers, covering the
entire cost of new technology to convert from âdirtyâ coal-fired power
stations, saving energy firms from having to pay for it themselves. The
industry later gave Davies an award. Davies was at least open about the
process he conducted to prepare the new European laws, justifying his
actions by using a famous quotation often misattributed to Otto von
Bismarck: âThe public should never be allowed to see two things: how
sausages are made and how laws are made.â[50]
If this is the reality of the supposedly democratic legislative process,
it is unsurprising that popular enthusiasm for conventional politics is
waning. Membership of political parties, one measure of popular
participation in conventional politics, is in steep decline in all major
Western societies.[51] Global surveys confirm that while people in
general prefer democracy, they are less and less happy with the practice
of democratic government.[52] Voter turnout has been in long-term
decline in almost all democratic systems. In the last parliamentary
elections in France, for instance, turnout was the lowest ever recorded.
The European Parliament elections of 2009 suffered the same ignominious
outcomeâfewer voters turned out for them than in any election since the
parliamentâs inception. In the United States, 25 percent fewer people
vote in elections than they did in 1960, when John F. Kennedy was
elected
Despite the promises of politicians to limit the lobbying industry and
its influence, it has continued to grow. Its pernicious powerâan
inherent function of the reductive pyramid from voters to decidersâseems
greater than them. One of President Obamaâs first acts in government was
to appoint as deputy defense secretary a longtime lobbyist for Raytheon,
a top weapons contractor, despite Obamaâs campaign commitment to
prohibit any such appointments. In New York State, the successful
Democratic candidate for governor in 2010 proclaimed his forthright
opposition to special interests and lobbyists throughout his campaign,
yet the bulk of his campaign funding came from organized labor, real
estate firms and related industries like construction, the health care
sector and lobbying firms.[53]
In 2010, the Supreme Court, in its misleadingly named âCitizens Unitedâ
ruling, decided to allow commercial companies to pay directly for
political advertising, absurdly defining companies as having the same
rights as individuals, and overruling the existing feeble limits to curb
their influence. The ruling permitted corporations and other types of
organizations to raise large amounts and run political campaign ads
without revealing the source of funding. Sure enough, the 2010
congressional elections saw large influxes of money from these
unaccountable bodies, tilting the races for many seats. Professor
Lawrence Lessig has argued that the mutual dependency of lobbyists and
legislators is now so profound, and corrupt, that legislation is enacted
with the sole purpose of extracting rents from corporate interests.
Former senators have admitted the same thing: that all legislation is
made on âK Street,â the infamous Washington street where lobbyists have
their offices.[54] One observer estimates that the lobbying industry
spent $3.3 billion in just one year (2008).[55] Private companies that
run prisons now employ lobbyists to press for legislation requiring
judges to impose longer sentences.[56]
In Britain, the corrosive influence of lobbyists is better concealed and
less acknowledged. In a system where vast power is concentrated in the
prime ministerâs office, many of Tony Blairâs advisers left office for
highly paid executive positions in companies that had substantial
political interests in their earlier incarnation. One senior adviser
joined Morgan Stanleyâs investment banking division as a full-time
senior managing director. Another left her job in Blairâs inner team to
work for the oil giant BP.
Several of Blairâs press advisers formed a PR group on Blairâs departure
from office that now enjoys lucrative contracts with businesses, many of
which had clear interests in legislation delivered by the Blair
administration. After leaving office, Blair himself was awarded a
position as âsenior adviserâ to investment bank JPMorgan for a salary of
half a million pounds a year, a role to which he gave rather less
publicity than to his position as a peace envoy in the Middle East for
the so-called Quartet group of countries.[57]
Within the political class in Britain, there appears to be a tacit
understanding not to criticize such obvious conflicts of interest,
perhaps because other members of that class wish to leave themselves
that opportunity in future. The self-serving excuse, which can often be
heard sotto voce in Westminster, is that such rewards are a just payoff
for the supposedly poor pay and hard labor of a career in politics.
A similar unspoken understanding is clearly at work in Washington too,
where politicians âretireâ from their legislative duties as elected
officials to sell their contacts and networking expertise as lobbyists.
When former Democratic majority leader Senator Tom Daschle was
scrutinized by Congress to lead President Obamaâs health care effort, it
was revealed that he had earned over $5 million as a lobbying adviser to
various industries. Notably, it was not this blatant influence-peddling
that provoked the criticism that met his nomination, and ultimately
forced him to withdraw, but his failure accurately to declare for taxes
the gratis use of a limousineâone clientâs form of payment for his
services.
Meanwhile, former American ambassadors, after their years of public
service, sometimes return to Washington to act as paid lobbyists for the
very countries to which they used to represent U.S. interests, a naked
breach of ethics, not to speak of the risk to national security.[58] Two
senior officials from the Clinton administration, including the former
presidentâs legal counsel, later ended up as paid lobbyists for Laurent
Gbagbo, the former president of CĂŽte dâIvoire, whose refusal to
relinquish power after losing elections in 2011 led to widespread
violence costing hundreds of lives. These well-connected American
officials lobbied the State Department and White House on behalf of the
worst of tinpot dictators.[59]
Given the pernicious forces at work in the current political system, it
is unsurprising that the decisions produced are often grossly divorced
from the needs of electors, or even of the state itself. In the United
States, where the lobbying industry is most developed and where
politicians are highly dependent on campaign contributions, these
effects are most noticeable. For instance, members of Congress in 2009
demanded that the government purchase seven extra F-22 fighter aircraft,
at nearly a quarter of a billion dollars each, which the Department of
Defense itself had not requested. At this point, the U.S. was at war in
two countriesâIraq and Afghanistan. Although by that time already in
USAF service, the F-22 had not been used in either conflict. In the UK,
the government has been convinced by the defense industry to purchase
two enormous aircraft carriers to âmaintain Britainâs ability to project
force,â even though the carriers offer a far greater capability than
Britain has enjoyed for many decades, if not ever.
Trade sanctions are commonly instituted by the U.S. to pressure
countries that have committed some grievous breach of international
peace and security, or stand accused of âstate sponsorshipâ of
terrorism, like Iraq, Libya or Iran. Some American companies, however,
have managed to win exemptions to rules preventing trade with these
countries. Unsurprisingly, most are large companies with a commensurate
lobbying presence in Washington. Kraft Foods, Pepsi and some of the
nationâs largest banks have secured thousands of exemptions for their
products to be sold to countries like Iran, allowing them to do billions
of dollars of business despite tough measures to prevent commerce with
states that sponsor terrorism. Wrigleyâs chewing gum was classed as
âhumanitarian aidâ and thus exempted from sanctions, permitting millions
of dollars of sales to Iran and other sanctioned countries. One official
later admitted that while the government debated whether chewing gum
counted as food, and thus would be exempt, lobbyists too had played
their part: âWe were probably rolled on that issue by outside
forces.â[60]
On another patch of the carpet, the oil giant BP revealed that it had
âexpressed concernâ to the British government about slow progress in
diplomatic negotiations between Libya and Britain on the transfer of
prisoners, on the grounds that it might negatively affect BPâs oil
exploration contracts with the Libyan government. These contracts were
worth $900 million. The company claimed that such an expression, and
indeed its concern, had nothing to do with the incarceration of the
Lockerbie bomber Abdelbaset al-Megrahi, whom Libya was campaigning to
have transferred to Libya from his Scottish prison, where he had been
sentenced to life imprisonment for the 1988 Lockerbie bombing, which
killed two hundred seventy people.
BP admitted its intervention on the prisoner exchange issue only after
al-Megrahiâs transfer to Libya and following a public outcry. The delay
in the negotiation had been caused by the British governmentâs
insistence that the Lockerbie bomber be excluded from the prisoner
transfer agreement. It backed down, and no exclusion to the agreement
was specified. Al-Megrahi was transferred, much to the outrage of many
of the families of those killed.
Thanks to pressure from lobbyists and agricultural special interests,
the U.S. Department of Agriculture has spent millions of dollars, under
both Republican and Democratic administrations, encouraging the
consumption of cheese, including the promotion of extra-cheese Dominoâs
pizzas which contain 40 percent more cheese than âregularâ pizzas.
Pressing this foodstuff upon consumers is directly contrary to the
interests of citizens themselves, whose consumption of cheese, and with
it saturated fat, has tripled over the last thirty years. Other parts of
the government, including the Agriculture Departmentâs own nutrition
committee, meanwhile, are busy telling Americans to reduce their
consumption of highly saturated fats.[61] Perversely, the governmentâs
promotion of cheese is a direct consequence of consumersâ growing
preference for low-fat and nonfat milk and dairy products. This has
created vast surpluses of whole milk and milk fat, which the dairy
industry turned to the government to help offloadâas high fat cheese.
Thus, even as consumers exercise their own choice to eat less fat, the
government, pressured by cheese lobbyists (hilarious but true), exploits
the consequenceâunused high-fat milk and cheeseâto persuade the consumer
to eat more of it.
In a similar case in Britain, the government in 2011 published a list of
healthy eating guidelines, including the advice that consumers should
eat no more than 2.5 ounces of red and processed meat per day. The
Department of Health produced a list helpfully indicating several meaty
items alongside their respective weights. Alongside a cooked breakfast
and the Sunday roast and other common meals, only two branded products
were mentioned by name: Big Mac and Peperami. It just so happened that
both items came in under the limit. The previous November the government
had set up five âresponsibility dealâ networks with the food business to
come up with health policies. At the time, this was criticized as being
akin to letting Big Tobacco draft smoking policy. Two of the companies
were McDonaldâs and Unilever, who happen to be the manufacturers of the
Big Mac and Peperami, respectively.[62]
The political space is more and more occupied not by citizens, but by
big business and the wealthy. Not content with the purchase of lobbying
power in our nationsâ capitals, oil companies are using the political
techniques of environmental activists to promote their own interests, in
this case to prevent curbs on carbon emissions. In a memo leaked in
2009, the American Petroleum Institute, which represents the U.S. oil
industry, wrote to its member companies asking them to âmove
aggressivelyâ to stage up to twenty-two âEnergy Citizenâ gatherings,
mostly located, it turned out, in districts of representatives with slim
majorities. Without irony, the memo declared that the objective of the
demonstrations, which would be organized and funded by API, would be to
âput a human faceâ on the impacts of âunsoundâ energy policy, i.e.,
efforts to limit climate change.
Elsewhere, wealthy philanthropists use their foundations, and financial
pull, to promote their political preferences. The foundation of Wall
Street billionaire and Nixon administration Commerce Secretary Peter G.
Peterson, for instance, is seeking to address the issue of taxes,
deficits and fiscal responsibility, using advertising and public
appearances by foundation experts to educate the public and increase
engagement on the issue of the fiscal deficit. The foundationâs website
offers sample op-ed articles and letters to public officials and
editors, some of which have appeared in newspapers. All members of
Congress received a copy of a report by the foundation.[63] This is an
interesting twist on the traditional understanding of philanthropy; some
foundations now actâwith tax-free benefitsâas a kind of âforce
multiplierâ for the political preferences of the âphilanthropist.â These
activities may be beneficent, such as Bill Gatesâs efforts to improve
school curriculums, or malignant, but either form of influence shares
one common characteristicâit is accountable to no one.
It is not only big business that engages in the lobbying business. To
compete in the overcrowded and cacophonous halls of modern âdemocraticâ
legislatures, anyone with an axe to grind has to follow the same
tactics. At international conferences, invariably there are now âNGO
forumsâ to accommodate the scores and sometimes hundredsâas at the
Copenhagen climate conferenceâof organizations with views to present.
There is no assessment of the democratic legitimacy of these groups:
Some represent many millions of members; others are tiny, and represent
nobody apart from themselves. The more skillful use direct tactics to
get their message across to legislators: The National Rifle Association,
one of the most accomplished at this practice, maintains an online
roster of the voting patterns of members of Congress, âscoringâ them
according to their support ofâor hostility toâpro-gun positions. Such
tactics are now becoming commonplace across the political spectrum.
The number of nonprofits in the U.S. has increased by over 30 percent
between 1996 and 2008, to well over 1.5 million.[64] Such organizations
are today more likely to be located in Washington and have a subscriber
base of members who pay dues but do not attend or participate in local
meetings. There have been similar trends in Britain. Such organizations
are in effect turning political activity into a business, what some have
called a âbusiness of protest.â The organizational model for many
contemporary political nonprofit organizations now resembles that of a
commercial business, which defines its target audience, purchases
relevant mailing lists and advertising to reach that audience, and asks
minimal participation (usually just membership fees) from them to
achieve their lobbying goals.[65] Whereas active participation in
community organizations correlates with political participation, there
are no such âpositive externalitiesâ of paying membership dues to a
nonprofit. In essence, we are contracting out politics to be done by
others.
Common to these interest groups is that they are in general focused on
single, narrow issues: gun rights, fuel taxes, environmental protection,
abortion rights. Their aggressive tactics and sheer numbers fill the
domestic political space and have created a new culture of politics,
where legislators are confronted with a panoply of groups and lobbyists,
erecting a kind of wall between them and individual voters.
Such groups also contribute to a growing and unpleasant extremism in
political debate. Adept at one-sided presentation of the evidence, these
groups advocate black-and-white positions with aggressive vigor and
armfuls of one-sided researchâoften representing those who oppose them
as foolish and sometimes evil. The compromises inherently necessary in
political decision making thus become harder; deadlock becomes likelier.
Facts and reasoned analysis are invariably the victims.
One effect of these trends is the polarizing rise of partisanship. Many
have commented on the growing ugliness and vituperation of public
debate. For the first time in living memory, a lawmaker shouted, âYou
lie!â at the U.S. president when he spoke to both houses of Congress. It
is a long way from the method of the Indian âtalking stick,â introduced
by the Iroquois to Ben Franklin, and reportedly used by Americaâs
Founding Fathers, which requires participants to be able to articulate
one anotherâs position before having a chance to speak.
At the conservative National Review, which had prided itself on its
high-minded and thoughtful debate, the columnist Kathleen Parker
received eleven thousand e-mail messages when she argued in an article
during the 2008 presidential campaign that Governor Sarah Palin was
unfit to be vice president. One message lamented that her mother did not
abort her.[66] On the Internet, which some extol for its invigorating
heterogeneity and debate, it is clear that the opposite is also true:
Online, people tend to choose views that confirm their own.[67] There
are even dating sites to accommodate lonely hearts distinguished by
their political views.
In Britain, recent elections saw the first ever accession to a
parliamentary seatâin the European Parliamentâof a far-right party with
the victory of the British National Party. In the U.S., Republicans and
Democrats are increasingly choosing to live apart from one another, and
locate themselves with others of similar political views.[68] Red and
blue are now more starkly drawn than ever.[69]
The polarization of political views, the intercession of business,
lobbyists and interest groups between voters and their representatives,
the growing number and power of political actors who are neither
politicians nor conventional political parties, nor accountable to
anyone but themselves yet nonetheless wield considerable
influenceâtogether, these factors suggest a deepening divide between the
public and their nominal representatives. They suggest nothing less than
a crisis in democracy.
The pact between citizen and government is never explicit. You can spend
an entire life paying taxes, obeying laws, without once being asked
whether you wish to contract into or out of it. Government insists upon
your registration at birth, and to be notified upon your death. At no
point does it seek your consent. You never get the chance to contract
into the pact: Your parents are legally obliged to do so on your behalf
whether they like it or not. And there is only one way to contract out.
The pact rests on one central pillar (and, oddly, it is the same whether
a country is democratic or not)âthat government more or less represents
the collective interests of the populace. The democratic process
providesâin theory at leastâfor continual feedback, as Karl Popper once
theorized, from governed to governors, the only way, Popper believed, to
optimize policy so that it reflects the needs and preferences of the
people. But if that feedback is interrupted, government policy, at best
approximate to the collective wishes of the people, starts to diverge.
People and government become estranged. When this happens, the pact
breaks down. The evidence is accumulating in the twenty-first century
that this is indeed happening.
If government cannot provide for the stability, safety and just
arbitration of our common affairs, who can? The answer is both radical
and discomforting. For there is only one alternative if government
cannot successfully provide: We must do so ourselves. Self-organized
government is one term; another, rather more loaded term, is anarchism.
But this is not the anarchism of early twentieth-century bomb-wielding
Russians, or nihilists charging police lines at G8 summits. It is a
different vision, of individuals and groups peacefully organizing their
affairs, arbitrating necessary business directly with one another,
guided by their conviction and direct experienceânot by party political
dogma. It is more evolution than revolution, for it is dawning on people
across the world that in order to fix our problems, there is no one to
look to but ourselves. The minimalist act of voting is looking less and
less adequate as a solution.
This vision may animate people, but it does not prescribe. Instead, this
new way of doing things is just thatâa way of doing things, a method,
and emphatically not an end in itself, nor a design to be imposed upon
others. Only a fool would wish the abrupt or violent overthrow of the
current system, for the certain result would be violent chaosâanarchy of
the worst kind.
But if itâs true that government is less and less able to manage our
collective affairs, it seems we have little choice but to take that
burden upon our own shoulders. We must learn anew to look to ourselves
to produce the effects we desire, to take responsibility for ourselves
and for others, and to cooperate and negotiate with each other, instead
of leaving that arbitration to an evidently imperfect mechanism. As
these habits spread, a new and more durable order may emerge, notâas
nowâlegislated from above but built from the ground up, by people acting
upon their beliefs and engaging with each other.
For curiously, it is perpetuation of the existing way of doing things,
not anarchism, that may pose the greater risk to our peace and security.
It is the alienation of government from people, and us from each other,
that more endangers our fragile stability. It is no coincidence that
this is the commonest criticism of anarchism, that it engenders
disorder, that Anarchy = Chaos. Let us examine this, most serious,
objection to this different way of doing things.
When the trouble first ignited in March 2004, I was in Geneva, at a
conference designedâironically, it turned outâto promote reconciliation
between Kosovoâs Albanians and Serbs. An adviser to Kosovoâs prime
minister, a friend, drew me aside: âThree Albanian children have been
killed,â she whispered conspiratorially, âby a Serb.â With deliberate
portent, she added, âThere will be trouble.â Curiously, she seemed
excited by the news. It was as if she was relieved that, at last,
something was happening.
Next day, back in Pristina, Kosovoâs capital where I then lived, it was
clear that her premonition was correct.[70] Tension was palpable in that
cityâs polluted air, straining peopleâs faces. The rumors were
widespread, amplified by irresponsible journalists: A Serb had driven
three children to their deaths, the reporters claimed, by drowning.[71]
Not only that, but they had died that horrible death in the Ibar, the
very river dividing Serb and Albanian halves of Mitrovica, Kosovoâs most
divided city.
That afternoon, at UN headquarters where I worked, we received reports
of crowds gathering in towns and villages across the province. Suddenly,
the security guards announced over the office loudspeakers that a large
group of young men was approaching the headquarters. Soon, their
chanting âU-Ă-K! U-Ă-K! U-Ă-K!ââroughly, Ooh-Chay-Kahâreverberated
around the building, loud and aggressive. âUĂKâ is the abbreviation for
the Kosovo Liberation Army, the Kosovo-Albanian guerrillas who resisted
Slobodan MiloĆĄeviâs repression, including during the 1999 war that led
to the withdrawal of Yugoslav forces.
Without warning, the loudspeakers announced that the building was
immediately to be evacuated. But there was no information on how the
evacuation should proceed or where the UN staff would go. There was a
sudden and anxious sense of panic. People began to run up and down
corridors. Mobile phones stopped workingâit was later discovered that
the riots had overloaded the networks, partly because some had used
their phones to organize the riots. For some reason, the elevators
stopped functioning too. Some began to weep, perhaps with fear.
I was with my wife, who had come to my office for its greater security.
My Albanian assistant, Besnik, took charge and ushered us down the fire
escape and into a car. We drove out of the compound and back to our
house. On the streets, groups of young people were gathering. Many were
children. They looked excited and agitated. That night, the groups
merged into mobs.
I had agreed that evening to take part in a television discussion with
political leaders at the main television station in Pristina. As we set
out driving to the studio, near our house a large mass of people blocked
the streets. It was dark and I could not tell their number. The mass
swelled and shifted; it had a shape and intent beyond its individual
components. There was shouting and the bangs of what I thought at the
time were firecrackers. I later realized it was gunfire. There were no
police in sight.
The television debate was ugly. Along with an American diplomat, I
argued that the riots must stop immediately. Parents should tell their
children to go home. But the political leaders from Kosovoâs Albanian
majority did not agree. According to them, the trouble was the UNâs
fault. In their version, the riots had been triggered by the UNâs
decision to allow Serb protesters from a village nearby Pristina to
block one of the main roads to the south.
The Kosovo-Albanian leaders argued that the anger on the streets was
legitimate protest at the many injustices Kosovars had suffered, past
and present. From the tenor and aggression of the debate, it was clear
that some of the leaders sensed a revolutionary moment where the UN, the
de facto power in Kosovo, might be overthrown. They grasped the tail of
the tiger. By the end of the program, my back was in painful spasm from
the tension gripping me. I returned home through a city smoldering with
violence.
Back at home with some Albanian friends, we sat listening to the gunfire
and occasional explosions. A red glow appeared at our window. We looked
out to see sparks and flames spurting into the air nearby. We realized
it was the Serbian church at the top of our street, aflame. There was an
awful sound: a bell ringing incessantly.
After a while, when things seemed calmer, my friend Ardi suggested we go
out to see what was going on. We walked up our street to the church. It
was ablaze like a summer bonfire, its steeple a column of fire. On top,
the church bell rang with a desperate rhythm. The heat was somehow
making it ring. Fortunately, there was no one still inside the blazing
building. At last the bell stopped. Scores of young men surrounded the
church. Their work done, many were sitting, gazing at the fire, smoking
and chatting. Someone was selling cigarettes.
We walked away. Ardi, a Kosovo-Albanian, would not look at me. He was
beside himself with anger and shame. Spent cases of plastic bullets and
rifle cartridges crunched under our feet. The UN riot police had
confronted the mob here. But they had been overwhelmed and retreated,
leaving the church to its fate. All across Kosovo, the forces of law and
orderâthe UN and local police and NATO peacekeepersâhad lost control. In
one town, a contingent of German soldiers had remained in barracks while
a mob of thousands roamed the town for hours, moving from district to
district, picking out Serb churches, houses and UN offices, ransacking
buildings and putting them to the torch. When we later visited the town,
we saw at its center a blackened hillside, studded with the shells of
burnt-out houses, as if a forest fire had swept through it.
The next day, the violence continued. There were reports of buses
transporting rioters around the province to attack different Serb
enclaves. In southern Kosovo, a large mob was prevented from besieging a
Serb Orthodox monastery by the intervention of a local Albanian former
KLA guerrilla leader (he was later to become Kosovoâs prime minister).
In the divided town of Mitrovica, where the Albanian children had
drowned, NATO troops shot and killed several Albanians trying to cross
the river to attack Serbs in the northern part of the city. Riots went
on around the country into the night. Every UN office in the territory
was attacked, more than a hundred fifty UN vehicles were destroyed. At
least 550 homes and twenty-seven Orthodox churches and monasteries were
burned, and more than four thousand peopleâmostly Serbs, but also Roma
and other minority groupsâwere driven from their homes.[72]
Eventually, the violence died down. Local political leaders claimed that
their calls to end the turmoil had worked, rarely confessing that these
entreaties had been made under pressure from international officials.
But in truth it appeared more that the chaos and violence had simply
petered out. On the streets, the rhythm and the momentum of the violence
pulsed through the city. Before the violence erupted, you could feel it
build up as an urge needing expression. As the violence played out, that
dark energy was ventilated. As it ended, somehow you could tell that the
force that had driven the chaos and rage had at last been exhausted.
It is commonly held that society requires authority in order to enjoy
peace and stability. Without such institutionsâlaw, the police, the
armyâsociety will collapse into anarchy and disorder; the many will fall
victim to the criminal few. In case we need reminding of what this might
be like, movies abound with depictions of anarchy, even if often
perpetuated by zombie hordes (28 Days Later, I Am Legend) or provoked by
alien invasion (War of the Worlds). Either way, the anarchy shown is
entertainingly terrifying. It seems there is only a fragile veil
dividing us from the jungle. Television offers ceaseless titillating
depictionâboth real and falsifiedâof the criminals who lurk to destroy
us, but for the thin blue line of law and order to hold them back.
But in these illustrations lies a clue. There is scant entertainment
involved in the real and actual horrors of humanityâthe Holocaust, the
Khmer Rougeâs âYear Zeroâ or the butchery of Charles Manson. If anarchy
were so close, and so awful, we wouldnât find its Hollywood depiction
entertaining; instead, we would find it horribly frightening,
unwatchable.
One criticism of anarchism as a political strategy is so ubiquitous that
it merely requires a reshaping of the word: anarchism = anarchy. Without
a superstructure of institutions to maintain order, it is claimed,
disorder and chaos will surely resultâHobbesâs âwar of all against all.â
This is indeed a frightening prospect that few dare contemplate. When
disaster strikes, like an earthquake in Haiti or a hurricane in New
Orleans, it is never long before commentators, safe in their television
studios, issue dire warning of social disorder and breakdown, as if this
is more frightening than the original natural disaster. In post-Katrina
New Orleans, reports of carjackings, rapes and murders flooded the news.
Thousands of law enforcement agents were deployed from other states as
Louisianaâs governor warned, âThey have M16s and are locked and loaded.
These troops know how to shoot and kill and I expect they will.â Police
in one suburb neighboring the flooded city were so alarmed at the
prospect of looters and other malcontents that they blocked the bridge
from the city, preventing the hungry and desperate from getting help.
Others cold-bloodedly shot fleeing refugees.
As the essayist Fareed Zakaria has noted, the federal governmentâs
fastest and most efficient response to Hurricane Katrina was the
creation of a Kafkaesque, GuantĂĄnamo-like prison facility in which
twelve hundred American citizens were summarily detained and denied any
of their constitutional rights for months.[73] Later accounts, such as
Dave Eggersâs Zeitoun, told stories ignored at the time, like that of
Abdulrahman Zeitoun, who after the hurricane paddled around the flooded
city in a canoe offering help, ferrying neighbors to higher ground and
caring for abandoned pets, only to be arrested by National Guardsmen and
held incommunicado for several weeks without charge and without medical
attention along with other Arab-American companions.
But as Rebecca Solnit has written, disasters in fact often produce the
opposite of disorder in human society: instead of violence and anarchy,
community and solidarity.[74]
A recent letter to the Financial Times makes a common claim: that
civilization is fundamentally fragile and requires government to protect
it. The correspondent cites the example of the arrival of the mutineers
from the Bounty on the isolated Pacific island of Pitcairn:
When the nine Bounty mutineers and 17 Tahitian men and women arrived
there in 1789 it was as close to the Garden of Eden as anywhere in the
real world: generously endowed with water, sunshine and fertile soils,
and uninhabited by anyone else. The perfect test of Hobbes versus
Rousseau. In the event, Hobbes won. The British sailors fought among
themselves and tried to subjugate the Tahitians. The Tahitians resisted
and fought among themselves.
By 1800, 11 years later, only one of the mutineers, nine Tahitian women,
and many children were left, most of the others having died unnatural
deaths. The surviving mutineer created political order by establishing
not just an autocracy but a theocracy, with himself as the link between
God and man.â[75]
The writer concludesâquite reasonably, given the episode he offers as an
exampleâby emphasizing âthe importance of continued efforts to sustain
governance organizations that bring together the specific interests that
count most in the definition of a common (national, regional, global)
interest, in order that, through repeated interaction, convergent
interests will prevail over divergent ones.â
The writerâs conclusion is entirely correct. Unfortunately, however, it
is not clear that contemporary political institutions, whether national
or international, do in fact successfully give sufficient attention to
the common interests of humanity. Instead, itâs increasingly evident
that these institutions instead elevate the interests of the most
powerful interest groups over collective interests, and neglect
long-term primary needs, including the environment.
One can also argue that the worst outrages in human history occurred not
in the absence of authority and government, but were instead perpetrated
by governments claiming to act in the common interest: Nazi Germany,
Stalinist Soviet Union, Khmer Rouge Cambodiaâthe list is a very long
one. The criminal acts undertaken by these governments were permitted
and in fact ordered in the name of the collective interest; the
individual perpetrators were thus rendered immune. Democratic
governments are also fully capable of terrible crimes, legitimized by
governmentâs ultimate moral immunity of droit dâĂ©tat, or âstate
interestâ (on this, more later). But in any case, the correspondentâs
argument is widely shared: Institutions protect us against ourselves,
above all against what would otherwise prevailâchaos and disorder.
Itâs worth examining this specific proposition in more detail by taking
the opposite case: a thought experimentâimagine a world without
institutions. And let us take a difficult context: the sometimes venal
and secretive world of financial investment.
The gigantic Ponzi scheme orchestrated by the financier Bernard Madoff
was the worldâs largest fraud ever perpetrated by one man. It ruined
thousands of investors and symbolized the most grotesque excesses of
Wall Street. Despite the abject failure to catch Madoff by the
government body established to police and regulate the investment
industry, it was almost universally agreed that the best way to prevent
such crimes in future was tighter regulation and scrutiny of the
investment industry. The overwhelming reaction was that the government
should have protected the innocent investors: Something must be done!
But there may be an alternative approach that overturns every assumption
we have about how to deter, prevent and punish such crimes in future. It
may be that the very rules and institutions established to protect us in
fact do the opposite.
Madoffâs fraud was simple. He encouraged investors to deposit money with
his firm, paying them returns that were consistently higher than the
going rate. With the appeal of above-market and above all steady
returns, Madoff had little difficulty in attracting new investors. Their
fresh deposits would be used to fund returns to the earlier investors.
All the scheme required was a never-ending flow of new investors, with
deposits sufficient to fund the above-market returns to the earlier
investors, and to pay off the occasional depositor who wished to
withdraw their whole investmentâand for obvious reasons, those wishing
to withdraw from this cash cow of easy money were few.
Madoff and his co-conspirators manufactured a huge volume of falsified
reports and data to pretend that their fraudulent scheme was in fact a
legitimate and highly successful investment business. Madoffâs cover was
effective. On three occasions in the 1990s, he was elected chairman of
the NASDAQ. By his own admission, he perpetrated this massive fraud for
nearly two decades, and was uncovered only when the precipitous market
collapses at the end of 2008 prevented him from raising the funds to pay
off those wishing to withdraw their money. In the end, it was estimated,
Madoffâs fraud cost his investors perhaps $20 billion.
Less simple is why a scheme of such magnitude and pervasive dishonesty
succeeded for so long. Madoff lied systematically both to his investors
and to the supervising federal authorities. In this criminal endeavor,
he was apparently assisted by colleagues, some of whom have been
prosecuted or face further investigation. But the scale of profits from
his fund should have provoked more intrusive suspicion; few others
within the industry tried to work out how his company could consistently
make such high profits, against market trends, outperforming all
competitors year after year.
The institutions designed to prevent such crime completely failed. The
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the federal body established
in the 1930s to supervise the investment industry, conducted several
investigations. Madoff himself has later said that he had âhundredsâ of
contacts with SEC staff.[76] Prompted by tip-offs from others in the
industry who questioned Madoffâs fantastic profits, the SEC failed,
however, to uncover the crime.
A later report on how the SEC missed Madoff found many failings: Staff
were overspecialized, devoted to particular subsets of fraud and
rewarded for pursuing that particular kind of crime.[77] Different parts
of the SEC investigating Madoff were unaware of each other. Each
individual part cleared Madoff of other allegations against him.
Together, they managed to miss the big picture.
Elsewhere, the report revealed not only that SEC staff were often
incompetent in understanding Ponzi schemes, but that Madoff intimidated
SEC investigators because of his stature on Wall Street. The
investigation at one point describes investigators as âenthralledâ by
Madoff: Some of them asked Madoffâs staff if they could work for
him.[78]
This failure appears part of a disquieting pattern. It was only after
the BP Gulf oil spill of 2010 that the many failings of the body
assigned to monitor and regulate the oil industry surfaced. In the
aftermath of the disaster, it emerged that the Minerals Management
Service (MMS) had allowed BP to skip environmental assessments ahead of
drilling the well that spewed millions of barrels of oil into the Gulf.
MMS inspectors had also permitted oil company employees to fill out
inspection forms in pencil, which they would then ink in. Others had
accepted illegal gifts, consumed drugs and literally gone to bed with
officials from the companies they were supposed to regulate.[79] One
inspector had negotiated a job with an oil company while at the same
time inspecting the companyâs operations.
With Madoff, the financial industryâs own self-regulatory bodies did
nothing to investigate or stop his suspiciously profitable activities.
This was unsurprising given that Madoff was a prominent member of many
of them. Madoff was at various times chairman or board member of the
National Association of Securities Dealers, a self-regulatory securities
industry organization. The Madoff family had longstanding, high-level
ties to the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, the
primary securities industry organization. Madoffâs brother Peter served
two terms as a member of this organizationâs board of directors.
Madoff was regarded as a dominant figure in the investment industry, one
of the largest âmarket makersâ at the NASDAQ. He and his company were
major political donors: Notably, he gave nearly a quarter of a million
dollars to both Democrats and Republicans, indicative not of any
political preference, but more a naked purchase of influence. Some have
suggested that his political connections, and links to the SEC, helped
deter a more thorough investigation of his activities.
The testimony of financial analyst and would-be Madoff whistleblower
Harry Markopolos to Congress, after the fraud was uncovered, was
revealing. Giving evidence to the House of Representatives capital
markets subcommittee, Markopolos said that he had investigated Madoff on
behalf of a group of private investors.[80] After only a short
examination of the numbers, he came to the conclusion that Madoffâs
spectacular returns could be explained only by one investment technique:
fraud. Markopolos testified that for nine years he had repeatedly tried
to get the SEC to investigate and shut down the Madoff Ponzi scheme. The
SEC had not only ignored these warnings, according to Markopolos, but
was fundamentally incapable of understanding the complex financial
instruments being traded in the twenty-first century. And here lies one
clue to what might be done to prevent such crime in future.
Another lies in an uncompromising look at the investors themselves. Many
suffered terribly from Madoffâs fraud, losing life savings, being forced
to sell homes or return from a well-earned retirement to work
indefinitely, their nest egg stolen. In many cases, their lives were
utterly ruined. But why did these investors give their money to Madoff
without the most cursory scrutiny of his company? Madoffâs returns were
so implausible that any sensible investor should have held back, but
many committed their entire life savings. Harry Markopolos told Congress
that investing in Madoff was a âno-brainerâ in that âyou had to have no
brains whatsoever to invest into such an unbelievable performance record
that bears no resemblance to any other investment managerâs track record
throughout recorded human history.â
Some commentators have suggested that one of Madoffâs techniques was to
hint at a vague air of wrongdoing to help justify his otherwise
inexplicable returns. The right to invest in his company was by
invitation only, creating an air of desirableâand perhaps
disreputableâexclusivity, that something special was going on, maybe
something if not illegal then a little bit questionable: insider-trading
perhaps, of some kind. For several years, potential investors who
approached Madoff were told that the fund was âclosed.â Such false
allure is the classic sign of a Ponzi scheme.
In The New York Times, business commentator Joe Nocera has argued that
for these investors to blame the government for their decision to give
every last penny to Bernie Madoff âis like a child blaming his mother
for letting him start a fight while she wasnât looking.â[81] But here
lies one explanation of why people may have invested in Madoff. The mere
existence of the SEC, with its claim to supervise, scrutinize and
protect, must inevitably lower peopleâs own sensitivity to risk. If the
teacher is present, what is going on in the playground must be, in some
way, acceptable.
Research suggests that when measures are in place to protect people from
risk, they tend to indulge in more risky behavior. In his 2006 book
Government Failure Versus Market Failure, Clifford Winston, an economist
at the Brookings Institution, cites considerable and diverse research
which shows, for instance, that people drive faster in vehicles that
feel safer, cycle more dangerously when they wear helmets and take less
care bathing infants when using child seats designed to reduce the risk
of drowning.
This research makes sense. We tend to lower our guard when told that the
coast is clear. Indeed, so evident is this fundamental human tendency
that one can make a further, and perhaps provocative, presumption: that
criminal frauds like Madoff are actually made more feasible by the
presence of institutional authorities designed to prevent them. The
evidence for this seemingly outrageous claim is in front of our noses:
The fraud happened, right under the SECâs nose.
Moreover, as the Madoff example has clearly shown, it is naive to expect
any single authority to keep up with the massive complexity and dynamic
changes of an industry like securities investment. There is a
fundamental and insoluble imbalance in such supervision. Government
bodies suffer the constant depredations of budget cycles, cuts and the
intrinsic disadvantages of employers who can offer salaries equivalent
to only a tiny proportion of those available in the industry they
supervise. Given this fundamental and persistent power imbalance, it is
surprising not that institutions like the SEC fail, as they regularly
do, but that investors expect such institutions to keep up with the
free-wheeling, greed-tainted and secretive world of securities
investment.
On the broader scale, it is often claimed that the recent global credit
crisis was caused by the absenceâor more precisely, the withdrawalâof
the correct controls on the financial industry. It is persuasively
argued that it was the proliferation of certain financial instruments,
collectively known as derivatives, and specifically âcredit default
swapsâ (or CDSs), which helped spread the poison of the subprime
mortgage crisis across the world. CDSs are essentially legalized
gambling: They are bets on whether certain financial indices, like
mortgage repayments or stock prices, will rise or fall; a financial
instrument that Warren Buffett has called âfinancial Weapons of Mass
Destruction.â Some have called them the twenty-first-century version of
the âbucket shopsâ of the 1920s where people could bet on whether stocks
could rise or fall without actually owning those stocks. The bucket
shops were blamed for the wild speculation that helped fuel the Wall
Street Crash of 1929. They were subsequently outlawed. In 2000, Congress
passed a little known law that essentially permitted such betting again.
As for the industryâs own alleged safeguards, banks paid the ratings
agencies to rate and thus endorse the mortgage-based investment
instruments that âsliced and dicedâ and concealed and spread the
dangerous risk of subprime lending.
Many commentators have therefore reasonably concluded that the obvious
answer is further regulation, to ban CDSs and rely on legislation to
tame the industry. The problem with this analysis, however, so tempting
in these turbid days, is that it rests on an assumption about the
legislative process that is perilous indeed: that legislators act upon
the interests of voters, and no one else. The law in question, the
Commodity Futures Modernization Act, was passed in 2000 by a Democratic
administration; it was proposed by the Clinton administration and passed
quickly through both Houses. Not one member of Congress raised
objections to this particular provision, which was secreted away in a
bill of many hundreds of pages. Needless to say, that year the financial
services industry, which strongly supported the bill, contributed large
amounts to both Democrats and Republicans.
After the crash, politicians on both sides of the Atlantic roared their
populist anger against the banks and mortgage companies that helped
precipitate the crisis, then demanded massive government bailouts for
their companies, while continuing to pay their executives grotesque
bonuses. In all countries, political leaders queued up to decry the
greed and swear their commitment to legislation that would ânever againâ
allow such abuse to recur. But out of this bellowing public rage, the
legislation actually delivered resembled more a mouseâs squeak.
The legislation is complex. In the U.S., the bill finally passed in July
2010, allegedly to âreform Wall Street,â is a document of thousands of
pages.[82] Many of its provisions are highly technical in nature,
allowing politicians to claim to an ill-informed public that the new law
amounts to more than it in reality is. The press, in its complacency as
the âfourth estateâ in the body politic, did little to inquire into and
explain the complexities. For instance, much was made of the
prohibitions against âproprietary tradingâ; most people would have no
clue what this actually is.
In fact, this prohibition, in any case very limited, will do almost
nothing to prevent the kind of collapse that the global economy
experienced in 2008 and 2009. Within months of the âreform Wall Streetâ
legislation, banks were finding ways to circumvent this âVolcker ruleâ
to limit tradingâperhaps better known as bettingâon their own accounts:
precisely the activity that helped bring down Lehman Brothers in
2007.[83]
Most financial commentators agreed that there was one simple and easily
explicable measure that would surely have limited the ability of banks
to create the chaos that they did: limits on capital-to-loan ratios,
i.e., require banks to hold more capital relative to their lending. In
the confusion and obscurity of new measures, such rules were largely
absent or, if present, in watered-down form. Instead, in a telltale
signal that the necessary tough decisions had been dodged, Congress set
up new bodies, and new mechanisms, to deal with these problems in the
future. Likewise, amendments designed to address the problem of banks
âtoo big to fail,â by limiting their capital and thus the risk they pose
to the whole economy, were rejected. Instead of passing the necessary
measures in the immediate aftermath of the crash, when they might have
been politically possible, the congressional legislation empowers a new
regulatory body to pass them in future, when without doubt still less
political support will be available. In a sure sign that the legislation
was indeed to the benefit, not detriment, of the banks, shares in all
financial service companies significantly rose immediately after the
Senate vote.
Meanwhile, at the global level, neither the G20 nor the global banking
regulatory mechanism, the Basel Committee, have managed to agree on
measures to ensure that banks hold sufficient deposits against lending.
The âBasel IIIâ proposals in 2010, celebrated by the banking industry as
a major step forward, were judged by a more independent and
disinterested group of distinguished academic finance experts as âfar
from sufficient to protect the system from recurring crises.â[84] Clive
Crook in the Financial Times commented that the new Basel rules were an
improvement on the preceding arrangements, but ânot by much.â[85]
The reason for this failure is not hard to find. As soon as anyone
suggested more effective measures, like higher capital-to-lending
ratios, legions of banking industry spokesmen would rise as one to
complain that such requirements would render U.S. financial companies
âuncompetitiveâ in the global market place. The CEO of JPMorgan Chase,
for instance, wailed that new financial regulation including stricter
capital controls would be the ânail in the coffinâ of big American
banks, adding for good measure that this would âgreatly diminish
growth.â[86] This was a powerful argument in a country deeply mired in
recession. But the argument rarely needed to be publicly advocated:
There was precious little public debate on the bill, since politicians,
both Democrats and Republicans, conspired to pretend that the bill had
sharp teeth when in fact it was but a set of crummy plastic dentures.
This too was unsurprising, since the financial industry had taken care
to donate generously to both sides. In advance of the congressional
bill, financial institutions spent $1.4 million a day on lobbying; they
had hired seventy former Congress members to their payroll, and 940
former federal employees. Senator Scott Brown, a Republican from
Massachusetts, raked in âoff-the-chartsâ donations from the financial
industry while working to water down the financial bill.[87] On the
Democratsâ side, President Obamaâs then budget director, Peter Orzsag,
left the White House and waited a seemly four months before joining
Citibank, which of course was busy marketing new credit cards to
indebted Americans.
The congressional debate was in fact not a substantive discussion of
what was really required to prevent another financial meltdown in the
future. It was instead a kind of theatrical performance presented for
the publicâs benefit to reassure them that âsomething was being done.â
The Republican chairman of the House Financial Services Committee,
Spencer Bachus, soon afterward remarked with refreshing candor that âmy
view is that Washington⊠[is] there to serve the banks.â
The answer then may be to do the one thing that no one seems prepared to
contemplate: Take away the teacher in the playground. Let anarchy reign.
Itâs interesting to contemplate what might follow. Some pointers are
already available: in the behaviors and systems that have grown up on
the World Wide Web.
On eBay and other online marketplaces, there are few certain methods to
prevent fraud. Itâs easy for a seller to take payment online for
imperfect or nonexistent products then disappear into the anonymous
jungle of the Internet. When eBay began, the anonymity of the Web did
little to produce trust. On the contrary, buyers and sellers were quick
to complain about each otherâoften directly to Pierre Omidyar, the
founder of eBay, who in the early days would answer customer service
complaints himself. He was soon overwhelmed with the volume of
complaints.
Omidyar decided to introduce a system under which eBay participants
could rate each other onlineânot just to say when they were
dissatisfied, but when they were happy, too. This feedback system is one
of eBayâs most well-known features: Sellers advertise their positive
ratings as a selling point. Sellers without positive ratings struggle to
find buyers. Thus, there is a huge incentive for sellers and buyers to
treat each other well, if they are to do any repeat business. And
interestingly, like the accumulation of friends on Facebook, which takes
months and years to build up, the accumulation of trust indicators
within this system is also a huge barrier to entry for prospective
competitors to eBay.
The ideaâand effectâwas to incentivize sellers to behave well: to
deliver what they sold promptly and in good order. The system seemed to
work. Introduction of the ratings system helped drive a massive increase
in transactions on eBay and a reduction in the number of fraud charges
arising from eBay purchases.
In China, things have worked slightly differently, but prove the same
point. Here, eBay lost market share to a competitor that understood
better how customers wanted to build trust with one another. On its
Chinese site, eBay did not offer ways for buyers and sellers to chat
online, fearing they would close their transactions off the site to
avoid paying fees. By contrast, eBayâs rival service, Taobao.com,
understood that live conversations were necessary for Chinese consumers
to cultivate trust, and offered an instant-message service to allow them
to haggle over deals. eBay forfeited the Chinese online market to Taobao
partly as a result.
The online classifieds site Craigslist did something similar to eBay,
following the philosophy of its founder, Craig Newmark, that âpeople are
good and trustworthy and generally just concerned with getting through
the day.â[88] All you have to do is build a minimal infrastructure and
let them work things out for themselves. The primary mechanism of the
site is the red flag: If other users flag an unacceptable advertisement
enough times, it will disappear. The mission of Craigslist is simple: to
enable local, face-to-face transactions. This formula clearly works
despite the many aesthetic flaws and frustrations of Craigslist. It is
by far the most popular community site in the U.S., and is reportedly
viewed by forty-seven million unique users each month.
The very openness of the Web, however, has brought to the surface some
of mankindâs worst aspects. But with the transparency, others are
learning to combat the most undesirable and sometimes criminal
activities.
For instance, in 2010, campaigners demanded that Craigslist remove its
âAdult servicesâ section because it was being used by sex traffickers to
pimp underage girls. Craigslist at first refused, citing its commitment
to freedom of speech, but eventually succumbed to the pressure and
removed the offending section. Likewise, Amazon removed a self-published
book on pedophilia after mass Twitter and e-mail protests. In both
cases, the action to address the offense took place with no government
intervention.
Small businesses everywhere must rapidly adapt to a world where their
services and products are discussed openly and critically on the Web by
customers. Discomforting for some, the enforced visibility and criticism
on the Web is proving for others a liberation, and a sales advantage.
The evidence is mounting that of two otherwise identical businesses, the
one that responds quickly and positively, and above all transparently,
to customer complaints online, will rapidly gain the better online
ratings, with positive consequences for their likely sales.
A new phenomenon is emerging on the Internet, which one commentator has
called the âPanopticon.â[89] The original Panopticon was an imaginary
prison, designed by Jeremy Bentham, where all parts of the prison were
visible from one central point, without the prisoners knowing that they
were under observation at any particular moment. But the Panopticon of
the Internet is not for the observation by one of many, but more of âall
watching all.â As our lives are lived increasingly online, so are our
traces apparent. More and more it is possible to locate, identify and
examine people from their online presence.
There are obvious privacy concerns here, which we have yet properly to
contend with. It is a new and disquieting world when a trainee teacher
can be denied a college degree because she has posted a photo of
herself, drunk, on MySpace.[90] But at the same time there is also the
potential for a new form of collective security. Already, it is possible
easily to access the human rights and environmental records of major
companies;[91] one website allows you to research all the components,
and the labor history embodied in them, of even complex products like
computers or TVs.[92] It is easy to see how this scrutiny will spread
more widely. Already, employers Google prospective employees to
scrutinize their online history. Prospective lovers do the same. The
Panopticon is already reality.
While online transparency and criticism may help improve the services
offered by competing local plumbers, itâs harder to see how it may work
for the securities industry, a world that is not only secretive but also
so complex that many of its most sophisticated denizens (George Soros,
for instance) freely admit that they do not fully understand the
financial instruments now available. Here, we return to Harry
Markopolos.
After conducting his own investigation of Madoff, and concluding that
something very fishy was going on, Markopolos sought to inform the SEC
which, as we now know, failed to follow up on his suspicions. This he
was permitted to do by law. Markopolos was not, however, permitted to
publicize his concerns, for to do so would have immediately made him
vulnerable to punitive lawsuits by Madoff. Indeed, Markopolos testified
that the failure of the SEC to investigate his complaints made him fear
for his safety. The net effect, therefore, of the laws existing at the
time of the Madoff fraud was not to inform and protect investors, but to
protect Madoff.
Perhaps it is naive to expect ordinary investors to enjoy the expertise
to scrutinize investment funds like Madoffâs, even if one might expect
them to exercise more diligence than that demonstrated by Madoffâs
unwise and unfortunate investors. It is not unrealistic, however, to
envisage a system whereby disinterested experts might offer advice on
the wisdom of investing in certain funds. Looking at the way e-commerce
is developing on the Web, this might consist of several connected
elements: a ratings system for buyers anonymously to rate their
investment âexperience,â independent sites which offer disinterested
advice on various investment alternatives and, finally, investors might
form groupsâlike cooperativesâsuch as that which hired Harry Markopolos
to conduct research on their behalf.
Above all, the Web shows that it is transparency that wins customers.
Ergo, those that eschew itâor actively reject it, as Madoff didâshould
pay the penalty in lost business. Madoff himself has argued that his
claimed âblack boxâ investment strategyâthe series of computerized
algorithms to decide equity tradesâwas unintelligible to most of Wall
Street, let alone ordinary investors, claiming that many other hedge
funds are similarly opaque to outside scrutiny: âDoes anyone know how,
say, Renaissance really makes its returns?â Madoff asked in an interview
with the Financial Times, referring to the wildly successful hedge
fund.[93]
Perhaps he is right. However, what is beyond dispute is that from 1992
onward Madoff, by his own admission, conducted no trades at all and
faked the documents, pretending that they had taken place. This fraud
should have been easy to detect with only the most cursory scrutiny, if
the market were more transparent: It should be straightforward to
corroborate the trades with the counterparties, those who supposedly
bought and sold Madoffâs equity holdings. In other words, transparency
does not need to reveal the secret investment strategies of successful
funds, but it canâand simplyâreveal other telltale signs of fraud like
Madoffâs. Unlike his faked investment strategy, Madoffâs fraud was
devastatingly simple.
There is perhaps a final and subtle lesson to be learned from this
miserable episode. It is clear both from victims and Madoff himself that
the wealth and power of big Wall Street players was a deterrent against
scrutiny and investigation, intimidating those who sought to question,
including the SEC. From many accounts of the Madoff scam, Wall Street
appears as a layered hierarchy governed not by the SEC but by an
exclusive club of powerful financiers, whom Madoff sought to join and
succeeded in so doing. This club was bound by a wary but mutual trust
and tacit agreement among members to forbear from questioning one
anotherâs affairs too closely. Madoff claims that many major Wall Street
figures and banks, including JPMorgan, knew what was going on. Once
Madoff joined the club, and hobnobbed with its members, he was all but
untouchable.
We have been culturally conditioned to accept that the prosecution of
the occasional Madoff somehow proves the power of law and intrinsic
justice in the system. In fact, the story unearthed by his case proves
the opposite: The system is revealed as fundamentally iniquitous and
persistently vulnerable to crime and violent instability. The gross
inequality of contemporary society permits a culture of unaccountability
and, sometimes, criminality among the richest and most powerful. The
most extreme results of this imbalance are scandals like Madoff but
also, with the credit crunch, economic volatility that destroys millions
of jobs and endangers the entire global economy.
Methods to address this inequality will be discussed later. Money and
power are of course hard to assail as sources of influence and secrecy.
But what can be changed is the attitude of those outside the private
circle. We should no longer be intimidated. One clear lesson of the
Madoff scandal is the requirement for individual investors themselves to
use greater care and scrutiny: to exercise, in short, their own agency
rather than submitting their choices to the care of others. Everyone has
the right to question. This is a right that cannot be taken for granted
but must be continually asserted, by one and by all. The more that each
of us demands it, the easier it will be for all of us.
The exercise of collective and individual scrutiny, disinterested
analysis shared publicly, insistent questioning: None of these elements
alone would necessarily suffice to deter or prevent future Madoffs. But
together they would create a lattice of checks and balances whose
collective effect would be to force greater transparency within, and
scrutiny of, a notoriously closed, clubby and corrupt industry: a result
that decades of government supervision and legislation have signally
failed to achieve.
That lattice would not have a fixed structure, and it would likely
change over time in response to changes in the industry it was
monitoring. It would not have the reassuring bricks-and-mortar
institutional presence, and claim to expertise and authority, of a body
like the Securities and Exchange Commissionâitself a comforting name, at
least prior to Madoff. The lattice may not be imposed by legislation,
and its origin may be in a state of affairs some might call anarchyâthe
absence of rulesâbut its result would be not the disorder usually
associated with that word, but its opposite.
For two days in 2004, there was anarchy in Kosovo. The âauthoritiesââin
this case the local police, UN and NATO peacekeepersâlost control. This
was never publicly admitted. The candid admissions of failure in reports
by UN officials in Kosovo itself were altered at UN headquarters in New
York before they were reported to the UN Security Council, the ultimate
authority which supervised the de facto government of Kosovo. It wasnât
the UNâs fault, the Security Council was told. The violence was
deliberately instigated by extremist Kosovar leaders, an allegation for
which there was little hard evidence.
The journalists who arrived in Kosovo after the violence chose their own
convenient narratives: This was a typical, if depressing, cycle of the
familiar ethnic violence that had plagued Kosovo, like the Balkans, for
generations. Only a few chose to report the more complicated truth,
including the fact that the violence had been in part a kind of
rebellion against the ruling authorities in Kosovoâthe UN. Only one NGO,
a specialist in conflict whose two staff were deeply embedded in
Kosovoâs complicated stories, managed to capture the many strands of
what had happened there.[94]
In truth, each chosen narrative carried some weight. The story of
generational ethnic hatred was, in a sense, a true one. Serbs were
attacked by Kosovo-Albanian mobs across the territory; many Serbian
houses were burned; some Serbs were physically assaulted; eight were
killed (the remainder killed in the violence were Kosovo-Albanians shot
by NATO and UN forces).[95]
A second narrative was better concealed than the first, conventional
account. This was that the anger was directed as much against the UN
rulers of Kosovo as it was against the Serbs. Despite having their own
democratically elected government, the people of Kosovo were excluded
from the crucial decisions about their own future. I saw the evidence
with my own eyes. The UN was attacked in all its manifestationsâoffices,
cars, staff. Other international organizations, such as the EU, were not
attacked.
There was a deeper flux at work too. The boys and young men in the
rioting crowds were not sophisticated political critics. If you had
asked them why they were rioting, they would not have said it was
because Kosovoâs people were excluded from political decision making
about their future. They might have said, âWe hate the Serbs.â But what
one most frequently heard was this: âIt is because we are angry.â Angry
at the potholes and the lack of jobs; angry at the endless power cuts;
angry because the girls and the luxury we see on MTV are unavailable to
us.
So far, so political. But it was clear, because you could feel it, that
there was a collective emotion at work. An emotion that was evident in
individuals, but took greater force, and found expression, only when the
crowd formed. The violence felt, in some terrible inadmissible way, like
a release.
After the violence subsided, I returned to my work at the UN. My job had
been to guide the local elected Kosovo government to adopt so-called
standards of democracy: the rule of law, minority rights and other
measures of a stateâs worthiness to exist and be accepted in the
community of nations. The âinternational communityâ in this case was
embodied in a small and secretive group of six countries known as the
âContact Groupâ which ran international policy on Kosovo. This group had
insisted that such standards be established, and in some way fulfilled,
before Kosovo could be considered for âfinal statusââwhether it could
become a state, as the large majority of its people desperately wanted.
Politically, the imposition of these standards was one reason why the
violence had erupted. Because Russia, the U.S. and others disagreed in
principle on whether Kosovo should become a state, no one in the
âinternational communityâ was prepared to say what precisely Kosovo had
to do to become independent. Kosovo was caught in a state of perpetual
limbo, like being ordered every day to take an exam but never told if
youâd passed or failed, or indeed what a pass or fail required.
The two-day orgy of violence, therefore, represented a total failure for
my work. I sat at my desk, facing Besnik, my loyal assistant, and stared
at the stacks of papers elaborating the democratic, rule-abiding
âstandardsâ that Kosovo was required to meet. We discussed whether to
take the papers to the street outside the UN building, make a little
pile and set fire to them. In the end we decided it would be a
ridiculous and futile gesture: The rioters had already done it for us.
One incident, seemingly unremarkable, stuck in my memory. On the morning
of the second day of the trouble, the head of the UN mission, a former
president of Finland, had summoned Kosovoâs political leaders to his
office. He demanded to know what they were doing to stem the violence.
Reading from a note prepared by his staffers, he looked over his
spectacles at the leaders across the conference table, peering at them
like a remonstrative school teacher at his unruly pupils.
And the leaders were silent. They sat glumly, looking a little shifty,
like naughty schoolboys who had been caught smoking cigarettes behind
the gym. A few muttered excuses, but those uttering them seemed as
unconvinced as we were. There was a general air of embarrassment.
I pondered this incident. Why had the leaders not spoken up for their
political demands? Why had they not blamed the UN and the international
community for stoking the frustrated anger of the Kosovo-Albanian
majority? Why had they resembled nothing so much as a bunch of
adolescents being punished after school?
Slowly, it dawned on me. No one was prepared to take responsibility for
the violence, because no one felt responsible for it. The behavior of
Kosovoâs leaders was immature and childish, because that was what was
expected of them. The international community had refused to give these
political leaders the real responsibility to run the country, telling
them instead that they and their country were not yet ready for the
burdens of statehood. My work in elaborating and implementing the
âstandardsâ sent, and made concrete, this very message.
Kosovo was permitted to have elections, an elected government and a
parliament, but the real power resided in an unelected officialâthe UN
Special Representative, the Finn, appointed by the UN
Secretary-Generalâwho could veto any decision made by the local elected
government.
The dramatic events in one small Balkan province (now a state) were
unique, but there are nevertheless lessons of broader significance.[96]
Western democracies are not on the cusp of violent disorder (although it
cannot be ruled out if the current system is not improved). The violence
and unrest on the streets of Kosovo, but above all the feckless behavior
of Kosovoâs elected but powerless politicians, carried one crucial
lesson: If people do not have responsibility, do not expect them to
behave responsibly.
This episode suggests a broader lesson about democracy, stability and
anarchy. Defenders of the current order argue that to abandon the system
of representative democracy is to invite anarchy, a war of all against
all. But the 2004 disorder in Kosovo suggests a more subtle and
unexpected lesson. It is this: The less people have agencyâcontrolâover
their own affairs, and the less command they feel over their futures and
their circumstances, the more inclined they are to take to the streets.
The best way, indeed, to invite violent anarchy is to reduce the agency
and sense of control that people need to feel over their lives.
The disconnection between voters and their government, along with
governmentâs declining ability to deal with problems of global origin,
are combining in the current dispensation to produce this very effect.
The frustration, disillusionment and growing extremism all too evident
in todayâs democracies are symptoms of this phenomenon: loss of agency.
Kosovo may represent an extreme case, but for it not to become a
harbinger, action must be taken. Our way of doing politics, indeed our
way of thinking about politics, needs to change, from passivity to
action: reclaiming agency.
And in that reclamation, we must find better ways of doing business with
one another. If too distant and corruptible institutions are proving
inadequate, what might work? Some believe that technology alone, and the
Internet in particular, can deliver the necessary revolution. Some even
believe that the Internet is the necessary revolution, and that its
inherently heterogeneous and transparent nature amounts, in itself, to
political change. Closer analysis reveals, however, a more complicated
and ambiguous reality.
Something else is needed. And that something else, it turns out, doesnât
require fancy technology, Web-based platforms and Twitter feeds (though
they may help). That something else turns out to be simple indeed.
During the Spanish Civil War, more than thirty thousand people from over
fifty nations volunteered to fight the Nationalist armies of General
Franco. Many gave up jobs and left families in order to fight the
emerging global threat of fascism, and to defend a nascent socialist,
even anarchist republic.
They joined Republican forces that were in many cases undertrained and
equipped with antique and inadequate weapons. In Homage to Catalonia,
George Orwell vividly describes the miserable conditions of the
front-line troops, dug into feces-strewn trenches with neither the
clothing nor arms properly to fight the Francoâs armies, which by
contrast received substantial international support from Italy and Nazi
Germany.[97] Yet Orwell compellingly evokes the comradeship among the
Republican troops, the abolition of traditional hierarchies and the
appealing idealism of both the Spanish and international volunteers. He
recounts too that anarchist principles were no obstacle to effective
military organization: Although there was debate within army unitsâand a
welcome absence of the cringing deference of many military
organizationsâthere was also discipline, not least thanks to the unity
of purpose among the troops.
Much history since has given the impression that the international
volunteers were mainly middle-class intellectuals. But in fact they came
from all walks of life.[98] The âInternational Brigadeâ of foreign
volunteers fought in several key battles of the civil war, including a
notable role in the ferocious Battle of Madrid, where Republican forces
successfully beat back a Nationalist assault in the autumn of 1936. The
fighting was intense and bloody: Infantry fought at close quarters, room
by room, with bayonets and grenades.
Of the thirty thousand or so foreign volunteers who went to fight for
their beliefs, nearly ten thousand were killed in action and another
eight thousand or so wounded. Of those who survived, many returned to a
less than welcoming reception in their home countries. Some were
imprisoned, others were denied citizenship, while some, such as the
three thousand or so antifascist Germans, were unable to return home at
all.
The war in the Darfur region of Sudan has been raging since 2003.
Civilian casualties are enormous, with some estimating that several
hundred thousand people have been killed, and perhaps three million
refugees displaced. The killing has been sustained and deliberate,
leading many to depict the conflict as a planned genocide of the
indigenous inhabitants of Darfur, engineered and led by the Sudanese
government in Khartoum and executed by militias under its control,
including the notorious Janjaweed. In 2008, the president of Sudan, Omar
Hassan al-Bashir, was indicted for war crimes by the International
Criminal Court in The Hague. At the time of this writing, however,
Bashir has not been handed over to the court for trial;[99] all the
signs indicate that the âinternational community,â including the U.S.,
is prepared to allow the indictments to be quietly forgotten.
But nongovernmental reaction to the killings in Darfur has been
vociferous. Across the world, hundreds of protest groups have demanded
action to stop the killing, calling for the intervention of foreign
troops either under United Nations or African Union auspices. Some
protest groups, such as Not on Our Watch, were set up by famous film
stars, including George Clooney and Brad Pitt.[100] Students from
Swarthmore College set up a telephone hotline that immediately connects
the caller to the office of their representative in Congress, whom they
can demand take action about Darfur. There have been a large number of
Internet petitions about Darfur, some attracting many millions of
signatories.
But this vast expenditure of campaigning energy has resulted in scant
additional protection for Darfuri civilians. As the war raged, the
âinternational communityâsâ response amounted to a small and
underequipped African Union force which, several years after the
conflict began, comprised only a few thousand lightly armed troops to
provide security in an area approximately the size of Spain. Even the
forceâs defenders make no claim that the AU force is in any way adequate
to deter or prevent attacks against civilians. And indeed the killing
has continued up to the time of this writing.
Some commentators have suggested that the rhetorical heat generated by
Western pressure groups, and in particular their use of the word
âgenocide,â may have made the chances of finding a peaceful outcome
locally more difficult.[101] Just as distant governments must simplify
the complex realities of foreign conflicts in order to pronounce policy
about them, so too did the simplifying lens of distance enable
campaigners to turn a complicated and fluid situation into a compelling
black-and-white narrative of good and evil, leading some to argue that
the simplifications of celebrity campaigning have actually helped
prolong the conflict.[102] No foreign citizen has taken up arms
themselves to defend the Darfuris.
The advent of the Internet has released a wave of enthusiasts who
believe that democracy can be improvedâsaved, perhapsâby technology
alone. There are now innumerable websites where online petitions can be
created and propagated on any topic, from freeing imprisoned Burmese
democracy leader Aung San Suu Kyi to liberating socialite Paris Hilton
from her brief incarceration for drunk driving. Politicians have been
quick to glom on to the petition trend. The website of the British prime
minister, like that of the White House, encourages their submission
though there is little mention of what becomes of any petition thus
delivered. The woefully undemocratic British House of Lords, where every
member is either appointed or inherits their seat, recently established
an equally pitiful blog site to encourage âdialogueâ between their
Lordships and the grateful public.[103] Even the British sovereign, to
whom all Britons are subject, now has a Facebook page where the Queenâs
subjects can ventilate their feelings.
Not one to miss out on a trend, Chinaâs Communist Party, a body not best
known for accountability and transparency, has launched its own
discussion forum, âDirect line to Zhongnanhai.â Zhonghnanhai is the huge
and secretive compound in the heart of Beijing where Chinaâs leaders
live and work. As one commentator aptly put it, âThe site appears to be
an effort to persuade people that the leadership is listening to their
very personal concernsâŠ. It is clearly designed to demonstrate that the
leadership is attentive and sensitive.â[104] But as the Financial Times
reported, although the new message board is trying to demonstrate
responsiveness, it does not actually provide responses from the leaders
addressed. A further problem with âInternet democracyâ was revealed when
such an attempt was mounted during the transition period after the U.S.
presidential election of 2008. When the new administration of
President-elect Barack Obama created an online âCitizenâs Briefing Bookâ
for people to submit ideas âvirtuallyâ to the president, they received
over forty thousand proposals and nearly a million and a half people
voted on their preferences among those proposals. The most popular idea
was to legalize marijuana. Legalizing online poker topped the
contributions in the technology category. Revoking the Church of
Scientologyâs tax-exempt status garnered three times more votes than
raising funds for childhood cancer. The New York Timesâ conclusion from
this episode was that advocates of the Internet as the incarnation of
real-time participatory democracyââAthens on the Netââstill had some
arguments to answer.[105]
There are now websites that invite views on proposed legislation,
scrutiny of campaign finances and details of your representativesâ
voting patterns. âSee, click, fixâ allows citizens to identify local
problems online for government action.[106] But all these supposedly new
forms of political action rely on a very traditional mechanism of
political changeâup/down: pressuring, scrutinizing, demanding that
representatives and government take action. There has been no change to
the fundamental model of politics.
It is correspondingly easy for government and other embodiments of the
status quo to adopt these new technological tools, and thus neutralize
any benefit. Governments are now replete with their own tech fetishists,
wittering on (or twittering on) about âGovernment 2.0â and organizing
podcasts, tweets and blogs saying more or less the same things that
politicians have always said, albeit through a different medium.
Despite the repeated claim from government that the flow of information
is from people to government, the evidence suggests that the true
direction is the opposite. There is scant evidence to suggest that any
significant government policy has been informed or altered by tweeting
or the fancy online tools set up, for instance, by the U.S. State
Department to encourage a âglobal conversation.â The basic power
structure is unchangedâup/downâthe only difference is the form of
communication. Revealingly, the most palpable results of this ânewâ Web
activism are to be found in the most traditional manifestations of âoldâ
politics: organizing get-out-the-vote volunteers and, inevitably,
raising money.
Celebrants of the new technological democracy often cite examples from
âabroadâ where technology has brought about political change, like the
âcolorâ revolutions in Ukraine or Georgia, or the âTwitterâ protests
against the government in Iran in 2009, and most recently the
revolutions in Tunisia and Egypt in the âArab springâ of 2011, where
indeed it is clear that social media played an important role.
They rarely mention that there are equally many examples where
technology has had a more malign effect. In Nigeria, deadly riots in the
city of Jos were fueled, according to one authority, by text messages
sent between rampaging mobs;[107] the same thing happened in the
violence that gripped Kosovo in 2004 (described in the previous
chapter). In London, the killing of a fifteen-year-old boy was
coordinated by his attackers on Facebook.[108] The âTwitterâ protests in
Iran did not lead, yet, to the overthrow of government; many protesters
ended up in the same prison very traditionally used by different regimes
to house political prisonersâTehranâs notorious Evin jail. These
prisoners now include Iranâs best-known blogger, Hossein Derakhshan, who
in 2010 was sentenced to nineteen years in jail for alleged
collaboration with foreign governments, spreading âpropagandaâ against
the Islamic regime and setting up âobsceneâ websites.
In early 2011, the dictatorial regime in Sudan learned quickly from the
Mubarak regimeâs mistakes in managing Internet-based protest in Egypt.
Khartoum turned the Internet against the protesters, setting up fake
pro-democracy pages on Facebook and arresting all those who showed up
for the demonstrations advertised on the site. Eventually, activists
avoided using Internet-based tools at all, returning to more traditional
and covert forms of organization.[109] The lesson is stark: Power adapts
to new technology, and swiftly.
After an initial spasm of excitement at the liberating possibilities of
the World Wide Web, it is now emerging that Chinaâs adoption of the
Internet does not necessarily herald a new dawn of transparency and
incipient democracy. Every major Internet company in China employs
scores and sometimes hundreds of Internet âadministratorsâ to search for
subversive content. The city of Beijing recently advertised for ten
thousand volunteers to act as monitors.[110] Twitter, Facebook and
YouTube remain blocked. China is adapting search technology similar to
Googleâs to hunt and prosecute dissent. The search company that
pioneered the antidissident algorithms is now a successful commercial
company, listed on the Chinese stock exchangeâa neat rebuttal of the
naive equation that free markets ipso facto produce freedom of speech.
In general, the protection of basic freedoms on the Web relies on the
goodwill and good intentions of the very small number of people who
control its most powerful institutions: the very opposite of the ideal
condition required for the maintenance of freedom and democracy. Large
companiesâYahoo, AOL, Googleâdominate decisions about what content may
appear on the Web; one can only hope they are beneficent. Google alone
controls 63 percent of Internet searches. In deciding what can or cannot
be published on the Web and listed in its searches, and whether to
comply with censoring governments, Google is taking decisions of immense
consequence for freedom of speech. Its decision to confront censorship
in China in early 2010 was a decision of great political, and not merely
commercial, consequence.
As Google stood up to China, Microsoft without apology continued to
offer a censored search service. Yahoo! and Microsoft have been accused
by Amnesty International of abetting censorship and repression in China
by supplying equipment and adapting their search engines to block
certain sites and, in Yahoo!âs case, assisting the Chinese authorities
in identifying online antigovernment critics. In response, they have
argued that no company alone can change Chinese law, by which they must
abide.
Eli Pariser of MoveOn has warned of a more subtle danger: that Google
and Facebookâs filtering mechanisms are creating a âfilter bubbleâ
around us; the algorithms applied by these sites to âpersonalizeâ our
Web experience are effectively rendering much of the Web invisible.[111]
We think we are browsing the entire World Wide Web, but in fact we are
only seeing the sites Google and Facebookâs filters deem appropriate to
our interests. The Web surfer in China experiences the same phenomenon.
There is no outward sign that the sites they are visiting have been
vettedâor filteredâfor their consumption by the sophisticated filtering
technology used by the Chinese government. Unwitting, they think that
they are surfing the whole Web. In this regard, they are just like Web
users in the West.
As Stanford Universityâs Professor Lawrence Lessig has argued, it is
hard always to square the interests of a commercial company seeking to
expand market share with the protection of freedom of speech: â[Google
has] enormous control over a platform of all the worldâs data, and
everything they do is designed to improve their control of the
underlying data. If your whole game is to increase market share, itâs
hard to do good, and to gather data in ways that donât raise privacy
concerns or that might help repressive governments to block
controversial content.â[112]
At least the Internet, it is argued, will encourage debate and
interaction, albeit virtually rather than in person. But here, it
appears that instead of encouraging debate among those of differing
views and thus convergence, the opposite may be happening. The Web
offers multiple locations to find those one agrees with, and to avoid
those one doesnât. As columnist Nicholas Kristof has commented, we
select the kind of news and opinions that reflect our own prejudices
back to us, an emerging news product Nicholas Negroponte of MIT has
called âThe Daily Me.â[113]
One result is that any clash of opinions, especially in the
anything-goes anonymity of the Web, is increasingly violent, hostile and
insulting. Name-calling is frequent; reasoned debate rare. Particularly
when opinions differ from the party lineâwhether of left or
rightâcriticism tends to escalate, and coarsen. Itâs not only domestic
debates that witness such growing vituperation. In China, when a Chinese
fighter plane crashed, killing its pilot, after colliding with a U.S.
reconnaissance aircraft over the South China Sea, the Chinese
blogosphere erupted with violently anti-American and nationalist
sentiment: views that the Chinese government was happy, at least at
first, to allow, perhaps as a means to ventilate more general political
frustrations. Demonstrations followed, and the American embassy in
Beijing was attacked by stone-throwing hordes. Some demanded that China
declare war on the U.S. The traditional state-controlled press, while
critical of the U.S., had taken a more measured tone. The Chinese
authorities struggled to contain the situation and began to downplay the
issue in public. Some of the more rabid blogs were closed down.
Eventually, the riots stopped. Back in the U.S., the governmentâs
director of National Intelligence has observed that the Internet is a
fertile breeding ground for terrorism, warning that, âWhen it comes to
susceptibility to radicalization, virtual communities have become as
important as physical communities.â[114]
The antagonism and hostility of political debate on the Internet reveals
an essential truth of the modern condition, which is in fact a perpetual
condition of humanity, but one which modernity places in starker relief:
The more detached people are from one another, the more they can cloak
themselves in anonymity and be shielded from the consequences of their
views, the more violent, hostile and irresponsible they are likely to
be. It is a peculiar but retrograde feature of modernity that its
facetsâthe nature of modern work, communications, political interaction
and the modern state itselfâhave heightened that detachment.
There is a form of politics which produces more consensus, a better
understanding and respect for alternative points of view and a deeper
acknowledgment of facts over opinion. It does not require an expensive
computer or any technical equipment at all, for the Internet often
excludes the poor and otherwise marginalized.[115] It is as
old-fashioned as the earliest parliaments, where people gathered on a
hillside to arbitrate their common business. The academic who has
pioneered the technique calls it âdeliberative democracy,â but really it
can be called something simpler: meeting people.
After Hurricane Katrina, much of the infrastructure of New Orleans was
devastated: More than 70 percent of housing was damaged and entire
neighborhoods were almost completely destroyed; schools, hospitals and
police stations were shut down. Nearly a hundred thousand jobs were
lost, and eighteen months after the hurricane, more than half of the
cityâs population had not returned.
In the aftermath, plans to rebuild New Orleans confronted a ravaged
infrastructure, enormous financial losses, a local government in
disarray and a citizenry whose trust in government had been sorely
undermined. The early planning efforts by city officials were met with
anger and protest as the community struggled with the challenges of
distributing resources and reviving an entire city.
Faced with this crisis of confidence, city officials decided to involve
the citizens in a full discussion, in depth and face-to-face, on the
priorities for the city. Most of the cityâs inhabitants were still
spread across the U.S., not yet able to return. Four thousand New
Orleanians met in âCommunity Congressesâ staged across the country to
discuss recovery priorities for their city. As decision makers listened,
citizens discussed how to ensure safety from future flooding, empower
residents to rebuild safe and stable neighborhoods, provide incentives
and housing so people could return, and establish sustainable and
equitable public services.[116]
At the end of the deliberations, fully 92 percent of participants agreed
on the âUnified Planâ for the city. Critically, this approval rating
represented the collective view of the citizenry: Participants reflected
pre-Katrina New Orleansâin proportion to both race and income. At
earlier similar events, black and poor citizens were often severely
underrepresented. This time, citizens had participated not only at home
but in cities across the country where hurricane refugees were then
living. Thus, the cityâs new plan was discussed and endorsed not only by
its officials, but also by its citizens, who overwhelmingly committed to
support the plan.
There has been a more sustained experiment in such âparticipativeâ or
âdeliberativeâ democracy in Porto Alegre, one of Brazilâs largest
cities. âThe Porto Alegre Experimentâ again shows that better outcomes
result when citizens are directly involved in decisions over their own
lives. In 1989, when the experiment began, the city suffered some of the
worst inequality in the continent. The poorâone-third of the cityâs
populationâlived in slums around the periphery; the rich controlled the
cityâs government and budget. Over the last ten years, the city has
gradually developed a multilayered approach to participatory budgeting.
Starting at the most local level, citizens are encouraged to participate
in debates about local spending prioritiesâwater, schools, hospitals,
housing, roads. Of the cityâs 1.5 million inhabitants, every citizen is
informed about the budget process and around fifty thousand now take
part.
According to a World Bank study, the participatory process has fostered
direct improvements in facilities in Porto Alegre. For example, sewer
and water connections increased from 75 percent of households in 1988 to
98 percent in 1997. The number of schools has increased fourfold since
1986. The city is at the cutting edge in developing progressive
recycling and renewable energy projects. The participatory process is
overwhelmingly supported by the cityâs population. It has also,
reportedly, encouraged a change in the tenor of local politics. Less and
less a partisan contest, the common enemy is the occasional crisis.
Everything is transparent, from decision making to the awarding of
contracts.
These new deliberative processes are locally driven and designed for
local circumstances; there is no âone size fits all.â The general
benefitsâof greater citizen empowerment, of greater consensus over local
spendingâare clear: They flow directly and crucially from the agency of
those involved. People participate not to be consulted by government and
service-providers but to make real decisions themselves about their
circumstances. And when people are trusted and informed to make
decisions, they tend to make good ones. Such deliberative processes,
with real decisions as their result, are not to be confused with
Americaâs overheated âtown hallâ meetings of recent memory, or the
vulgar arguments on Internet âforums.â While politicians claim that they
are intended as a place to hear the views of the public, the town hall
meetings are not places where decisions are made. Typically, the local
angry brigades line up to denounce elected officials and their plans,
providing an unpleasant experience for everyone except those who enjoy
public confrontation. Rational discussion and respect for the facts are,
unsurprisingly, rarely the result.
In a recent book, legal scholar Cass Sunstein has noted that very often
when groups of people are placed together to debate an issue, they often
end up more polarized than at the beginning.[117] But Sunsteinâs work
also suggests how to create greater unity. The more detached groups are
from society, the more extreme their decisions are likely to become. The
less that a decision debated within a group actually matters, the
greater the likelihood of dispute and conflict. A lesson becomes clear:
When nothing is at stake, and when no one has agency, it is predictable
that heated disagreement will be the outcome.
It is not only hurricane-struck New Orleans that suffers a crisis in
democracy. With turnouts falling and disaffection with âpoliticsâ
growing in all democratic countries, its model, like that of Porto
Alegre, offers lessons applicable beyond the occasional management of
disasters.
One particular example of that crisis is found at the European
Parliament. Originally conceived and empowered to give European peoples
a voice in EU decisions largely dominated by governments, its problems
highlight weaknesses increasingly apparent in other democratic
legislatures.
At the most recent elections to the parliament, extremist parties jumped
at the opportunity offered by the dismal turnout of Europeâs votersâthe
lowest in the parliamentâs history. Realizing that many mainstream
voters would stay away, extreme and far-right parties made special
efforts to mobilize their supporters. The result was that such parties
were represented in greater number here than in their own national
parliaments. The right-wing British National Party joined Italian and
Lithuanian proto-fascists, Dutch anti-immigrant parties and other
assorted representatives of the fringe in the home of European
âdemocracy.â
Neither phenomenonâlow turnout, extreme political partiesâbodes well for
the legitimacy, popularity or effectiveness of the decisions arising
from the parliament. Both phenomena, however, point to a future of
democratic politics, of both disenchantment and extremism, that may
become more and more evident, in more established parliaments and
congresses too. What is to be done?
The Financial Times recently reported an exercise which sought to
address this problem, asking the question: How much longer can the EU
continue as a project controlled by elites and disregarded by the
masses?[118] What is the solution to this âdemocratic deficitâ?
One answer was attempted by Professor James Fishkin, a social scientist
at Stanford University. He conducted an experiment in which a balanced
sample of 348 Europeans from the EUâs twenty-seven countries were
brought to Brussels for a three-day dialogue on the elections and the
policy issues surrounding them. This is a procedure known as
âdeliberative polling,â a concept Professor Fishkin introduced in 1988.
One outcome of the exercise was that many participants changed their
voting intentions as a result of the dialogue. Beforehand, 40 percent
said they would vote for mainstream center-right parties, 22 percent for
socialists, 9 percent for centrist liberals and 8 percent for Greens.
After the exercise, support for the center-right dropped to 30 percent,
the socialists and liberals were almost unchanged at 21 percent and 8
percent respectively, and the Greens shot up to 18 percent. The rise in
support for the Greens came about as a result of detailed discussions
among the participants on climate change. Participants were asked to
choose between the view that âwe should do everything possible to combat
climate change even if that hurts the economyâ and the alternative view
that âwe should do everything possible to maximize economic growth, even
if that hurts efforts to combat climate change.â Before the discussions,
49 percent wanted to emphasize the fight against climate change.
Afterward, this figure rose to 61 percent.
Exercises like that performed by Professor Fishkin, and the New Orleans
reconstruction plan too, have shown repeatedly that when a group of
people gathers together to consider their affairs and collective
response to themâand, crucially, make decisionsâa number of valuable
benefits follow:
likely to acknowledge the concerns that underlie other peopleâs
political views.
dataâthan normal political debate, composed largely of opinions, allows.
greater degree of consensus within the group.
collectively in this manner than to decisions imposed by any other
authority.
Fishkin calls this âdeliberative democracy.â It is a process of a
different order from the current system, prevalent in all democratic
states, of representative democracy, whereby citizens elect
representatives to make decisions on their behalf. Indeed, deliberative
democracy in its fullest form, where people make genuine decisions of
consequence as a group, or a grassroots, community-based democracy, is
in fact ultimately incompatible with representative democracy. If two
mechanisms make decisions, what if their choices are contradictory? One
must be supreme.
Professor Fishkin attempts to bridge this problem, and render
deliberative techniques compatible, by proposing that deliberative
polling, of the kind described above, should help inform the regular
structures of representative democracyâthe legislators and members of
the executive who make up the decision makers. But despite his efforts
to construct such groups as representative of the general populaceâby
selecting their members in proportion to the political support for
different parties in the broader populationâsuch âdeliberative pollingâ
groups fail in one fundamental regard: They lack legitimacy. They are
not elected, so why should their voice, however proportionately it might
represent the rest, be heard above others?
Pollingâlike frequent referendumsâfails in another regard too. While
polls may provide an indication of what people think on a particular
question at a particular moment, they leave out one crucial component of
Fishkinâs experimentsâthe deliberation: the talking, the to-and-fro, the
listening, the compromise. Any citizen of California, where referendums
are frequent, will recognize that they have done little to contribute to
responsible and effective government of the stateârather the opposite.
This is also why Internet surveys of opinion, or petitions, tend to the
extreme, and are so pathetically inadequate as a new form of democracy.
In his essay âThe Pursuit of the Ideal,â Isaiah Berlin concludes that in
deciding what to do, the only option, in private life as in public
policy, is to engage in trade-offsârules, values, principles must yield
to each other in varying degrees in specific situations, adding that âa
certain humility in these matters is very necessaryâ since we have no
guarantee that any particular course we choose will be right. This is
the essence of democracy: discussion of differing views and options on
how we together must live, with a viewâultimatelyâto collective
decision. The mere ventilation of opinions, whether in person or online,
does not qualify.
In microcosm, it is self-evident that encounters and negotiation offer a
greater possibility for respect and agreement than either the virtual
chat room or a distant authority. Difficult discussions with friends or
family can quickly degenerate online as misunderstandings; willful
misinterpretations multiply. No one pretends that meetings in person are
necessarily easier, or less painful, but somehow we are able to see and
feel more and thus achieve a greater comprehension. Perhaps, above all,
we simply spend more time.
Professor Fishkinâs excellent books are filled with examples of
deliberative democracy, and his comprehensive analysis of why and how it
works and the impressive results it clearly delivers. But by and large,
deliberative democracy has remained a matter for academic discussion,
and occasional illustrative, yet tantalizing, exercises of the kind that
took place in New Orleans or Porto Alegre, or the experiments practiced
by Professor Fishkin.
The trouble with deliberative democracy is, of course, that it poses a
direct challenge to the existing constitutional order of representative
democracy, where the few are elected to arbitrate the affairs of the
many. Deliberative polling, while imaginative and revealing in its
insights, fails to bridge the gap. For in the existing system, it is not
tolerable to the existing authority for citizens to gather to sort out
their affairs and make decisions with real effects: that is what
governments are for!
For deliberative decision making to function properly, and for citizens
to enjoy its full and evident benefits, a condition must apply which,
oddly, even the most ardent academic proponents of deliberative
techniques seem loath to confess: There must be no other authority, at
all.
Though it is rarely mentioned, even in the histories of that period, the
Spanish civil war saw a moment, tragically brief, of real existing
anarchism. In the area of Spain under Republican control, anarchists for
a short while held sway, as far as that term means anything when no one
was completely in charge. This was not anarchy, an absence of order, it
was a society that for a period decided to govern itself not by
centralized authority, but by the wishes of local communities, workers,
men and women, led by values of equality and mutual respect.
This happened between 1936 and 1938, and was confined mostly to parts of
Catalonia in northern Spain, including Cataloniaâs capital, Barcelona.
It was estimated that perhaps ten million people participated in this
âSpanish Revolutionâ where farms and factories, and even shops and
barbers, were collectivized and run along communal linesâneither owned
by the state nor private capital, but run by the peasants and workers
themselves. Decisions were made on libertarian principlesâby those
affected, without bureaucracy. In many areas, agricultural production
significantly increased.
By 1938, it was over. The Communist Party in Moscow decided that Spain
was not ready for proletarian revolutionâat least not this kindâand
ordered its cohorts in Spain, the local Communists, to suppress the
anarchists. There were mass arrests, street fighting and executions.
Anarchist leaders and parties were denounced. This repression was one of
the reasons for the ultimate defeat of the Republicans, and the ensuing
four decades of fascist dictatorship under Franco.
George Orwellâs memoir of his experience in Catalonia contains vivid
depictions of what anarchism, in practice, was really like. When
published, Homage to Catalonia was attacked in Britain and elsewhere,
above all by Communists and the left in general, who rejected its
account of Communist suppression of the anarchists, preferring Moscowâs
propaganda that the anarchists were somehow in Francoâs pay or otherwise
to blame for the in-fighting in the antifascist ranks.
Homage sold very few copies on initial publication. Even now, the book
is rarely seen for what it truly is, and is instead interpreted as a
tragic and picturesque account of failed resistance against
fascism.[119] Orwell had joined a small Marxist-oriented party,
POUM,[120] in order to fight fascism, but later in the book confesses
that if he had the choice again, he would have been an anarchist. He
describes life in Barcelona during anarchism:
Many of the normal motives of civilized lifeâsnobbishness,
money-grubbing, fear of the boss, etc.âhad simply ceased to exist. The
ordinary class division of society had disappeared to an extent that is
almost unthinkable in the money-tainted air of England; there was no one
there except the peasants and ourselves, and no one owned anyone else as
his master. Of course such a state of affairs could not last. It was
simply a temporary and local phase in an enormous game that is being
played out over the whole surface of the Earth. But it lasted long
enough to have its effect upon anyone who experienced it. However much
one cursed at the time, one realized afterwards that one had been in
contact with something strange and valuable. One had been in a community
where hope was more normal than apathy or cynicism, where the word
âcomradeâ stood for comradeship and not, as in most countries, for
humbug. One had breathed the air of equality.[121]
This description tantalizes with its suggestion of what might be
possible if self-organized government were to become reality. Homage to
Catalonia also tells a vivid story about how one generation chose very
directly to tackle the problems of the world, in this case fascism. And
it is to this global stage that we must now turn. For here particularly,
perhaps even more than in the domestic realm, governments and their
organizations claim to have matters in hand. And in general, it seems,
we are happy to believe them. On the world stage, in general, the
management of âinternational affairsâ is left to practitioners like
statesmen and diplomats, which I once was.
It seems at first sight a reasonable bargain. The world is complicated;
it requires professionals to sort it out. But as we shall see in later
chapters, the bargain, like the pact between government and voter at
home, seems to be breaking down. Established systems of interstate
cooperation do not seem to be producing the solutions the world needs.
But there is a worse and more pernicious effect too.
Somewhere along the way, it has become accepted that in representing a
state, normal moral rules are suspended. Under the catch-all moral
permission of droit dâĂ©tat, officials acting in the name of the state,
even law-abiding democracies like Britain or the U.S. are entitled to
forsake normal moral inhibitions, like those against killing or causing
harm to others. If such actions are justified by the needs of the state,
they are not only excused, they are explicitly available. Indeed, the
good diplomat is told to reject the soft-headed morality of ordinary
people if he is to practice his trade as it must be
practicedârealpolitik. If death and the suffering of others are the
result, this is a necessary price of protecting our own.
I have not come by this criticism by way of academic study or historical
research. I know this, because once I did it. I helped do harm to
innocent others, with the explicit moral cover of the state, safe in the
knowledge that I would never be held to account. With the comfort of
impunity, I once committed violence in the name of the state.
The experiments conducted in the early 1960s by the Yale psychologist
Stanley Milgram are a well-known demonstration of how authority can
incite people to undertake heinous acts. Conducted soon after the 1961
trial of the Nazi Adolf Eichmann, Milgramâs experiment showed how
otherwise normal individuals could be instructed to commit horrific acts
including torture and murder, if commanded to do so by a person of
sufficient, even if feigned, authority.
But the experiment also illustrates a problem that pervades the current
international system and the current practice of diplomacy. That problem
has a nameâamorality: the profoundly negative moral consequences of
officials, in this case diplomats, of not taking responsibility for what
they do. And as we shall see, it is not only a problem of diplomacy, it
is a problem of any system that suppresses peopleâs sense of agency.
Milgram arranged a fake experiment whereby volunteers were instructed to
give ever greater electric shocks to another participant in the
experiment, unknown to the volunteer, an actor. As the subject failed to
give correct answers to the instructorâs questions, the volunteer was
told to give higher and higher electric shocks. As the shocks increased,
the actor pretending to be the subject would bang on the wall in feigned
agony, complain about his heart condition and, eventually, as the shocks
increased to the normally fatal level of 450 volts, fall silent. If the
volunteer hesitated in administering the electric shocks, a white-coated
âinstructorâ (in reality, another actor) told the volunteer that they
must continue. If at any time the unwitting volunteer asked to halt the
experiment, he was told, successively, by the âinstructorâ:
If the volunteer still wished to stop after all four successive verbal
injunctions, the experiment was halted. Otherwise, it was halted after
the volunteer had given the maximum 450-volt shock three times in
succession. Of Milgramâs subjects, 65 percent (twenty-six out of forty)
administered the experimentâs finalâand theoretically fatalâ450-volt
shock. Only one participant refused to administer shocks before the
300-volt level. Notably, all were told during the experiment that they
would not be held responsible for what happened.
Traditionally, and by Milgram himself, this experiment has been cited to
demonstrate the pernicious effects of authority upon moral conduct. If
people are told to do something awful by someone who is clearly in
authorityâin this case, a professorial type in a white coatâall too
often they do it. But another lesson is also evident in the fact that
the volunteers who administered the electric shocks, crucially, were
told that they had no responsibility for the results.
The nasty human truth of Milgramâs experiment has been demonstrated many
times in recent history. Mass warfare offers many examples. During World
War II, German reservists were called up by the government to join
regular military units but also police units, like Reserve Police
Battalion 101. The members of this unit were âordinaryâ men: teachers,
bankers and plumbers drawn from a wide variety of backgrounds, from
across Germany. As is the way with groups put into difficult
circumstances together, the battalion quickly bonded into a close-knit
team. The battalion was deployed to the Eastern Front, where it followed
closely behind the Wehrmacht advance across Eastern Europe and into the
Soviet Union.
The battalion was not recruited on any particular ideological basis,
though some were also members of the Nazi party (a good percentage of
Germans were at the time). But these were not Waffen-SS ideologues; they
were largely middle-aged men with wives and families, gardens and pet
dogs.
The battalion, in other words, was unexceptional, banal (as Hannah
Arendt might have put it).[122] In a little over a year, this battalion
of approximately five hundred âordinary menâ killed thirty-eight
thousand Jews and dispatched approximately forty-five thousand more to
extermination camps.[123] The battalion did most of its killing by
shooting civilians at close range after rounding them up from villages
and towns overrun by German forces. In the course of this murderous
spree, not one member of the battalion questioned their orders or sought
to leave the unit. When given the option by commanders to opt out of
specific opportunities for mass murder, fewer than fifteen men of five
hundred did so.
The Milgram experiments were recently repeated, to test how people today
might submit to authority when ordered to inflict pain upon innocent
others.[124] As reported in the journal American Psychologist, Professor
Jerry Burger replicated part of the Milgram studiesâbut stopping at 150
volts, the moment at which the subject cries out to stopâto see whether
people today would still obey.[125] There were some changes to account
for modern ethical rules and social sensibilities. University ethics
committees barred researchers from pushing the unwitting subjects
through to an imaginary and âlethalâ 450 volts, as Milgram did.
But despite these restrictions, the results were very much the same. As
in the 1960s, more than half the participants agreed to proceed with the
experiment past the 150-volt mark. Burger interviewed the participants
afterward and found that those who stopped generally believed themselves
to be responsible for the shocks, whereas those who kept going tended to
hold the experimenter accountable. This reveals a crucial distinction:
It was the participantsâ assumption for relinquishing of agency that
determined their actions.
Milgramâs experiment is today so well known that it has entered the
collective consciousnessâbut for the wrong reason. Although the
experiment is generally viewed as demonstrating the pernicious effects
of authority, in fact it reveals a more important truth: that when
people feel no agency and no responsibility for their actions, they can
commit horrific crimes. The Milgram experiment nevertheless seems remote
from our normal lives. One problem with such an experiment is that it is
hard to imagine ourselves in a situation where we would have to give
electric shocks to an innocent person. But the uncomfortable truth is
that such situations do not come announced; the chance to perform
cruelty upon others comes disguised. I know this now because I was once
in a position of one of Milgramâs test subjects, asked to inflict
suffering upon others. Except in my case, unlike his experiment, the
suffering was real.
For almost as long as I remember, I have wanted to be a diplomat. As a
schoolboy, I read The Times (of London) every day, pretty much all the
way through, gripped by its accounts of détente, the proxy wars between
East and West and the terrifying, yet intriguing, calculus of nuclear
war: first strikes, the âmissile gapâ and the strange but compelling
logic of Mutually Assured Destruction. Thanks to inherited
color-blindness, I couldnât fulfill my original ambition to become a
fighter pilot. The next best thing would be to become a diplomat and
enter this weighty but arcane and closed world, to learn its
terminologies and codes.
I was, moreover, fired by emotional urges. My family exuded a certain
awe of âthe Foreign Officeâ where British diplomats worked: Several
relations had tried and failed to enter the elite ranks of the
diplomatic corps. One childhood memory stands out. At perhaps age
twelve, I announced to my family that I wanted to become a diplomat. My
father, who later denied having said this, turned to me and said, âYou
have to be very clever to become a diplomat.â Thus was my ambition
sealed.
University came and went. Eventually, I managed to enter the fast stream
of the Foreign Office, a tiny group: some twenty-odd of the many
thousands who applied. We were a chosen elite, given to expect that in
due course we would become ambassadors and undersecretaries, the most
senior exponents of our countryâs wishes. I was elated to join this
exclusive club and happy to undergo the many compromises membership in
this group entailed.
Among them was the process that all new entrants must undertake in order
to join the foreign service, and therein become party to the stateâs
secrets. âPositive vettingâ is a deeply intrusive examination of
friendships, family relations, habits and personal history designed to
discover whether the proposed new diplomat poses any kind of security
risk.
To check its prospective sharers of secrets, the Security Department of
the Foreign Office assigned an investigator to examine my personal
background, quiz acquaintances and friends, in order to find out whether
my behavior, past or present, might render me vulnerable to approaches
from foreign intelligence services. Without this clearance, the would-be
diplomat cannot begin work since a great deal of work in the âoffice,â
as it soon became known to me, involves access to Top Secret material,
the compromise of which, in theory at least, poses a grave risk to the
security of the state.
Others who had gone before told me that the process was straightforward
âas long as you donât tell them anything.â Unfortunately for me, my
personal referees had already told my investigator various things,
including the fact that I occasionally drank too much at university,
played poker and that I was sharing a flat with a gay man. I took the
naive view that since I had nothing in my life to be ashamed of, I would
tell them the truth. This approach proved to be a serious mistake.
My vetting took place almost exactly as the Cold War was ending, in
1989. But the Foreign Office still feared the corrupting attentions of
the KGB and others, and it was felt that being homosexual, which I am
not, risked exposing the officer to blackmail. It did not seem to have
occurred to the mandarins in charge of Security Department that a
blanket prohibition on homosexuality was more likely to force serving or
potential foreign service officers to lie about their true sexual
natures and thus increase their vulnerability to blackmail. So my
vetting officer subjected me to a long series of absurd and insulting
questions about my sexuality, culminating in the conclusive, âSo youâve
never been tempted off the straight and narrow, then?â
Meanwhile, my investigator had found out from application forms that my
grandmother was Polish. Poland was at that time undergoing its
transformation to democracy. But Security Department suspected,
following policy, that the mere fact that I had Polish relations posed a
security risk, since the KGB might âget atâ them and use them to âget
atâ me (it had happened in the past when Poland was a vassal of the
Soviet Union). My family was thus forced to dig up long-buried records
and tell the awful investigator exactly when, where and how all my
Polish ancestors had died, in order that the KGB couldnât discover their
names and impersonate them to âget atâ me. This led to the upsetting
discovery that some of my Polish forebears, captured as members of the
Polish resistance, had died in Auschwitz.
I was obliged to attend several interviews with the investigator in a
sparse office in an anonymous building near Parliament Square, furnished
with sinister-looking steel filing cabinets. His desk, like that of an
interrogator, was bare but for one government-issue swivel lamp, the
only light in the otherwise gloomy room. Sometimes the interviews would
last for hours. My family and friends, who were subjected to separate
questionings, were at first amused by his questions, but soon became
irritated and in some cases upset.
The planned start date of my work at the Foreign Office came and went
and I had not passed my âPV,â as positive vetting is known. The
personnel officer assigned to my case took some pleasure in telling me
that it was extremely unlikely that I would eventually be allowed in. I
considered withdrawing from the process and abandoning my application to
join, but I decided instead to swallow these humiliations. Too badly I
wanted to become that rarefied species, a diplomat.
In retrospect, this process was akin to a kind of âhazingâ ritual, of
the kind practiced in certain American colleges, the military or similar
institutions. It was a form of ritual humiliation, where my sexual
habits, personal finances and most intimate relations were probed and
exposed. Once complete, not only was I permitted to join the elite club
of those permitted to see state secrets; I felt that I had shared with
themâthrough my investigatorâsomething of me, something private and
personal. This was more, much more than a regular induction into a job.
The inculcation went further when the new entrant to the diplomatic
service entered training. Immediately, we were encouraged to undergo a
subtle but crucial transformation: the âIâ became âwe.â In describing to
us the arcane and fetishized practices of the foreign service (the use,
for instance, of special paper for ministers and senior officials:
green-colored paper called, perversely, âblueâ), our instructors did not
talk of how they saw things with the personal and individual âI.â
Instead, they talked about how âweâ saw the world. Telegrams, then the
principal form of communication between the Foreign Office and British
embassies worldwide (there are now âe-gramsâ), were written in the first
person plural. The author did not describe his or her own view of
politics in Iran; instead they described how âweâ saw the prospects for
engagement with the Islamic regime.
A young diplomat from the British High Commission[126] in Pretoria
lectured the new entrants about how âweâ thought sanctions on apartheid
South Africa were a bad idea (these were the days of Margaret Thatcherâs
policy of âconstructive engagementâ with the white minority regime). A
diplomatic dispatch was presented to us as an example of how to write
such pieces. In it, the ambassador wrote about how âweâ had got Iran
âwrongâ and âweâ needed a new approach. In a number of different ways,
the new recruits were taught how âweâ saw the world. What we were never
taught, however, was why it was that âweâ saw the world that way. This
method was assumed, implied, never confessed but nonetheless supreme.
One training exercise involved a game revolving around a crisis in a
fictional country, Boremeya, and what âwe,â meaning Britain, should do
about it. It was a good game, and fun. It lasted about a day and
consisted of crisis meetings, submissions to ministers (âMake sure to
use âblueâ paper!â) and difficult encounters with the Boremeyan foreign
minister, played by one of our instructors. Throughout the game, the new
entrants were told to consider what âweâ wanted or needed in the
situation. Within such exercises, and infused in all our training, was a
clear, if only rarely explicit, assumption. As diplomats, âweâ were the
embodiment of the state, Britain. What we thought was right was thus
implicitly right for Britain.
It is obvious to the reader that such a transformation from the
individual to the group must imply a loss both of individual agency and
of moral autonomy. Processes such as that I underwent to join the
Foreign Office have parallels in military induction, including in more
striking form, Reserve Police Battalion 101. But it was not obvious to
me at the time. I still felt the same person. I still believed that I
was autonomous and free to make my own choices, within certain limits
that I freely accepted. I convinced myself that if faced with a morally
unacceptable instruction, such as murdering Jews, I would have the
courage to refuse. Little did I know that todayâs moral choices rarely
come so clearly signaled.
I had been in the foreign service some nine years by the time I was
posted to the British mission to the United Nations in New York. By then
I was deeply steeped in the culture and mind-habits of my institution.
Many of my friends were in the Foreign Office. The âoffice,â as we
called it, was a kind of brother-and-sisterhood: All over the world
there were co-members with whom I shared a common language and
experience. I had experienced with them excitement and boredom, from the
corridors of the United Nations to the mountains of the Hindu Kush. I
was with them as they wept at the frustrations of negotiations, and as
gunfire crackled on the streets of Pristina. They have been at my side
in Hebron and Dresden, Oslo and Islamabad. With them, I watched wars
begin and end, wrote and argued international law, and shared the many
joys and miseries of a life lived in the glamour of overseas embassies,
of high-level meetings and the dinginess of Whitehall offices. It was
not an ordinary job.
And my job in New York was not ordinary either. I was to be the head of
the Middle East section at the British Mission to the UN. It was an
exciting and challenging task. My responsibilities covered the
ArabâIsrael dispute, the 1988 Lockerbie bombing by Libyan agents, and
the long-standing and unresolved injustice of Moroccoâs occupation of
the Western Sahara. But my primary responsibility was Iraqâensuring its
disarmament and containment after the 1990 war, and the sanctions agreed
at the UN Security Council to effect these goals. For Britain at the UN
in those days, there was no more important task, and it was my
responsibility. In the early days of my posting, I was so excited by the
prospect of my work that I would whoop with joy as water poured over me
in my morning shower.
One central part of my job was to maintain the UN Security Councilâs
support of restrictive economic sanctions against Iraq. When first told
of this task, I relished it. I had no question that the sanctions were
justified. Their purpose was, after all, to punish and contain that most
evil and lawless of dictators, Saddam Hussein. When briefed in London
before my posting, however, the first doubts began to assert themselves.
Sanctions on Iraq had been imposed, I naively thought, because Iraq had
not disarmed itself of its infamous âweapons of mass destructionâ (WMD),
in this case defined as nuclear, chemical and biological weapons, and
ballistic missiles with a range of over 150 kilometers. This failure
presented a clear case for the maintenance of sanctions. However, when I
asked one of my briefing officers in London whether the UK believed Iraq
maintained significant stocks of WMD, he looked a little sheepish. âNot
really,â he replied. How, then, do we justify sanctions, I asked, trying
to contain my astonishment. He replied, on the basis that Iraq had
failed to answer multiple questions about the destruction of its earlier
stocks. In summary, sanctions were in place because Iraq had not
correctly answered questions.
By the end of 1997, when I joined the mission, British and American
policy at the UN Security Council was under severe pressure. Iraqâs
allies on the council, particularly France and Russia, were arguing for
an easing of sanctions on the grounds that Iraq had complied fully with
its obligations, following the Gulf War cease-fire, to disarm completely
of its nuclear program, chemical and biological weapons and long-range
missiles. The UN weapons inspectors were, however, clearly saying that
this was not the case, and that there remained many unresolved issues
about Iraqâs WMD. We, the U.S. and the UK, deployed these unresolved
issues to argue support for sanctionsâwhat had happened to all the
missiles Iraq had imported? Why the discrepancy between chemical bombs
produced and those verifiably destroyed? Et cetera, et cetera.
Sanctions, we argued with great vigor, were necessary to force Iraq to
disarm, fully and verifiably, as it had demonstrably not yet done. It
was a tough diplomatic fight, not helped by the absence of hard
evidence.
Though opponents of sanctions argued that they were unjustified and
caused immense human suffering in Iraq, our counterarguments were
plausible: Iraq had failed on many occasions to cooperate fully with the
weapons inspectors, leaving important questions unanswered; Saddam
Hussein obstructed the operation of the UNâs oil-for-food program, which
was designed to lessen the humanitarian suffering.
It was my job to cull and collate the innumerable statistics, reports
and testimonies in support of this latter version of the story and to
deploy them in speeches and debates in the Security Council. On the
other side of the table, the diplomats opposing sanctionsâled by Russia
and Franceâcould cite myriad reports detailing the suffering under the
sanctions regime and the inequities of the oil-for-food program.
It was, of course, a complex story that we managed to divide into two
distinct and opposing narratives. The atmosphere between the delegations
on the Security Council was aggressive and adversarial, as it remained
untilâand afterâthe 2003 invasion. Political divisions were allowed to
degenerate into personal animosities. The council, its chambers and
corridors became a diplomatic battle zone where the more we fought, the
more we entrenched our positions into competing blacks and whites. Thus
were we able to obscure the deeper truth.
Governments and their officials can compose convincing versions of the
truth, filled with more or less verifiable facts, and yet be entirely
wrong. I did not make up lies about Husseinâs smuggling or obstruction
of the UNâs humanitarian program. The speeches I drafted for my
ambassador to deliver to the Security Council and my telegrams back to
London were composed of facts filtered from the stacks of reports and
intelligence that daily hit my desk. As I read these reports, facts and
judgments that contradicted âourâ version of events would fade into
nothingness. Facts that reinforced our narrative would stand out to me
as if highlighted, to be later deployed by me, my ambassador and my
ministers, like hand grenades in the diplomatic trench warfare. Details
in otherwise complicated reports would be extracted to be telegraphed
back to London, where they would be inserted into ministerial briefings
or press articles. A complicated picture was reduced to a selection of
facts that became factoids, such as the suggestion that Saddam Hussein
imported huge quantities of whiskey or built a dozen palaces, validated
by constant repetition: true, but not the whole truth.
In the end, it became clear even to us that comprehensive sanctions were
counterproductive. They targeted the wrong group of people, and their
effects undermined the necessary international support for the
containment of the Saddam regime. This reality slowly percolated into
our small policy-making group, and eventually led to a change in policy.
As the century turned, the U.S. and initiated a shift in Security
Council policy toward what became known as âsmart sanctionsââwhereby
Iraq could import all civilian goods except those with potential
military application: so-called dual-use goods. But by then, the damage
had been done.
That damage has been more fully revealed since the 2003 U.S.-led
invasion of Iraq. One assumption of those planning that war was that
Iraqâs middle class would quickly recover from Saddamâs removal, and
Iraqâs economy would rapidly thrive. That assumption quickly met the
brute force of the reality that there was no longer an Iraqi middle
class and no economy to speak of. Iraqâs non-oil economy had been more
or less completely destroyed by the dozen years of sanctions that I, and
others, had helped enforce. Anyone with the chanceâmostly the educated
and professional classesâhad left. Within a year of the imposition of
sanctions, Iraqâs GDP had dropped by about three-quarters of its 1990
value to approximately that of the 1940s. By 1996, one million children
under five were malnourished. In a country that had been cholera free,
by 1994 there were 1,344 cases per 100,000 people. Even after the
oil-for-food program came into operation, water treatment plants lacked
the proper spare parts and maintenance; there were extended power cuts.
The population had no choice but to obtain water directly from
contaminated rivers, resulting in turn in massive increases in
water-borne diseases such as typhoid and cholera. Though the statistics
are debated still, and data from Iraq during this period are unreliable,
a recent and thorough academic history of the sanctions era concludes
from a review of epidemiological studies that for the period from 1990
to 2003, there was an âexcess mortality rateâ of more than 500,000 for
children under five. In other words, half a million children died.[127]
Though Saddam Hussein doubtless had a hand too, I cannot avoid my own
responsibility. This was my work; this is what I did.
I have no way to assuage the shame I feel when I contemplate this
episode. I was aware of the reports of humanitarian suffering, but I did
little about them. In discussion within my ministry, I may have
occasionally argued for easing the effects of comprehensive sanctions.
But if I did, I suspect that I argued the political grounds for such a
shiftâthe loss of support for our policiesârather than the urgent moral
and humanitarian arguments. In our ministryâs culture, it was often
deemed âemotionalâ or âimmatureâ to burden arguments with moral
sentiment. Real diplomats were cold-eyed and hard-headed, immune to the
arguments of liberal protesters, journalists and other softheads who did
not understand how the âreal worldâ worked.
For years afterward, I wondered how this might have happened. Why did we
permit this? Or, rather, the actual, direct but more uncomfortable
question: Why did I do this? My colleagues and I were decent people, or
so I preferred to think. Likewise, my ministers and officials who
endorsed the policy and defended it in Parliament and before an
increasingly critical press. It was this very decency that helped still
my doubts, that persuaded me that we could not have been doing wrong.
Later, in recounting this story, my former colleagues or friends would
say, âYou were doing what you were told,â implying thereby that I bore
no guilt and, needless to say, that they bore none either.
And as in all institutions unscrutinized from outside, the hold of
âgroupthinkâ was a firm one upon our little group of policy makersâno
more than half a dozen or so people in the British government, a few
more in the U.S. We reassured one another that we were doing the right
thing. Our arguments sounded all the better the more we rehearsed them
to one another.
The comfortable succor of my institution, in this case the British
Foreign Office, allowed me to ignore the dictates of my own conscience.
My bosses and colleagues were to me as the white-coated instructor in
the Milgram experiment. The man who knew better. The man who held
authority. Paid and committed to my profession and its enveloping
persona, I was more than happy to press the button.
But here the parallel with Milgram ends. Milgram was an experiment. No
one was hurt. Nothing really happened except a point was proven.
Sanctions on Iraq were, unfortunately, no experiment. Though the
arguments we played out in stuffy rooms in the UN in New York often
seemed abstract, the effects of sanctions on ordinary men, women and
children were to them all too painful. In the end, the difference
between what I did and the Milgram experiment was this: In Milgram, the
victim being electrocuted was an actor. In my case, the screams of pain
and anguish coming from the other side of the wall were real.
The âman in the white coatâ problem, as the insight from Milgramâs
experiment might be called, is not just a problem of diplomacy. It takes
little imagination to see how, to varying degrees, it is a problem
intrinsic to any system where people feel dissociated from the
consequences of their actionsâwhere they feel that someone else, not
them, is really in control. Thus, the ultimate paradox of government,
however well-meaning in intent, is revealed. The more government seeks
to act to tackle particular problems, the less individuals are likely to
feel responsible for them. Whatever is legal is thus rendered morally
permissible. Evidence for this is all around us in the decaying
standards of public behavior in many realms, from the shameless greed of
Wall Street bankers, to the brutality and exploitation perpetuated in
the anonymity of the World Wide Web, to the thuggish antics to be
witnessed on public transportation.
The answer is obvious. Confront individuals with the consequences of
their actions. Restore the moral understanding that each of us is
responsible for the world as it is, and for each other. Take away the
man in the white coat.
Relations, Why Jackson Pollock Paintings Are a Better but Still
Inadequate Metaphor, and Why This Has Profound Political Consequences
The chess game is a frequent metaphor for the business of international
relations. Artfully shot photographs of kings and knights adorn many a
book or scholarly article (particularly those about the theory of âIRâ).
The chess game appeals as analogy because it is complicated, it involves
two clearly defined opponents and, above all, because although a very
difficult game, it is ultimately comprehensible: There may be a very
large number of permutations (according to Garry Kasparov, there are
10ÂčÂČâ° possible games), but there are a limited number of outcomes.
Computers can be programed to play chess, as well as if not better than
the best human players.
Such metaphors, therefore, have a reassuring quality: If the game is
played well by a state, a government, they will win, or at least prevent
a lossâas long as our players, or computers and software, are good
enough. The shape and possibilities of the pieces and board are known
and finite. Itâs comforting to think that foreign policy is a bit like
pulling a lever, and after some whirring and clicking, a result pops out
at the other end. Historians and commentators reinforce this suggestion.
Their articles and books abound with the linear narrative: Decision A
leads to policy B leads to outcome C; if only Washington adopts policy
x, result y will surely follow.
Maps and atlases evoke a similar effect. None of them portrays a world
as it is: No globe is big enough. Jorge Luis Borges suggested such a map
in his wonderful story Of Exactitude in Science: a map to the scale of
the Earth, with every manhole cover, every goat path depicted as it
actually is. Such a map would be perfectly accurate but of course wholly
useless. All depictions must therefore reduce and thereby distort. All
maps are nonetheless imbued with a certain implied confidence that their
delineations are meaningful and significant. The neatly drawn lines,
dots and shadings convey a message that the world is ultimately known
and demarcated, complicated but clearly defined.
There are several problems with the chess metaphor, and indeed with the
conventional way of thinking about international relations. In the
discomforting reality of the world today, the number of relevant actors
who may affect the outcome is invariably far greater than two, the
potential moves of these multiple players is unlimited, and therefore
the number of possible interactions in a globalized world is certainly
greater than 10ÂčÂČâ°, even though this is already an unimaginably big
number.
Multiply the billions of connected humans in todayâs world by the
actions available to them, then throw in the reactions and
counterreactions to these initial actions, run the calculation for even
a short while, and you will end up with an impossibly large number of
possible outcomes. That number is massive and possibly infinite; there
are probably insufficient atoms in the universe to equal it. Given this
reality, the hope of a foreign policy of deliberate action to produce
predictable results looks increasingly vain. Instead of pulling a lever
on a machine to produce a predictable result, making foreign policy
starts to look more like a roll of the diceâor more accurately,
selecting a number between one and infinity.
Few dare acknowledge what increasingly appears to be the truthâthat the
world has no defined shape, aside from its continents, rivers and
oceans, and even these shift form and location, now at an alarming
speed. That instead of a chessboard or a web, it is in fact a swirling
miasma of billions upon billions of interactions, not on a fixed
pattern, or a net, but an ever-changing mesh of connections, some
significant but temporary, some long-lasting but inconsequential, a
reality more evocative of the swirls and spatters of a Jackson Pollock
painting than a chessboard.
When we look at some illustrations drawn from this maelstrom, youâll see
the dilemmaâŠ.
In 2009, a spate of high-profile kidnappings in Phoenix left Arizona the
kidnapping capital of the United States. That same year, eighteen people
were killed in Mexico City after a gang of hooded gunmen attacked a
local drug treatment facility, apparently a refuge for rival gang
members. The connection between these two phenomena was a seemingly
harmless U.S. policy aimed at improving border enforcement with Mexico.
The policy was designed in part to placate a domestic constituency
alarmed at high rates of illegal immigration. But it had the adverse and
unexpected consequence of aggravating a series of drug wars in Mexico.
By slowing migration from Mexico, so too it slowed the transfer of drugs
to the north. But as drug supply in the U.S. fell, supplies increased
dramatically in Mexico, lowering domestic prices and fueling a spike in
local drug consumption. Over the next months, gang-related violence and
kidnappings surged as new and old gangs alike sought to mark out their
turf in the newly developing marketplace. With thousands dead and the
violence spreading back to American territory, U.S. policy makers are
now forced to contend with the unintended consequences of actions once
thought to bring greater stability to Americaâs southern border.
It is now well known that Osama bin Ladenâs involvement in the battle of
the Afghan mujahideen against the Soviet army served as the springboard
for Al Qaedaâs campaign of global jihad. The defeat of that armyâs
occupation of Afghanistan, among other factors, helped contribute to the
fall of the Berlin Wall and the collapse of the Soviet empire. Though
bin Laden and Saddam Hussein were wholly unconnected, the 9/11 attacks
created the political momentum for the invasion of Iraq.[128] That
invasion indirectly led to the de facto separation of Iraqâs Kurdish
north, the rise of Iran as the dominant regional power and, likely and
tragically, the demise of the Christian community in Iraq, driven out by
sectarian violence. None of these outcomes was predicted, even by the
invasionâs most imaginative planners.
The weapons and influence of Al Qaeda were a function of bin Ladenâs
personal wealth, which was itself a consequence of his fatherâs large
fortune, made from building for the royal family and others well
connected in oil-rich Saudi Arabia, his home country, a long-standing
U.S. ally. The âoriginalâ Al Qaeda, as some analysts now call it, has
meanwhile spawned several deadly affiliates or âfranchises,â a name
reminiscent of the spread of McDonaldâs burger restaurantsâAl Qaeda in
the Islamic Maghreb (AQIM), Al Qaeda in the Arabian Peninsula (AQAP), AQ
in Somalia, AQ in Afghanistan, the âNigerian Talibanâ Boko Haram, and
terrorist groups without names in London and Miamiâand has helped
inspire murderous attacks from Fort Hood, Texas, to Bali and Mumbai. One
of the planners of the Mumbai rampage, which cost nearly two hundred
lives, was an American who also, it turns out, was for a while an agent
for Americaâs Drug Enforcement Agency, which wanted his help in locating
heroin suppliers in Pakistan. The DEA, it appears, failed to inform
other parts of the massive U.S. intelligence machinery.
Elsewhere, Al Qaeda is also loosely associated with, and serves as
inspiration for, the Al Shabaab Islamist militia, which currently
controls much of southern and central Somalia.
Here, the insatiable global appetite for fish has driven international
fishing fleetsâfrom Japan, Russia and Europeâto plunder Somaliaâs
unprotected waters, denying a livelihood to Somaliaâs many coastal
fishermen. Partly as a result (there are other reasons too), some have
turned to piracy, hijacking vessels in a lucrative trade, which a
substantial flotilla of heavily armed ultramodern warships deployed in
the area has failed so far to prevent. This naval fleet, sometimes
numbering as many as twenty or more vessels, embodies unprecedented
international cooperation, including warships from former antagonists
like Russia, NATO, India and China. âCombined Task Force 150â also
includes the European Unionâs first ever joint naval deployment. But so
far, this unique and expensive military collaboration has failed to stop
or deter the pirates. More people were taken hostage at sea in 2010 than
in any previous year on record.[129]
Some of the proceeds of that piracy, where ship owners often pay several
million dollars to liberate their captured vessels and crews, have found
their way to Al Shabaab, which has used the money to purchase weapons
with which to fight its insurgency against the internationally backed
Somali Transitional Federal Government in Mogadishu. Young men are now
travelling from the U.S., Britain and elsewhere to train with Al Shabaab
and their piracy-funded weapons. National security agenciesâMI5, the
FBIâhave warned of the danger that these radicalized young men pose on
their return to their âhomeâ countries, trained and ready to commit
further acts of violence. In late 2010, a young Somali-American sought
to detonate a bomb at a Christmas tree lighting ceremony in Portland,
Oregon.
Such effects are inherently unpredictable and can appear random, even
though some causes and some effects are, at least in retrospect,
discernible. They do not follow the neat patterns of a flow chart or a
mathematical equation. Though multiple and complex, the model of a chess
game is no more appropriate, either. What we witness in the world is not
ordered, at least in a sequential, logical fashion, but neither is it
chaos. It is entirely wrong to say that the pattern of cause and effect
in the world today is chaotic or anarchic, even if sometimes it seems
that way. It may resemble chaos, but in fact it is a hugely complex and
dynamic mesh of multiple cause and effect and back again (even Jackson
Pollock paintings comprise an underlying order). Given this reality, any
model or any metaphor may oversimplify and thus distort this natureâan
artificial simplicity imposed upon complexity.
Only later will historians, masters of the reductive art of the
narrative, be able to put shape to what seems today formless, and even
then they will be capturing but a tiny part of what comprises existence
now. For now, a better depiction suggests itself, a fantastic mélange
with ends and connections that shift, merge and disappear. To shape this
mesh, to put form to it, to give it names, is to change it, to reduce it
and ultimately to fail to understand it completely. Unfortunately, this
is precisely what governments are required to do.
It is conventional wisdom that with myriad international problems that
cross frontiers, the world needs ever more international diplomacy and
engagement. But it may be, in fact, that we need less, at least of the
kind that currently predominatesâthe lattice of state-to-state relations
and multilateral institutions.
There are now a great many international negotiation processes
addressing a bewildering array of problems, from the familiarâclimate
change, nuclear proliferationâto the obscureâpostal standards and the
standardization of measurements. But on the most acute and urgent
problems, the evidence is mounting that these processes are not
delivering the necessary resultsâeffective solutions to the worldâs
international problems. The measure of the effectiveness of this form of
politics must be as for any form of politics: What are the outputs? What
are the real effects on real problems and people?
The climate change âprocess,â with its summits at Copenhagen (2009) and
CancĂșn (2010), has comprised hundreds of meetings involving thousands of
delegates and, on more than one occasion, âworld leaders.â But the
process has yet to produce any substantive agreement, let alone concrete
and plausibly effective measures, to reduce atmospheric carbon, despite
the vast expenditure of negotiating energy and voluminous reams of
treaty text and media commentary. Meanwhile, the concentration of carbon
in the atmosphere continues to rise.
The G8 Gleneagles summit in 2005 was notable for the extraordinary
length and height of the fences erected, and the ten thousand police
required, to keep protesters away from the tiny group of decision makers
meeting in the remote Scottish location. The summiteers themselves
sought to make history by their commitment to $50 billion in new aid
money. This announcement was claimed to âmake poverty history,â echoing
the rhetoric of the huge âMake Poverty Historyâ campaign, which
culminated in several massive âLive8â concerts that summer, where those
enjoying the music in person or on television were encouraged to lobby
their leaders by sending them text messages asking them to relieve Third
World debt. At the UN World Summit later that year, all member states of
the UN recommitted themselves to the goal of reducing absolute poverty
by half by 2015âthe headline target of the so-called Millennium
Development Goals. (MDG).
It is depressing to relate the utter failure of those making these
commitments to keep to them.[130] Of those making the Gleneagles
declaration, all serious countries and seven of them more or less
democracies, not one fulfilled the promise they had made. Five years
after Gleneagles, it was estimated that G8 pledges would fall short by
$20 billion.[131] The U.S. and European Union had done virtually nothing
to remove the import barriers and agricultural subsidies that do much to
stymie economic growth in developing countries. By 2010, the G8 itself,
perhaps out of embarrassment, had ceased mentioning its aid goals in its
communiquĂ©s. It did, however, make play of yet another new âinitiative,â
this time to target maternal health. The most recent assessment of the
MDG is that they will certainly not be attained, an unsurprising
assessment given the paltry efforts made by the signatories of the UN
declaration to substantiate their rhetoric. Of one thing, however, we
can be sure: There will be more such declarations, freshened up with new
slogans and impassioned speeches or tweets, or Facebook pages, or
whatever, in future.
The recent financial crisis has occasioned massed bouts of international
hand-wringing over global regulation of banking and investment. The G20
countries has emerged as the leading forum to discuss such measures,
clearly necessary to manage the out-of-control flows of unintelligible
financial instruments, like the infamous âcollateralized debt
obligationsâ (CDOs) that spread risk with no oversight. But despite
repeated meetings, communiqués and speeches, here too no effective
policy response has emerged. It has instead become clear that the
financial industryâs lobbyists in each country have conspired to ensure
that every government is unwilling to trade their supposed competitive
advantage for collective measures, like globally agreed and sufficient
capital requirements for lenders. To satiate public concern, instead
these meetings offer âcommitmentsâ to effective controls, and
âprocessesâ to discuss themâno doubt without cease until the next crisis
erupts. Thus, the impression of activity is created, the absence of
concrete action obscured.
Given the gravity of the problems that these international processes are
supposed to address, and yet their feeble outputs, itâs urgent to
consider whatâs going on. The cynical might argue that these processes
are simply rackets run by the powerful, who have no intrinsic interest
in success. In its own way, this is a comforting and self-serving excuse
that requires little response save cynicism on our part. But my own
experience of diplomacy and international negotiation suggests something
more subtle is the problem.
Invariably, when these negotiations and conferences fail, commentators
are quick to point fingers at one participant or other for derailing the
process: the Chinese for eviscerating the Copenhagen climate change
talks, France for blocking Security Council authority for the invasion
of Iraq in 2003. But these accusations may be missing the point: The
problem of international diplomacy is not the actors within it, though
their actions may hint at the more submerged problem. The real problem
may be concealed within the very system itself. Indeed, the problem may
be the system.
Diplomacy is a system. Any systemâlike a clubârequires certain
characteristics in order to participate. And it reinforces these
characteristics merely by existing and by requiring its members to
exhibit these characteristics. The current international system
comprises the conventional institutions of diplomacy. From these
institutions, we can see clearly what characteristics are required to
participate.
Diplomacy and international relations are, by their nature, about nation
states. The United Nations, the European Union, ASEAN, the World Trade
Organization, the G20 are all associations of states. This may seem a
very obvious and trite point to emphasize, but it is essential. For my
experience suggests that states, and their exponents, do not accurately
reflect what humans are about, nor what they want. Thus, it is naive to
expect that their machinations, in the form of interstate diplomacy,
will produce results consistent with humanityâs needs in general.
This problem takes several different forms, and the evidence for it, if
you choose to look, is manifold. The first is that the connection
between what states do and say in international negotiations and what
their populations think is now extremely tenuous, to say the least. In
democracies, the international representative of the state is
accountable to their home ministry, which is led by a politician who is
accountable to the legislature, which is ultimately accountable to the
population which elects its members. This is already a very long chain
of explanation and accountability.
A good example of an acutely important but complicated issue is Iraq
policy. My experience dealing with Iraq policy was that only the very
small group at the coalface of the policy had any hope of a
comprehensive grasp of the many and diverse issues at stake: WMD,
sanctions, international law, the dynamics of the UN Security Council,
to mention just a few, all of which themselves were extraordinarily
complicated. My ministers, whose job it was to explain and âsellâ the
policy in public and to Parliament, usually had only a very general and
hazy grasp of the subject. In Parliament, there were no MPs who could
equal the officialsâ knowledge and expertise, and thus properly hold
them to account. In any case, during the four and a half years that I
worked on Iraq policy inside the British government, I was never
questioned by any MP directly about my work, nor did any journalist ever
closely question me with any serious expertise. The picture in the U.S.
is similar.
One consequence of this extraordinarily dissociated chain between
diplomat and citizen is that the diplomat can have no accurate idea of
what the citizen wants. Hence, this requires diplomats to assume, or
rather invent what they think the citizenâhis nationâwants. I know this
because I did this myself many times. It is a function of the
inculcation process diplomats must go through to join and then embody
their professionâthe assumption that âweâ know best. Diplomats, by the
nature of their job, are encouraged to believe that they can determine
what is in their nationâs interests, without consulting those in whose
name they claim to be operating.
This process of assuming or inventing the desires and requirements of a
state, often called âinterests,â is usually conducted in secret by
exchange of telegrams or classified e-mails, or in policy submissions to
senior officials and political masters. I have participated many times
in such exercises. With exquisite concision, the official will describe
the issue at hand, then he or she will articulate what is at stake for
âusââour âinterests,â in short. In recent years, it has become
fashionable for the exponents of foreign policy to talk about âvaluesâ
as important in diplomacyâthings like democracy and human rights. But in
truth, the underlying calculus remains little changed, as does the
diplomatic mindset, and this is no surprise, for it is only natural for
the exponent of the state to think in terms of what his state needs and
wants; it is to the diplomat as to a cow eating grass or mooing; it is
what they do.
It would be absurd for a diplomat to adopt a different set of criteria
to guide their work and policies, and would certainly guarantee a short
career. Such interests typically, and by inherited tradition, take the
form of a hierarchy of priorities where securityâthe requirement to
secure the state and its populationâranks at the top, followed by
economic interests. There is little rigor in these delineations and
orderings, and indeed only rarely do officials distinguish between types
of interest, instead talking in more general terms about what âweâ may
want in any given situation. The identification between diplomat and
state cannot be overemphasized. While both security and economic
interests would fit onto most peopleâs lists of what is important, only
a very few people would, I suspect, declare them as paramount in all
situations or as their sole requirements in any situation.
The premise of the international system, and the state exponents who
populate it, is a fundamentally incredible oneâthat the needs and wants
of the Earthâs billions of people can be boiled down into separate and
discrete subsets of interests which can then be meaningfully arbitrated.
This is difficult to grasp because we have become so acclimatized to the
state-based system: the international diplomatic forums with their
neatly lettered name cards adorning serried rows at the UN General
Assembly or European Council. But reflect for a moment and the absurdity
becomes clear: How is it a tiny group of people can possibly know what
is best for their country of millions? By extension, it is equally
implausible to expect that a collection of such tiny groups, meeting at,
say, the UN or G20, can produce meaningful and effective agreements for
the whole globe? The disconnection is simply too great. They are
required to assume, to guess. They know it, as I knew it. But it is the
rest who believe it.
The problem is more insidious and damaging in its effects than merely
this. The requirement of the system is that the needs and wants of the
worldâs peoples are reduced into such subsetsâa reductive requirement.
That need to reduce the complexity of reality into simplicity imposes
upon the diplomats and other denizens of the system an unnatural and
distorting burdenâto turn their understanding of the world, and our
needs upon it, into something else: the calculus of states. Most of the
time this process is invisible, assumed and unremarked upon. Only
occasionally are its aberrations so gross that they break the surface of
our indifferenceâfor me, it was the experience of Iraq sanctions where I
realized, and only in retrospect, the gross divide between my own
beliefs and understanding of what was right, and the way I was required
to thinkâand doâat the time.
There is an additional negative consequence of this state-dominated mode
of thinking. The chess game requires two sides to be played: white and
black. The process of simplifying and overstating our own needs, known
as calculating our interests, requires a reciprocal technique. If there
is to be an âUs,â there must also be a âThem.â
This happened on the Iraq sanctions issue at the UN Security Council,
where the diplomats gaily perpetuated the national divisions between
opposing delegations, even when there were no facts to disagree over. I
was a willing participant in this farce: the UK/U.S. would veto
proposals made by the âotherâ side, in this case France and Russia, even
if we ourselves had made the very same proposal a few weeks earlier and
they had blocked them. The effect of such essentializingâthe segregation
of ourselves into two competing sidesâwas not to reduce conflict, but to
perpetuate it.
It is not coincidence that it is governments that perform this
essentializing. They must. It is necessary for government, and the
diplomats who represent it, and the politicians who lead it, to claim
that only they can speak for the whole country. Equally, therefore, they
must affirm the nature of the international system by accepting that
other governments speak for their whole countries. A modern diplomat
would deny that they are so crass as to generalize about other cultures
and countries in the way that I have described. Of course, they aver,
when they talk about Iranâs policy, they mean the policy of the Iranian
government, and indeed that is often how they will describe it.
But despite this designative care, the habit of referring to whole
countries in the singular and referring to their government as the
embodiment of that state is one as deep-rooted as the state-based
international system itself. To change the naming of the actors, to
remove the assumption that governments represent the whole of their
countries, would be to change the nature of the international system,
from one based around states as the primary unit of agency, to one based
on some other unit. But as long as governments wish to hold sway in
international policy and decision making, they must continually reaffirm
not only their own but each otherâs legitimacy to speak for their
countries, even when the government is as grotesquely undemocratic as,
say, the Syrian or North Korean regimes.
One of the seminal texts that helped define the nature of diplomacy is
by François de CalliÚres in Paris, published in 1716.[132] De CalliÚres
saw the principal function of diplomacy as moderating and managing the
clash of conflicting interests as efficiently as possible. The diplomat
was required to assess how the interests of his state, and the other
state, could be met in terms acceptable to both.
One can see how remarkably similar this conception of diplomacy is to
the way it is usually conceived today. Yet the world is remarkably
different. The postwar establishment of new multilateral diplomatic
machineriesâthe United Nations, NATO and the European Unionâwhile
creating new forums for state-to-state interactions, has not altered the
fundamental idea that diplomacy is about states identifying their
interests and arbitrating them with one another: that these interests
and identities are susceptible to calculation. Indeed, these
institutions are premised on the very notion that states can meet there
and decide upon their common problems. It is therefore no surprise that
diplomats tend to render the world and its myriad problems into these
shapes. That this process is becoming more and more artificial, and
disconnected from the reality of the forces at work in the world, is
only now becoming evident enough to compel change.
The negative consequences of this kind of thinking can be clearly seen
in negotiations over issues of common global concern, like climate
change. Here, where a shared solution is clearly necessary and urgent,
the habit of state-led thinking still dominates. While âworld leadersâ
and UN officials pontificated about the lofty goals of the process, the
negotiators in national delegations in the trenches of the conference
resorted to type. Zero-sum bargaining over concessions and commitments
dominated the discussions, with the usual rancor and finger-pointing
when a dealâpredictablyâproved impossible to find. Some delegates
suggested that the Earthâs atmosphere was divisible and that the
industrialized nations had already taken their âshare,â as if the
atmosphere were a cake to be sliced up.
As the head of Greenpeace dejectedly stated at the dismal end of the
Copenhagen summit: âIt seems there are too few politicians in this world
capable of looking beyond the horizon of their own narrow self-interest,
let alone caring much for the millions of people who are facing down the
threat of climate change,â he said. âIt is now evident that beating
global warming will require a radically different model of politics than
the one on display here in Copenhagen.â He didnât say what that model
was, however.
Some would argue that the solution to this problem is to increase the
number of supranational institutions like the European Union or the
United Nations, where unelected officials chosen by the member states
can somehow transcend the differences that bedevil nation states.
However, here too the outputs are disappointing. Again, we are
confronted with a vast, confusing and obscure tableau of processes and
groups and subgroups that pretend to solve common problems, from
terrorist financing to avian flu and the Middle East peace process. It
is clear that the existence of such processes can have in itself a
debilitative effect: The mere existence of a âprocessâ creates the
erroneous impression that something is being done, when it is not.
The dysfunctional Copenhagen climate process is one example. Another,
lesser known, is the âpeace processâ to resolve the illegal occupation
of the Western Sahara. This âprocessâ has lasted since the cease-fire in
1990 between the occupiers, Morocco, and the representatives of the
indigenous people, the Sahrawisâtwenty years and countingâwhen Morocco
agreed to a referendum for the territoryâs people to decide their
status, an agreement and legal requirement endorsed many times by the
âinternational communityâ at the UN. Every country in the world pretends
to support this process, run by the UN, but none does anything in
reality to advance it. The referendum has never taken place. In fact,
the âprocessâ is a way of shelving the issue indefinitely, to permit the
existing status quoâof occupation. The process is thus a sham, the
opposite of what it pretends to be.
Both the United Nations and the European Union have contributed
enormously to limiting the twentieth-century scourge of international
conflict. The EU has bound European countries together so tightly that
war, once habitual, has now become unthinkable. The UNâs sixty-year
existence has witnessed a steep decline in the interstate conflict
prohibited by its charter. But in these successes, new weaknesses have
emerged, not least in dealing with the more fluid and boundary-less
problems of the twenty-first century. The UN Security Council was
established to prevent wars between states. Today, not less than 80
percent of its agenda concerns issues involving nonstate actors, and
conflicts both within and sometimes transcending states, like
terrorism.[133]
Fatally, all such multilateral or supranational institutions suffer an
irredeemable deficit of democratic legitimacy. The greater the distance
between representative and elector, the less legitimate that
representative. The UN Secretary-General is, at least in theory,
supposed to represent us, but no one except the public is expected to
believe that he does. The UN Secretary-General is well aware that it is
the realpolitikers of the five permanent members of the Security Council
who mail his paycheck every month, and he behaves accordingly, just as
the president of the EU takes care to keep in close step with the major
powers of the EU: France, the UK and Germany. I have often attended
meetings between my ambassador at the UN and the Secretary-General where
he would be told in unmistakable terms what party line he and his staff
were required to toe. It didnât have to be spelled out in threats,
merely implied and hinted at. He invariably got the message.
For the ordinary citizen, institutions like the UN and the EU are even
more impenetrable and opaque than their already distant national
governments. I run a nonprofit diplomatic consultancy. Its staff works
full-time to understand the worldâs diplomatic and multinational
institutions, and we find it difficult to work out who does what, and
where real decisions are made. Pity the ordinary citizen seeking a
hearing in the shiny but dismal corridors of the EUâs institutions in
Brussels. Even for the acute, it is all but impossible to find out who
is truly responsible for anything. It is reminiscent of nothing so much
as the pathetic queues of provincial Chinese who make desperate but
hopeless pilgrimage to Beijing to seek settlement of grievances against
corrupt or incompetent Communist Party officials.
Moreover, but more subtly, the officials themselves are dangerously
detached from the problemâand the peopleâthey are seeking to arbitrate.
I saw this in the UN Security Councilâit was a curiously dry and boring
place to work despite its dramatic agenda of genocide and civil war. The
blood and emotion of these conflicts was absent in its discussions, and
it was not a good absence: It was not conducive to better negotiation,
but to worse. For one thing, the parties to the disputes on the
councilâs agenda were almost invariably absent from these
deliberationsâit is hardly a recipe for good decision making to ignore
the views of those most concerned. Moreover, the emotional and moral
content of events, so crucial to the motivation to solve such problems,
was missing. Between the reality of the problems and our deliberations
was a huge and unbridgeable divide, not only of actual distanceâfor we
were usually many thousands of miles from the disputes we discussedâbut
of import.
These deficits are intrinsic to supranational institutions, just as the
limits of nation-state thinking are inherent to the nation-state system,
a system that has, since the Peace of Westphalia of 1648, dominated
world affairs. Given these deficits, the answer to our global problems
may not in fact be more diplomacy and international negotiation, at
least not of the current kind. Thus conventional wisdom is turned on its
head: We do not need more state-to-state diplomacy to solve these
problems; we may, in fact, need less. And instead of relying on
state-to-state diplomacy to manage the world, we must do so ourselves.
As writer Parag Khanna has commented, âAs was the case a millennium ago,
diplomacy now takes place among anyone who is someone; its prerequisite
is not sovereignty but authority.â
The deficits of the state-based system are commonly known, yet these
systems endure, even when the operators of the systemâmy many and
cynical diplomatic colleaguesâhave themselves ceased to believe in them.
As they take the stand at public inquiries, or address the press, they
can hardly believe that anyone still believes them. It is a hollow,
hollow feeling and I know it. These systems will continue to endure
until those in whose name they claim to function withdraw their consent.
The pact is broken; it doesnât work. To name a problem as
âinternationalâ is to absolve oneself of responsibility and to place a
solution in the hands of those proven manifestly incapable. The
international is not international any more; it is simply us.
And here is the most insidious and yet hidden effect of the
international systemâof interstate diplomacyâas it currently exists. It
is not that this system may exacerbate differences, force its players to
define themselves more starkly than they otherwise might, nor that its
exponents must naturally reflect a calculus not of the messy and diverse
human family but of these strange and artificial units, states, or that
these exponents are, as I once was, wholly separated from their sense of
moral responsibility for their actions. These deficits are not the worst
aspect of this system. (The âLive8â text messages to the G8 Summit
provide a clue.)
The most dangerous effect of the system is not that it doesnât work; it
is that we, in whose name it is supposed to function, condone it,
pretend to believe it contrary to all evidence and permit it to
continue.[134]
It is one thing to accept this critique, but it is another to embody
this philosophical shift. In a world of global terrorism, a rising India
and China, and intense national competition for scarce resources, what
meaningful action is available to the individual? How can the world be
made to reflect its human reality rather than its inherited and
inappropriate delineations of segregated states and peoples?
One obvious answer is for individuals to organize across nations and
states around common causes. This is already beginning to happen:
witness the global movements around climate change or the protection of
human rights. (Ideas to guide such action will be more fully elaborated
later.) Less encouragingly, such borderless cooperation is also visible
in the transnational organization of drug trafficking or jihadist
terrorism, where extremists of many different nationalities have
gathered around the flag of the new Umma.
It is too easy to succumb to defeatism in regarding the world todayâits
weapons, its states, its self-serving and bumptious leaders. How on
earth are we supposed to deal with that? It might be revealing to look
at an issue that inspires the most pessimism and also the most horror.
Nuclear weapons embody in their very existence the possibility of
appalling destruction and indeed the annihilation of humanity as a
species. In some ways, they manifest the gross inhumanity of the state
systemâthat in order to defend the state, governments are prepared to
use weapons that threaten the destruction not only of their own
population, but the entire worldâs.
The conventional answer to this problem has been to look to governments
to get rid of nuclear weapons. Even the demonstrators massing on the
streets waving banners ultimately urge their governments to respond. Is
this a realistic ambition?
The 2010 review conference of the Non-Proliferation Treaty (NPT), the
cornerstone of the worldâs efforts to reduce nuclear weapons, lasted a
month and involved highly skilled delegations from someone hundred
ninety countries. The agreement they reached was lauded as a success,
primarily because, unlike previous review conferences for the last
decade, this gathering had actually achieved agreement. But the content
of the agreementâthe outputâwas feeble, despite the international
atmosphere being its most propitious for decades.
As usual, the âoutcome documentâ was longâtwenty-eight jargon-laden and
barely comprehensible pagesâwith a misleading sixty-four âaction
points,â most of which amount to no substantive action whatsoever. The
vast majority are declarative: âreaffirming,â âwelcomingâ or ânoting.â
The press, focusing on one small part of the forest, made great play of
the agreement to hold a conferenceâin the futureâon a nuclear-free
Middle East, but even that agreement left out the only country in the
Middle East currently possessing nuclear weapons, Israel. Otherwise, the
conference agreed merely to encourage the nuclear weapons states to make
more concrete progress toward nuclear disarmament and reduce the use of
nuclear weapons in their military doctrines; but attempts to make such
disarmament concrete and obligatory through a nuclear weapons convention
were fiercely resisted by the nuclear weapons states. As even the most
favorable commentators put it, all that was agreed was a further
process, not an output.[135]
In its closing statement, Cuba noted pointedly what the review
conference had not agreed: no timetable on nuclear disarmament; no
commitment to begin negotiations on a nuclear weapons convention; no
clear commitment to stop the development of nuclear weapons; no call for
withdrawal of nuclear weapons to home territories (i.e., out of Europe);
and no legally binding negative security assurancesâwe shall come to
these strange creatures later.
President Obama has declared his intention of ultimately ridding the
world of nuclear weapons. The Global Zero campaign, supported by many
prominent former statesmen and women and highlighted in a popular
documentary film, Countdown to Zero, is advocating the same. But it is a
fair bet that in the current state-based dispensation, these noble
efforts will fail. For it is implausible to expect that China, or
Russia, or even France or Britain, let alone Israel or Pakistan, will
give up this ultimate guarantor of their security, even if some
reductions may nevertheless be possible. As total arsenals go down,
louder and louder will become the argument that nuclear weapons have
successfully prevented mass conventional war between their possessors.
Itâs a plausible argument, as long as the proxy conventional wars that
these powers fought on the territories of others are ignored. But
nonetheless, the argument has force. Total disarmament relies on
something that evidently does not existâcomplete confidence and trust in
the commitments of others that they too have disarmed irreversibly, and
that they will not launch conventional attack.
The NPTâs answer to this problem is fundamentally ridiculous. To the
non-nuclear states who demand assurance that they will not be the victim
of nuclear attack, the nuclear weapons states (NWS) have offered
âreverse security guaranteesââpromises that they will not use nuclear
weapons against non-nuclear states in certain circumstances. The
âprogressâ of the 2010 review conference was that the conference agreed
to consider making these âguaranteesâ legally binding. In other words,
if a nuclear weapons state dropped the bomb or bombs on a non-nuclear
state, the victim state would be able to seek redress in an
international court, presuming that there would remainâpost-apocalypseâa
government, lawyers or courts with which to press such a claim. And such
legal obligations would arise only if the nuclear weapons states agree
to them, which they have yet to do: At the review conference, they
agreed only to âconsiderâ them. Such reverse guarantees, even if legally
enforceable, are unlikely to provide much reassurance if, for instance,
Ukraine finds itself dealing with a fascist-led nuclear-armed Russia,
which unfortunately is a more plausible prospect than the legally
binding reverse security assurances.
Under the NPT, the UK, like all other declared nuclear-armed states, is
in theory committed to disarm itself of all of its nuclear weapons. The
NPT was founded on a conceptual bargainâthat the rest of the world would
not develop their own nuclear weapons capability, as long as the nuclear
weapons states agreed to get rid of theirs, eventually. One indicator of
the âprogressâ made at the 2010 conference was that the UK for the first
time declared the full number of its nuclear weapons. No other declared
NWS has done so. Revealingly but perhaps also most honestly, France
insisted that the goal of the NPT âprocessâ not be stated as a âworld
free of nuclear weapons,â but the creation of âconditions which will
lead to a world free of nuclear weapons.â
Earlier that year, the U.S. and Russia agreed under the Strategic Arms
Reduction Treaty, or START, to a reduction in their arsenals of nuclear
weapons. Heralded as offering substantial new reductions, some analysts
judge that in reality the agreement barely affects the number of actual
deployed weapons, and involves no reduction in the number of Russian
launch vehicles.[136] Both powers continue to maintain hundreds of
nuclear delivery systems at Cold War levels of alert: ready to be
launched within a few minutes. One respected think tank noted that
âwhile the operational readiness of some weapon systems has been
reduced, there has been no major change in the readiness levels of most
of the nuclear weapon systems in the postâCold War era.â[137]
Instead, it is more plausible to refer to, reinforce and promote a
reality that the diplomats, politicians and analysts refuse to
contemplate. The calculus of nuclear weapons depends upon the existence
of the chess boardâa âThemâ and an âUs.â If you attack me, I will attack
you: black and white pieces, segregated and discrete. If those
distinctions no longer exist, the game cannot be played. If instead of
two distinct sets of pawns and pieces, clearly separated across the
board, all pieces are but varying shades of gray, intermingled and
spread all over the board. This depiction is much closer to the
contemporary reality, and the more time passes, the more accurate it
will become. A Pakistani attack on New Delhi would kill hundreds of
thousands of Muslims. An attack on Israel would kill thousands of Arabs.
Any use of nuclear weapons, more or less anywhere, would have
devastating effects on a highly interlinked global economy. Destroying
New York would kill people from every country on earth: people of more
than ninety different nationalities were killed in the destruction of
the twin towers; one borough of the city contains 174 different
nationalities. Killing Them would mean killing Us.
Nuclear weapons make this doubly true as even a limited strike on one
country would, according to recent research, imply appalling
consequences for the whole planet. Studies have shown that even a
âsmall-scaleâ nuclear exchange, say, India and Pakistan launching fifty
weapons each against each other, would have devastating consequences not
only for the countries directly targeted but for the global environment
and potentially for the survival of mankind.[138] Thus, nuclear weapons
are revealed in their true nature: not as weapons of deterrence or
plausible utility, but as mankindâs suicide pill.
This truth is already slowly spreading among some enlightened members of
the military, who are realizing that the use of nuclear weapons by
states is basically implausibleâand self-destructiveâin almost any
circumstance. The most likely people to use nuclear weapons are not
states but suicidal millenarian terrorists. Osama bin Ladenâs deputy
Ayman al-Zawahiri has already written a book dismissing moral objections
to the use of weapons of mass destruction, including nuclear
weapons.[139] Our possession of nuclear weapons is no deterrent to such
threats, but the very existence of nuclear weapons provides a possible
method for these extremists. Thus, the best thing would be to do away
with them altogether.
Establish this as a cultural truth, and eventually that understanding
will filter through. Wherever possible, travel, interact, make love,
argue, live with people elsewhere. Engage; co-mingle. Resist the efforts
of governments and others to paint the Other in stark colors, whether
black or white. Throw away the chessboard; cut the ground from under
those who would pretend humanity is but chessmen. Cease using the
outdated nomenclature of a world that is already receding into history;
stop naming; stop dividing.
One surprising conclusion from this analysis might come as a shock to
the antiglobalization protesters storming the next G8 Summit: What might
be the most effective tactic ultimately to get rid of nuclear weapons is
not less globalization, but more. The deeper the intermingling, the more
dense the mesh connecting humanity, the less the chessboard may be
clearly defined, the more absurd becomes the calculus of nuclear
weapons, and indeed of states as discrete entities, themselves.
Interestingly, this reasoning also applies to other harmful, if less
apocalyptic, forms of warfare. Many have expressed concern that China or
Russia are able to launch devastating âcyber attacksâ against Western
institutions, and economic and financial infrastructure. But one Chinese
official has reportedly dismissed this option, primarily on the grounds
of Chinaâs dependence on U.S. financial stabilityâChina owns nearly a
trillion dollarsâ worth of securitized American government debtâa cyber
attack on Wall Street would harm China as much as it harmed the
U.S.[140]
These examples suggest that the antiglobalizers storming the
G8-protecting riot police are precisely wrong.
Instead of conventional theories of government and international
relations, we need a new set of toolsâand perhaps a dose of humility
too, for a complex world may defy all but a general understanding of its
inherent and pervasive unpredictability and contingency. In fact, we
need the tools that interpret complex systems.
Malcolm Gladwell has popularized the concept of the âtipping point,â the
idea from complexity theory that even small events may trigger complex
systems to âtipâ over from one condition into another. Historian Niall
Ferguson and others have begun to suggest that empires, such as the
American âempire,â are complex systems and thus may be highly vulnerable
to outside events, perhaps seemingly minor, over which they have little
or no control, causing their downfall.[141] In finance, Nassim Nicholas
Taleb has suggested that highly aberrational âblack swanâ events,
hitherto regarded as extremely rare, are in reality much more frequent
than predicted, and moreover have vastly more dramatic consequences. The
May 2010 âflash crashâ on the Dow Jones seemed to prove his point.
There is, then, a growing realization that human affairs make up in
their totality a complex system. Complex systems share characteristics
which have important but barely noted consequences for politics.
Complex systems are not chaotic. They are not simple and ordered, but
neither are they an uncontrolled mess. Complex systems are instead
something âin between,â as Professor Scott Page, an expert on
complexity, has observed.[142]
Another characteristic is perhaps the most telling, and recollects the
stadium wave or the suicide bomber. The actions of one individual may
redound in very powerful and consequential ways. This insight is a
conclusion completely at odds with contemporary notions of the ranking
and power of government, state and individual. The individual is not
powerless, not subordinate; in fact individuals are a potent agent of
lasting change in the whole system.
If individuals begin to behave in the way suggested in this bookâto act
themselves to produce desired political results, cooperating and
negotiating directly with others affectedâthen a new dispensation will
emerge, something that we may not yet be able to describe. This is the
phenomenon of âemergence,â a key characteristic of complexity: that from
the combined actions of many agents, acting according to their own
microcosmic preferences and values, a new condition may emerge from the
bottom up, almost unconsciously, and certainly without imposition by
government, god or anyone else.
Intellectually, we understand that turning a vast heterogeneous mesh
into a chessboard of discrete players is to do something inherently
reductive, oversimplifying and thus, in its way, deceptive if not
downright dishonest. It is simply not possible credibly to claim that
any authority, like any historian, can understand this huge pattern of
interaction and connection. They cannot know, yet they must claim to.
Yet there is something still more insidious going on. In claiming
authority to organize our affairs, to order the Pollock-like mélange
into something that it isnât, governments take away something more
crucial from usâour own agency. Or rather, they take away our own sense
of agency, for in truth our control over events never left us, only our
belief in its existence.
Contrary to common assumptions, individuals acting collectively have a
far greater power to control their circumstances, and indeed those of
the whole world, than governments pretend. The immediate overthrow of
governments now would bring only chaos. But as individuals and groups
begin to assert their own agency over decisions and events within their
own reach, there will eventually emerge a much wider and more
fundamental effect, one that would ultimately amount to a revolution in
how we organize our affairs.
How this might look is inherently unpredictable. No one can know how the
sum of such deliberate actions might appear. This is, above all, a
cultural change not an architectural redesign of political structures.
Gustav Landauer, a nineteenth-century theorist, once wrote:
The state is not something which can be destroyed by a revolution, but
is a condition, a certain relationship between human beings, a mode of
human behavior; we destroy it by contracting other relationships, by
behaving differently.
It will start with individuals acting upon their convictions. It will
continue and gather force as they join togetherâperhaps in person,
perhaps on the Webâto organize, not to campaign, but to act and embody
the changes they seek. These networks of cooperation may be temporary;
they may be long-lasting. They may encompass a street, or the
inhabitants of a building, cooperating to manage their affairs. They may
span the globe as millions act together to address a shared concern. The
embryonic forms of such cooperation are already evident: There are
consumers cooperatives that bargain for lower prices; âcommon security
clubsâ where unemployed people share job-seeking skills, barter services
and organize shared childcare;[143] local groups where unemployed
handymen and babysitters offer their services to the community;[144] and
Internet campaigns that enroll millions across the globe.
As the realization of governmentsâ dwindling power spreads, this new
form of politics will become less about protest or petition and more
about action. The sum of these collectives will not have a fixed
structure; they will ebb and flow, responsive to the changing needs and
passions of the population. They may be local, but they will also
transcend borders, inevitably weakening the mental hold of boundaries
and inherited national identities upon peoples with common interests.
One day, so strong may be this new culture of collective collaboration,
and this mesh of different networks of cooperation, that our existing
institutions, based on the singularizing, centralizing unit of national
government, and indeed the notion of the nation state, may wither away,
unneeded, outdated, irrelevant.
This mesh of networks, of collaborating groups both local and
transnational, represents in its indefinite shapes its dynamic changing
nature and its responsiveness to the needs of its participantsâus,
ordinary peopleâa form much closer to the actual nature of the world
today, its diverse and massive flows, the multiplying and shifting
identities of its peoples, and above all its manifold challenges. And in
its consonance with the nature of the world, that mesh, that
shapeâindeterminate, unstructured, changing though it may beâoffers
paradoxically much greater stability and coherence than the fixed and
hierarchical forms of organization we have inherited from the past. The
world should be ordered according to our needs, not the projections and
requirements of static institutions.
The future nature of this world cannot be foreseen; it will emerge. But
one thing is sure. No longer would we be fooled into seeing the world as
a chessboard, demarcated, separated, neat, but instead it would seem to
us as it really is.
In colonial India, the British forbade Indians from making their own
salt, and charged steeply for it as a form of indirect taxation on the
subject people, a tax that hit the poorest especially hard. In 1930,
Mahatma Gandhi decided to attack this injustice directly, and organized
a march to Indiaâs coast, where salt could be made from seawaterâfor
freeâdirectly challenging the British monopoly of salt production.
Gandhiâs âsalt marchâ or âSalt Satyagrahaâ is rightly renowned as one of
the most important acts of political protest in recent history.
Gandhi chose to attack the salt tax, against the advice of some of his
political colleagues, because it was both a tool and a symbol of
Britainâs oppression. Thus, the action to undermine the tax assumed both
a practical and symbolic value. Gandhi carefully planned the march,
choosing only his most disciplined cohorts from his own ashram, and
sending scouts to reconnoiter villages ahead. He built up public
expectations and attention with press conferences before and during the
march. The salt march above all manifested a core principle of Gandhiâs
political philosophyâthat of satyagrahaâa synthesis of the Sanskrit
words satya (truth) and agraha (holding firmly to). In the common
shorthand of todayâs times, Gandhiâs philosophy is often summarized as
ânonviolenceâ or âpassive resistance,â and indeed it encompasses these
elements. But for Gandhi, satyagraha had a deeper and more positive
significance, not merely an absence of violence but more a strength. In
his words:
Truth (satya) implies love, and firmness (agraha) engenders and
therefore serves as a synonym for force. I thus began to call the Indian
movement Satyagraha, that is to say, the Force which is born of Truth
and Love or nonviolence, and gave up the use of the phrase âpassive
resistance,â in connection with it, so much so that even in English
writing we often avoided it and used instead the word âsatyagraha.â[145]
Above all, Gandhi believed that means were intimately connected with
ends. Indeed, they were to him the same thing, as connected as a tree to
its seed. If you used violence, you could expect nothing but further
violence in return. Satyagraha by contrast engaged a forceâloveâto which
there was no resistance. The salt march demonstrated clearly how these
concepts, combined with an acute political intelligence, played out in
practice.
The British, at first dismissive, were confused as to how to respond to
the march, which gained huge publicity in India and worldwide. It was
reported that sixty thousand Indians came to hear Gandhi speak on the
eve of the march. Not one to eschew melodrama, Gandhi warned that his
speech might comprise the last words of his life; he invoked a
compelling spirit of self-sacrifice: âMy task shall be done if I perish
and so do my comrades.â As the march progressed, crowds of tens and
sometimes hundreds of thousands gathered along the way. Gandhiâs
marchers slept in the open in the villages they passed through, asking
only food and water, the better, Gandhi judged, to recruit Indiaâs poor
whose support would be vital to imperialismâs defeat.
After a march lasting nearly three weeks and nearly two hundred fifty
miles, building up expectations and political tension all the way,
Gandhi arrived at the coastal village of Dandi in Gujarat, where raising
a handful of mud which he then boiled to make salt, Gandhi declared,
âWith this, I am shaking the foundations of the British Empire.â Gandhi
implored his followers and all Indians to follow his example and make
illegal salt, breaking the British monopoly and depriving the empire of
an important source of revenue. In the weeks that followed, sixty
thousand people were arrested for making salt. At Peshawar, British
troops killed over two hundred peaceful demonstrators. Gandhi was
arrested while planning his next satyagraha at the Dharasana salt works.
The march went ahead, eventually under the leadership of Sarojini Naidu,
a female poet and freedom fighter. She warned her fellow Satyagrahis to
expect to be beaten, but that âyou must not even raise a hand to fend
off blows.â Sure enough, soldiers beat the marchers with steel-tipped
clubs. As United Press reported:
Not one of the marchers even raised an arm to fend off the blows. They
went down like ten-pins. From where I stood I heard the sickening whacks
of the clubs on unprotected skulls. The waiting crowd of watchers
groaned and sucked in their breaths in sympathetic pain at every blow.
Those struck down fell sprawling, unconscious or writhing in pain with
fractured skulls or broken shoulders. In two or three minutes the ground
was quilted with bodies. Great patches of blood widened on their white
clothes. The survivors without breaking ranks silently and doggedly
marched on until struck down.[146]
Despite its receiving worldwide attention, this sacrifice failed to win
any immediate concessions from the British, and it would be another
seventeen years before India would at last be independent. Though
Indiaâs first prime minister, Jawaharlal Nehru, acknowledged the
enormous importance of the salt march in mobilizing Indiaâs masses
around the goal of independence, his Congress Party, to which Gandhi
then belonged, eventually abandoned satyagraha as a political technique.
Historians today tend to view the Second World War as the more
significant factor in ending imperial rule in India.[147] But the Salt
Satyagraha is remembered still for its signal achievement in one crucial
aspect. As one British colonial administrator noted at the time,
âEngland can hold India only by consent; we canât rule it by the sword.â
And thanks to the salt march, they had lost that consent.
Though technically the more powerful of the two antagonistsâwith the
power of the state, of arrest and ultimately of forceâBritain lost the
contest against Gandhiâs force of will, satyagraha. Those who were
clubbed to the ground ended up victorious, for by their reaction to the
march, the British lost the consent of the Indian population, upon which
they relied to maintain their colonial rule. The Salt Satyagraha thus
qualifies as one of the most effective political actions of recent
times. It is worth summarizing why:
The goal of the salt march was to make salt, directly confronting the
British salt tax and denying the colonialists revenue, thus the action
itself contributed to the political result intended.
one British administrator later confessed in an internal memo that they
would have preferred violence.
created enormous moral force, which not only helped recruit followers
but was also crucial in garnering massive international attention and
sympathy.
In an age of terrorism and violent counterreaction, such examples can
seem quaint and irrelevant, but surveys suggest that even in the Muslim
world, Al Qaedaâs use of violence, and in particular its targeting of
civilians, alienates more followers than it attracts. The persuasive
power of self-sacrifice and nonviolence remains undiminished, even if
violence seems once again the more fashionable.
In his short manual Guerrilla Warfare, Che Guevara dismisses terrorist
violence as ineffective:
We sincerely believe that terrorism is of negative value, that it by no
means produces the desired effects, that it can turn a people against a
revolutionary movement, and that it can bring a loss of lives to its
agents out of proportion to what it produces.[148]
Guevara preferred direct military confrontation with the repressive
forces of Batista, Cubaâs then dictator. In modern Mexico, recognizing
that conditions, though unjust, were less repressive than in
prerevolutionary Cuba, the leader of the Zapatista rebels in Mexicoâs
Chiapas region, Subcomandante Marcos, prefers irony and nonviolence to
bring home the Zapatistasâ message of the exploitation of Mexicoâs
indigenous peoples. As Marcos put it:
We donât want to impose our solutions by force, we want to create a
democratic space. We donât see armed struggle in the classic sense of
previous guerrilla wars, that is as the only way and the only
all-powerful truth around which everything is organized. In a war, the
decisive thing is not the military confrontation but the politics at
stake in the confrontation. We didnât go to war to kill or be killed. We
went to war in order to be heard.[149]
Gandhi himself sometimes despaired of the Indian peopleâs propensity for
violence. Exploiting his immense public standing and moral authority, on
several occasions he used hunger strikes as a tool of political
persuasion, including to seek an end to fighting between Muslims and
Hindus.
This technique too has modern relevance. The hunger strikes by
Republican inmates in the Maze prison in Northern Ireland in 1981
resulted in the deaths of several strikers, most famously Bobby Sands,
who was elected as a member of the British Parliament during his hunger
strike. After ten inmates died, the British government offered some
concessions. The most lasting impact, however, was, like the Salt
Satyagraha, deeper in its effects on that intangible: will. By 1985, the
British government, had negotiated the Anglo-Irish agreement that gave
the Irish Republic for the first time a consultative role in the
government of Northern Ireland, and heralded the peace process that
resulted in the Good Friday agreement of 1998, which largely brought an
end, though sadly not yet final, to the violence and sectarian strife
that had benighted the province for over thirty years.
In 2009, a forty-two-year-old woman named Aminatou Haidar used the
hunger strike for similar effect. A native of the Western Sahara, which
has been occupied by Morocco since 1975, Haidar has ceaselessly
campaigned for the right of her people, the Sahrawi, to
self-determination.[150] For these efforts, she has been repeatedly
imprisoned and abused. Returning from the United States, where she had
been awarded various human rights prizes, Haidar was prevented by
Morocco from reentering the territory where she and her children live.
The Moroccans seized her passport and demanded she sign an oath of
allegiance to Moroccoâs king in order to get it back. Haidar refused and
went on a hunger strike to demand its return. As Haidar approached
death, international efforts on her behalf stepped up and even Moroccoâs
allies, France and the United States, were forced to intervene. After
thirty-two days without food, Haidar was taken to the hospital, her
respiration and blood pressure dangerously low. She remained, however,
committed to the end, determined, she said, to return unimpeded and
without conditions or to die in dignity. Morocco at last capitulated and
permitted her return, a public humiliation for a monarchy that had sworn
it would not back down. Thanks to her willingness to starve herself to
the end, Haidar not only secured her own return to her homeland, she
also succeeded in attracting unprecedented international attention to
Moroccoâs occupation of Africaâs âlast colony.â
Sometimes protest can take the simplest form. In East Timor, then
occupied by Indonesia, the indigenous East Timorese would approach every
Indonesian soldier or settler they came across and ask, âWhen are you
leaving my country?â[151] The most basic declaration of discontent,
repeated, sends a signal that the status quo cannot endure.
In the summer of 1964, about a thousand American students mainly from
northern collegesâmost of them whiteâtraveled to Mississippi as part of
a campaign by the Student Nonviolent Coordinating Committee (SNCC) to
fight against racial segregation in the southern states. The students
lived in communesââFreedom Housesââor with local black families. They
registered voters and taught in Freedom Schools. In one of the most
notorious crimes of the civil rights era, three recently arrived
students were beaten to death by segregationists assisted by the local
police, killings made famous in the movie Mississippi Burning. The
murders shocked the world. As with Claudette Colvin, who refused to
change seats on her bus, the studentsâ actions directly contributed to
the repeal of the notorious racist Jim Crow laws and the end of
legalized segregation in the South, a reminder that laws follow action,
not vice versa.
These dramatic actions were often taken to address grave injustices,
like occupation and systematic repression. The hunger strike is an
extreme action taken in response to extreme circumstances. Moreover, as
Gandhi and Haidar both illustrate, it helps that the striker already
enjoys some standing in public, and ideally, as in both cases, moral
authority.
Political actions which produce, even in small part, the political end
they seek carry a persuasive force far greater than any mere campaign,
both for their demonstrative and symbolic force, and for the simple
reason that such actions, even if only on small scale, contribute to the
desired solution.
For example, in New York Cityâs Bedford-Stuyvesant, after a spate of
robberies, a group of local men decided to escort pedestrians home from
the subway. One of the founders of âWe Make Us Betterâ said, âI decided
we canât have these people terrorizing our young women and children, and
weâre not speaking up and making our presence felt.â The members of the
group donât regard themselves as political or activist; they are just
trying to make their community better by their example.[152] They plan
soon to set up a mentoring program.
This illustrates an important messageâthat it is changing attitudes and
demonstrating new forms of behavior, as much as laws, that matters. This
lesson is also evident in Naples, the heartland of the Camorra organized
crime ring. Here, local people have taken the initiative to resist
extortion and corruption, some pasting âanti-pizzoâ stickers on their
shops to indicate that they do not pay âprotectionâ money, and as a
signal of solidarity with those who do the same. Others are establishing
cooperatives to run the farms and businesses seized by prosecutors from
the mafia.
In a country where several legislators and the prime minister are
accused of links to the mob, a judge made the same point, âThe battle is
not just won by force and sequestrations, but by a social struggle. It
is a cultural battle.â[153]
In Britain, Prime Minister David Cameron has made great play of a
concept he calls âThe Big Society,â offering a rather sketchy blend of a
vague localism with more familiar Conservative moral philosophy about
individual responsibility. At the same time that the government has made
severe cuts in public spending, Cameron has argued that people should
play a greater role in local activities, hitherto the preserve of
government, including schools, parks and other public services. The
conjunction of cuts with the moral sermonizing is not the only aspect of
the Big Society that jars. This book argues that people will benefit by
taking charge of their shared affairs locally, but crucially this means
that they must also have agency over these decisions: control. The
benefits outlined hereâof better and more equitable outcomes, and social
consensusâfrom local and participatory decision making are not available
in the Big Society because in Cameronâs vision, central government
retains overall control. If taxes and revenues are collected and
distributed centrally, it is impossible for people at the local level to
have real control over budgets and thus policy.
The Porto Alegre experiment described earlier is an example of what real
local agency looks like, and its benefits are clearâabove all in the
more equitable distribution of government services, but also in greater
social consensus underpinning policy choices. The Big Society, by
contrast, has yet to amount to real autonomy at the local level. Local
people may provide, but not decide. It is this contradiction that
perhaps explains Cameronâs inability to explain his concept with any
clarity, and suggests that it will amount to little more than
encouraging volunteers at the local library. For this half-baked
philosophy entirely misses the point of real devolution of power.
Indeed, it represents no such devolution in substantive terms at all.
All that it offers is responsibility without power.
In 1980, CEOs of the largest American companies earned an average of
forty-two times as much as the average worker; in 2001, they earned 531
times as much. It is hard to imagine that these bosses have in twenty
years increased their contribution to company performance by such a
remarkable degree. Instead, there appears to be an emerging culture
among the top executives that, because they can pay themselves so much,
they should. This self-interested belief piggybacks upon and exploits a
vague cultural notion that competitive economies somehow require
exceptional rewards for the successful. Thus capitalism takes on the
qualities not only of an economic system, but also a moral code.
There is nothing inevitable about such excesses, or inequality. Such
irresponsible greed is not necessary for a competitive company, nor
intrinsic to an efficient economy. Indeed, the opposite seems to be the
case. Some economists, including a former IMF chief economist, now
believe that Americaâs gross wealth inequality lay at the root of the
financial meltdown: Middle-class families, whose incomes have been
stagnant for a decade, were forced to borrow more and more to buy houses
and maintain acceptable living standards.[154] Meanwhile, the rich, who
enjoyed a far greater share of the rewards of Americaâs economic growth
over the last decade, spend far less as a proportion of their overall
income, depressing the consumption necessary to fuel sustained
growth.[155]
But what might be done?
John Lewis set up his first draperâs shop in 1864. His son Spedan joined
the business toward the end of the century. While convalescing from a
riding accident, he realized that his father, his brother and he
together earned more than all the hundreds of other employees in the
familyâs two stores put together. Spedan Lewis instigated new systems
and practices as soon as he returned to work: He offered shortened
working days, set up a staff committee, and a third weekâs paid holiday,
an innovation for retail trade at the time. He founded a house magazine,
The Gazette, which is still published today.
In 1920, Spedan introduced a profit-sharing scheme. Twenty years later,
it was expanded into a partnership: In effect, Lewis handed over the
business to its workers. Today, nearly seventy thousand partner
employees own the scores of major stores and supermarkets operated by
John Lewis across Britain. Every branch holds forums to discuss local
issues. These aggregate to form divisional councils; partners elect the
large majority of members of the Partnership Council. The councils have
the power to discuss âany issue whatsoeverâ; the partnership puts âthe
happiness of Partners at the centre of everything it does.â
The partnershipâs constitution sets out to be both commercial and
democratic. The annual bonus for partners in 2008 was equivalent to ten
weeksâ wages. The partners own two country estates, sailing clubs, golf
courses, hotels and other extensive recreational and social facilities.
Pension schemes are generous; after twenty-five yearsâ service partners
are rewarded with six monthsâ paid leave. With its well-known slogan of
âNever knowingly undersoldâ and a guarantee that it will repay customers
the difference if they can find a lower price elsewhere (though not
online), John Lewis has been consistently profitable, despite the
cutthroat competition of the retail sector. Its revenues in 2008 were
nearly ÂŁ7 billion.
Speaking in 1963, shortly before he died, Spedan Lewis explained why he
set up the partnership and handed over what had been the family business
to its employees.[156]
It was soon clear to me that my fatherâs success had been due to his
trying constantly to give very good value to people who wished to
exchange their money for his merchandise but it also became clear to me
that the business would have grown further and that my fatherâs life
would have been much happier if he had done the same for those who
wished to exchange their work for his money.
The profit⊠was equal to the whole of the pay of the staff, of whom
there were about three hundred. To his two children my father seemed to
have all that anyone could want. Yet for years he had been spending no
more than a small fraction of his income.
On the other hand, for very nearly all of his staff any saving worth
mentioning was impossible. They were getting hardly more than a bare
living. The pay-sheet was small even for those days.
Note that Lewis suggests that his father would have been happier himself
if he had paid his workers more fairly, an observation borne out in the
2009 book The Spirit Level, by Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett
(Penguin), which found that everyone in society is better offâin terms
of mental health, crime and other indicatorsâin economies with greater
wealth equality. Spedan Lewis continued that the state of affairs in the
country was a âperversion of capitalismâ:
It is all wrong to have millionaires before you have ceased to have
slums. Capitalism has done enormous good and suits human nature far too
well to be given up as long as human nature remains the same. But the
perversion has given us too unstable a society. Differences of reward
must be large enough to induce people to do their best but the present
differences are far too great. If we do not find some way of correcting
that perversion of capitalism, our society will break down. We shall
find ourselves back in some form of government without the consent of
the governed, some form of police state.
Cooperative businesses, such as John Lewis and Spainâs Mondragon, which
pays its executives no more than eight times its lowest paid employees,
have shown that businesses owned by their employees can be as successful
as the most hierarchical, profit-driven enterprise. At such companies,
wage differentials are lower, benefits are more widely shared and, above
all, employees who are also owners feel not only more agency over the
future of their business, and thus their own, but also more
satisfaction. These companies are not compelled to a more egalitarian
approach by legislation; they were set up that way by the free choice of
their founders.
Founded in 1884 by Karl Eisener, who wanted to provide long-term jobs to
discourage the Swiss from emigrating because of poor economic
conditions, the knife company Victorinox is going strong, with a
respected global brand nearly a hundred twenty years later.[157] Still,
it suffered a severe crisis when penknives were banned from airports,
hitherto important sales channels, under post-9/11 airport security
measures. The company responded by referring to its values of
inclusiveness and loyalty to its workers. Despite a steep decline in
sales, no one was laid off. The company instead stopped hiring,
encouraged workers to take early vacations and reduced shifts, while
expanding its product ranges, particularly in watches. The company had
suffered similar crises before, such as a sharp decrease in orders from
the Swiss army after the First World War.
Victorinox, in contrast to the prevailing hire-and-fire model, treats
its workers the same, in good times as well as bad. It acts according to
its pronounced values (means and ends again) by establishing
employee-oriented management schemes and an integration policy that
better incorporates younger and older workers, immigrants and people
with disabilities. It pays the highest paid workers no more than five
times the wages of the average.
In the financial sector, mutual banks and insurance companies endured
the depredations of the financial crisis much better than publicly owned
banks and companies. Mutuals, by their very nature, discourage excessive
risk-taking and indeed excessive pay. They return banks to the
old-fashioned notion that lending should not grossly outpace deposits.
The trouble is that stock-market listing encourages the emphasis on
short-term profitsâand thus risk-takingâthat contributed to such
problems in the credit crunch. The ensuing government bailout of the
banks reaffirmed the implicit guarantee that no major bank would be
allowed to fail and risk wider economic meltdown. Thus, the current
system, even after the much-heralded âbill to control Wall Streetâ in
2009, and thanks to government action, rewards the most destructive Wall
Street behavior.
Boston University professor Laurence Kotlikoff has proposed that all
financial products be mutualized as âlimited purpose bankingâ (LPB) with
benefits in reduced risk, greater transparency and less excessive
executive compensation. Under LPB, mortgage lending, for example, would
take place through âmortgage mutual fundsâ whose managers would pick
loans to invest in. Mortgage applicants would provide the information
they do today, and different funds could bid for their custom. The
lenders would be investors owning shares in the mutual funds. At no
point would any bank actually hold the mortgage on its books. Indeed,
banks would not hold anything on their books at all except the modest
assets needed to manage a fundâcomputers and officesâand the matching
equity. They would neither borrow nor trade with borrowed funds.
Kotlikoff extends this principle to all of finance, including insurance
and derivatives. His proposed system, crucially, would mean that all
contingent liabilities would be fully backed by capital.[158]
In defending the inequities and excesses of the current system, the
beneficiaries of these injustices tout half-baked economic arguments
remarkably oftenâsuch as the economic necessity of enormous executive
âcompensation.â In public debate, the merits of private enterprise are
invariably presented as superior to government provision. These
arguments come to a head over âpublic goodsâ such as the nationâs health
or the worldâs oceans, where the choice is usually presented as between
private ownership or public provision and regulation: market versus the
state. Evident in these debates is an assumption that there are only two
optionsâpublic or privateâto resolve the âtragedy of the commons,â
whereby common resources such as water, land or oceans will be abused by
some, and neglected by all, without some form of order.
In fact, pioneering economists have shown that other spontaneous forms
of voluntary management and sharing of such resources have sprung up and
are, if anything, more successful at husbanding these common goods than
either of the two conventional models. One such economist was awarded
the Nobel Prize for economics in 2009. Professor Elinor Ostromâs work
has shown that societies and groups regularly devise rules and
enforcement mechanisms that stop the degradation of nature. The
traditional theory holds that pollution and depletion of resources would
occur because individuals fail to recognizeâor do not care aboutâtheir
effect on others. However, her research has shown that people can manage
resources tolerably well without rules imposed by the authorities if
rules evolved over time, entitlements were clear, conflict resolution
measures were available and an individualâs duty to maintain the common
resource was in proportion to the benefits from exploiting it. Notably,
she found that the most important criterion for the success of such
schemes was this: active participation in setting and enforcing the
collective rules to manage the common good.[159]
The tortured debate over health care illustrates this problem. In the
U.S., a system dominated by massive private insurance companies has
created enormous and escalating costs for American business and many
other distortions and inequities, particularly for the poor, who have
been excluded from private insurance provision. Vast sums may be spent
to prolong the lives of the well-insured for merely a few days, while
many millions of the poor endure chronic or even fatal illness without
treatment. Ideologues from the right, but also the heavily lobbied
representatives of both Democrats and Republicans, successfully
destroyed the âpublic optionââthat government should provide
insuranceâin the 2009 health care bill. Needless to say, the enormous
health insurance industry spent over $600 million on lobbying in the two
years before the bill.
Meanwhile, in the UK, where public provisionâand universal coverageâof
health care is entrenched in the form of the National Health Service,
there is very appropriate concern, among both doctors and patients, at
the overweening and barely accountable bureaucracy seemingly necessary
to run the system, and the sometimes arbitrary choices it must make, for
instance, that certain drugs be denied to the sick because they are too
expensive.
In both countries, the fundamental truth of any health care system,
whether public or private, is barely acknowledgedâthat there must be
some system of rationing care. Otherwise, demand for health care is
insatiable; its costs would eventually consume the entire economy, as
the costs of Americaâs insurance-based system indeed threaten to do if
unchecked.
Arrangements to include both doctors and patients equally in the
provision of health care have worked in the past, and work today. In
earlier eras, cooperative or âfriendlyâ societies pooled the
contributions of working families to provide care when illness or death
struck. Today, health care cooperatives are able successfully to manage
and deploy their available resources according to what their members
(i.e., patients)âand not the insurance companies or bureaucratsâregard
as important. This possibility is barely mentioned in the U.S. debate,
presumably because cooperatives have no lobbyists. If it does arise, the
idea of cooperatives is often hysterically attacked by both the
insurance industry, which claims cooperatives are public provision in
disguise, or by advocates for the âpublic option,â who argue that
nonprofits cannot possibly compete with the massive cartels of the
insurance giants. Neither argument stands up to scrutiny, for
cooperatives would operate without taxpayer support, and by their
nonprofit nature would be less expensive than profit-maximizing private
insurance companies: The CEO of one of the largest U.S. health care
companies earns over $33 million.[160]
The company, the primary unit of economic activity, is not a fixed
entity; it can be, and is being, transformed. The distinction between
for-profit companies and not-for-profit charities is blurring as
companies incorporate social and environmental responsibilities into
their business model, not as addons but as intrinsic to the way that
they work. Chris Meyer of the Harvard Business Review has called this
âinternalizing the externalitiesâ of the traditional economic model of
the firm. While it is easy to be cynical about this development, and it
is right to criticize the âgreenwashingâ of otherwise unchanged
corporate practice, there is also here unarguably an opportunity.
Encouraged by an NGO, scores of companies are choosing to eschew high
carbon fuel sources, like oil sands.[161]
In another initiative, thousands of the worldâs largest companies are
voluntarily publishing data on their electricity consumption and carbon
emissions in a collective effort to reduce emissions, organized by
another small NGO, the Carbon Disclosure Project.[162] Utilizing the
power of peer and investor pressure rather than government regulation,
the project organizes letters to companies representing investors
holding $55 trillion, pressing them to participate and thus be
scrutinized on their environmental records. Other banks are ceasing to
lend to the mining companies that blast the tops off Appalachian
mountains in Virginia, not because this activity is illegalâit is
notâbut because of the growing damage to their reputations.[163]
Consumers through their own choices can reinforce these trends: âWhen
youâre buying, youâre voting,â as the founder of Stonyfield Farms, the
organic dairy producer, once exhorted. Every choice carries economic,
political and environmental effects. It will soon be easy to monitor the
labor and environmental records of manufacturers on the Web, and perhaps
at the point of purchase. At projectlabel.org and other sites, the
embryonic form of such indices is already visible.[164] The space is
available to rethink what companies do, to realize at last that their
impacts are inherently political, but also to embrace and exploit that
reality. Whether this transformation is positive or negative will be
determined by simple, small everyday choices: the actions of those who
compose these new commercial, social and in fact highly political
entities.
A French philosopher was once asked about the significance of May 1968,
the demonstrations and eruption of spontaneous public anger in France
and elsewhere.[165] He replied that the importance of May â68 was that
it was the opposite of what the Communists had said was the correct
manner of the revolution. The Communists had said that the revolution
should be:
Not here but somewhere else, like Cuba, Vietnam or elsewhere.
Not now but tomorrow, in the future.
And not you but the Communists instead, the appointed cadres.
Rejecting this injunction, the May â68ers had declared instead, âHere,
Now, Us!â
The next chapter suggests some core principles that might guide an
individual or group wanting to take up the flag on any issue. This is a
politics that offers the possibility of yet-unimagined outcomes, not
those defined by our current structures and ways of doing business.
This manifesto is rather short and simple. It does not proclaim a
particular end-state or utopia, but instead a series of methods for how
the individual might engage upon the issues that most concern them. The
methods themselves are the message: a way of doing things that promises
greater mutual concern, meaning and community of purpose.
The ends are indeed the means.
So much for all the theory, stories and ideas⊠what is to be done? Here
is a short list of principles that may guide action, along with a few
practical examples. The principles are by no means exclusive or
comprehensive: mere pointers, not instructions.
1. Locate your convictions.
This is perhaps the hardest step, and I have the least useful to say
about it (apart from Gandhiâs and Claudette Colvinâs examples, cited
earlier). This must be an individual discovery of what you care most
about. And this is the most fundamental point: Do not let others tell
you what to care about. This can only be a leaderless revolution, if it
is to succeed. Make up your own mind. Examine your own reactions. This
is difficult in the banality yet ubiquity of contemporary culture, with
its cacophony of voices and opinion. Space for contemplation is all too
rare. But hereâs one suggestion which is doubtless revealing of my own
dyspeptic disposition: What makes you angry? What never fails to
irritate you for its stupidity and injustice? That may be thing you
should take up arms against. It was for me, and anger puts fuel in the
tank.
2. Whoâs got the money, whoâs got the gun?
Before taking action, assess the landscape. This simple axiom will point
to the main sources of influence, and obstacles. Thanks to the Internet,
it is now possible to discover pretty rapidly who has a stake in any
given situation, and thus who might alter it. When revolt against the
dictatorial rule of Colonel Muammar Gadhafi broke out in Libya in
February 2011, information on which companies were doing business with
his regime was available in detail, triggering immediate pressure for
these companies and individuals to disengage. The same week that the
revolt broke out, several major oil companies announced their refusal to
do business with the regime, under pressure from their own investors
organized by a campaign group, the Genocide Intervention Network. The
Sunlight Foundation published a chart of the lobbyists, including former
congressmen, who were paid by Gadhafi to promote his interests. The
director of the London School of Economics was forced to resign just
days after the revolt began when it was revealed that his university had
received substantial funds from the regime to train its elites. One
welcome consequence of the vast mesh of connections that the globalized
world now comprises is that even distant situations may be affected by
actors close to home, who may be susceptible to pressure. Find them, use
it.
3. Act as if the means are the end.
In the summer of 1968, Soviet tanks entered Czechoslovakia, crushing the
âPrague springâ of growing political freedom. Massively outgunned by the
Soviet tank columns, the Czechoslovak army gave way. Demonstrators
attacked the tanks in city squares with stones and petrol bombs. The
Soviet troops responded with machine-gun fire. One protesting student
set himself on fire in Pragueâs Wenceslas Square. Thousands were
arrested, many to be imprisoned for long sentences. The leader who had
encouraged the liberalization, Alexander Dubek, was forced to
capitulate, under duress signing an agreement with Moscow to reverse the
reforms. Czechoslovakia endured more than another twenty years of
Communism before democracy at last dawned.
That summer of â68, thousands of Czechoslovak students had traveled
abroad to work. The invasion left them stranded. Among them was P., who
spent the summer picking fruit in Kent. The Soviet invasion gave him a
terrible choice: Should he stay in Britain, or return to Communist
dictatorship? Compounding his dilemma, he had nowhere to stay. A story
in The Times reported on the predicament of the stranded students: An
organization was quickly set up to find them shelter.
My parents read the story and decided to offer refuge to the
Czechoslovak student, P., who arrived shortly afterward. Though my
parents that summer were caring for three children under four (my
brother and I are twins, my sister only twenty-three months older), and
had more than enough on their plate, they gave P. a bed. He stayed for
several weeks while considering what to do. After much agonizing, he
eventually decided to stay in England. By chance, he had hitched a lift
from a professor at Warwick University. That professor liked P. and
offered him a place on his course. P.âs studies were duly arranged and
he completed his degree, frequently spending his holidays at our house
in South London. He went on to become an expert in fish storage. The
father of two children, he now lives in Scotland.
Thirty years later my parents gave refuge once more, this time to a
Zimbabwean escaping the repressive rule of Robert Mugabe. Now they were
living in a smaller flat, their children long having flown the nest. My
father recalled that it wasnât as simple as giving P. a room back in
1968. Asylum laws in Britain are now strictly enforced. My father was
required regularly to report to the local police station that Ngoni was
indeed staying with them and had not absconded. Finding study
opportunities and work was also harder, though not impossible.
(Universities and other such educational institutions are today
themselves required to check the legal status of their foreign students,
and report any noncompliance, thus, in effect, making them arms of the
state.)
I asked my parents why they had taken P. in. Neither could really
remember, answering my question with vague responses like âWe couldâ or
âIt felt like a good thing to do.â Now with my own small children, and
exhausted by the tasks of their care, I marvel at my parentsâ
hospitality.
Life is about means, not ends. There is no utopia to be gained, there is
no end-state that is static and eternal, once accomplished. This was one
of the great lies of Communism. Likewise, capitalism offers the great
deception that thanks to its machinations everyone will be richer in the
future, thus justifying gross inequality and humiliation today.
Instead itâs all here, and itâs all now. Nirvana tomorrow does not
justify avoidable suffering now. We and our world are in constant
motion, responding to each other without cease. This is one reason why
Francis Fukuyama was wrong to declare âThe End of Historyâ with the
triumph of liberal democracies after the collapse of communism. No fixed
state of affairs lasts forever.
4. Refer to the Cosmopolitan Criterion.
This is a pretentious way of saying give consideration to the needs of
others, but based upon what they say are their needs, not what we think
their needs are. The so-called Golden Rule states that you should do to
others as you would be done to. This rule is often lazily touted as a
universal rule applicable in all circumstances. This rule is in fact
dramatically wrong, for it assumes that we know what they want or need.
This logic, taken to its extreme, leads to the arrogant violence of the
neoconservatives, who believe that they have the right to use force in
the interests of those they are attacking, to kill people for their own
good. The invasion of Iraq was clearly motivated by this logic: that the
Iraqi people needed democracy, even at the cost of their own lives (we
know of course that the reason was not to combat an imminent
threat).[166] A hundred thousand people and perhaps more died as a
result. Instability was triggered that endures, with accompanying
violence, to this day. Needless to say, those advocating the war never
consulted those who would do the dying for their lofty goals, whether
allied soldiers or Iraqâs civilians.
There is instead a much simpler way to decide what to do and how to
calibrate your own action. Ask people what they want. They are usually
more than willing to tell you.
With the Internet, ubiquitous mobile phones and Facebook, it is no
longer credible to claim that we cannot find out what people âover
thereâ are thinking. During the Arab revolutions of early 2011,
pro-democracy protesters broadcast their tweets direct from Cairoâs
Tahrir Square, their compelling 140-character messages shattering
generations-old Western stereotypes of the Middle East and the âArab
street.â Websites like Global Voices now aggregate citizen reports from
all over the world, but from close to the ground. And those voices are
clear and fresh and urgent.
5. Address those suffering the most.
A few years ago, my wife and I traveled to northern Mali, to the
southern reaches of the Sahara desert north of Timbuktu. We were on our
honeymoon. We decided to take a camel tour with some Tuareg tribesmen;
the trip appealed to our sense of adventure. The camels carried us far
from Timbuktu into a romantic landscape of trackless desert wastes.
As night fell, we were brought to a Tuareg encampment. It turned out to
be the tented home of our guide, a young Tuareg man who wore loose robes
and a turban of deep blue cotton, wound around his head and neck to
protect him from the blasting rays of the sun. We slept under a vast and
magnificent canopy of stars, our baggage stacked around us as a
barricade against the camels, who had been known to tread upon sleeping
humans.
We awoke to a clear and silent dawn, and wandered to the tents to join
our guide and his family for breakfast. And here the romance began to
shatter. The guideâs young wife sat with her baby under a rough screen.
The previous evening, in the dark, their shelter had appeared as a
robust canvas tent. But it turned out to be a patchwork of plastic and
burlap sacks. The young woman and her baby were besieged incessantly by
large swarms of flies, which would land in waves upon her and her
sleeping babyâs face. The woman, clearly exhausted, perhaps by hunger or
illness we could not tell, listlessly swatted the flies away, but they
would settle nonetheless on the babyâs eyes and lips, in swarms so thick
they appeared as a blanket on the poor childâs face.
Shocked, my wife and I drank our tea and ate our bread in silence. The
guideâs father joined us. Talking to his son, he would with horrible
frequency emit an awful hacking cough. As he coughed, he doubled over in
pain, his throat broadcasting the most disgusting sounds of collecting
phlegm and blood, which he would periodically spit onto the sand by the
fire. He clearly had tuberculosis or some other serious respiratory
disease. He was desperately thin, and appeared enfeebled to the point of
death.
Conversing in broken French with the guide, we asked what was wrong. The
young man answered that he didnât know. The old man had never seen a
doctor. But, the guide said, he had some drugs. He spoke to the old man
who pulled out a half-used packet of paracetamol, its use-by date long
past. Perhaps, ventured the young man, we could give any drugs we might
have. Of course we obliged and ended up handing over perhaps a couple of
hundred dollars to the guide, in excessive payment for the trip. The old
man had noticed my spectacles and exclaimed in delight when I handed
them to him to try. I gave him these too (I had a spare pair).
We were appalled and upset by this encounter with desperate poverty. We
were glad to return from the camel trip. After leaving Mali (to be
honest, with some relief), however, we have not had any further contact
with the guide or his family. We give some money to charity on a regular
basis, but it is not in truth very much, and certainly not enough to
occasion us any significant limits on our own consumption.
How should one respond to suffering? Consider two contrasting answers to
this question. In a recent book, the philosopher Peter Singer uses an
example to illustrate our obligation to others, including those far away
who may be unknown to us.[167] A small girl is drowning in a lake in
front of you and you are the only person who can rescue the child. You
are, however, wearing $400 shoes which will be ruined if you dive in to
rescue the girl. Singer believes, of course, that the answer to such a
dilemma is clear and accepted by almost everyone: You must dive in to
save the child, but ruin the shoes.
Singer argues that in reality the crisis of the drowning child is
presented to us constantly. Every minute, eighteen children die of
hunger and preventable disease: twenty-seven thousand every day. It
costs, moreover, far less than $400 to save them. Just as if the child
were drowning directly in front of us, the moral imperative is clear and
precise: We must act, even if there is a cost to ourselves, albeit a
small one. Using calculations by economist Jeffrey Sachs and others,
Singer suggests that if everyone in the rich world gave a mere 1 percent
of their income, poverty and preventable disease in the world could be
effectively eradicated. Singer has set up a website where individuals
can make such pledges.[168] Singer reportedly donates 25 percent of his
own income to charity.
At the other end of the moral spectrum, nineteenth-century German
ĂŒber-anarchist Max Stirner believed that the idea of morality is
basically absurd and manufactured by those who cloak their selfish
purposes in pseudo-universal principles which have no other origin.
There is no such thing as society (as Margaret Thatcher too once
famously observed). It is instead the individual and their own desires
which matter. Thus, the individual is required to do nothing but follow
their own wishes to the fullest, wherever this may lead. To do anything
else is to act falsely and to invite falseness from others in response,
thus risking an orderâor rather disorderâbased on dishonest and
manufactured ideas.
Stirnerâs ideas imply that we have no obligation to dive in to save the
child in Singerâs thought experiment. Almost everyone would find this
appalling. Yet, as Singer has observed, this is what we consistently do.
Very few individuals give even 1 percent of their income to those worse
off than they. Several thousand people have made such pledges at
Singerâs website, but of course this is but a tiny drop in the bucket.
Most rich governments have failed to fulfill their own oft-repeated
pledges to commit 0.7 percent of their GDP to development aid. The funds
required to meet the UNâs Millennium Development Goals, established in
2000 as achievable targets to reduce poverty and disease, have not been
provided, including by the G8, G20 and UN General Assembly, which have
on repeated occasions, promised all efforts to do so.
So whatâs the flaw with Singerâs reasoning? Why are we unconvinced to
help the distant poor? Are we inherently selfish, more Max Stirner than
Peter Singer? It is easy for a moralist to say that the needs of a
Somali woman dying in childbirth should be as compelling to us as if she
were our sister. But, as Singer has disappointingly discovered, such
reasoning has little lasting impact.
If a child drowns before us, how tiny would be the minority who refused
to act because they didnât want to get their expensive shoes wet, and
what would the majority do to that person once they found out? Somehow
we need to find a way to stimulate the emotional connection that evokes
compassion, an emotion that, unlike moral rules, seems shared among
humanity (with some sociopathic exceptions). How is compassion between
people generated? One clear and straightforward answer presents itself:
the encounter.
Missing in the reasoning of Singer is any sense of what Stirner, by
contrast, believed necessary, intrinsic and inevitableâengagement.
Stirner firmly rejected any a priori assumption of what such engagement
might produce, least of all that it should result in an obligation to
render help to others. But it makes sense that engagement produces a
different kind of reaction, and a different conversation, than mere
knowledge. It is clearly not enough to know that people âout thereâ are
suffering. But locate oneself next to that suffering, as my wife and I
found in the Malian desert, and the reaction becomes entirely different,
even though the facts and our knowledge of them remain exactly the same.
Thus nineteenth-century Stirner may paradoxically provide a truer guide
to action in the connected twenty-first century than contemporary
philosophers who, with great humanity, urge that we accept the
obligation to rescue the drowning child. For it is engagementâor rather
its absenceâthat may precisely explain why the Singers, and the
proponents of the UN Millennium Development Goals, or the 0.7 percent
goal, or the Bonos or Angelinas have failed to convince those who have
so much to hand over even a little bit, and make a huge life-saving
difference, to the billions who have so desperately little.
And from this, one conclusion stands out: States, borders and indeed
institutions in general must by their very nature limit our engagement
with one another; they channel, frame, render detached and sometimes
obstruct the vast mĂȘlĂ©e of human interaction. And by limiting that
engagement, somewhere along the way our compassion is eviscerated. The
requirement for engagement, as demanded too by the cosmopolitan
criterion (above), is reinforced.
The twenty-first century offers engagement at levels unprecedented in
human history. As Kwame Anthony Appiah observes in his elegant study
Cosmopolitanism: Ethics in a World of Strangers, a stroller along New
Yorkâs Fifth Avenue will pass more nationalities in half an hour than an
ancient Roman would have met in a lifetime. The multihued society of
America, Britain, Europe and more or less everywhere, increasingly,
offers commensurately varied chances for encounters with the hitherto
distant Other, be they Somali, Kyrgyz, Malay or Tongan. âAbroadâ is more
and more located right here. At least four hundred million people now
live in countries not of their birth. And these are just the first
generation immigrants; add a second and third generation, and the
proportion grows much higher. Over two million of Londonâs seven and a
half million inhabitants were born overseas. Heterogeneity will become
routine. Whether we like it or not, we will have to engage.
The sharp and unprecedented increases in immigration in almost all
developed countries, driving commensurate increases in ethnic diversity,
have triggered anguished debates in Europe and the U.S. In Switzerland,
a popular referendum affirmed a ban on mosque construction, though there
are very few mosques already. In the Netherlands, the 2010 general
election saw a significant swing to the far right anti-immigration party
of Gert Wilders. In the U.S., Arizona enacted a law allowing police to
stop anyone merely on suspicion of being an illegal immigrant.
And at first sight, it appears that fears of the effect of an influx of
outsiders on established stable societies are well placed. Harvard
sociologist Robert Putnam has found that the more mixed a society, the
lower its indices of âsocial capitalââtrust, altruism, associations,
active cooperationâand the higher its indices of social
fragmentationâcrime, for instance.[169] But crucially, he found that
these reductions in social solidarity and âsocial capitalâ were
short-term effects. At first, it appears, local societies âhunker downâ;
trust declines, even within members of the same race or ethnic group.
People retreat into privacy.
In the longer run, however, the outcomes are more positive. New forms of
association and social solidarity emerge. In more hybrid societies,
there is more creativityâas measured, for instance, by the number of
Nobel Prizes. Immigration is associated with more rapid economic growth,
although short-term effects should not be overlooked, particularly on
the lowest paid who tend to feel first the effects of more intensified
competition for jobs from immigrants.
The evidence suggests that immigration from the global south to the
global north greatly enhances development in the south, partly because
of the flow of remittances from new immigrants to their families âback
home,â but also because of the transfer of technology and new ideas
through immigrant networks. This effect is reportedly so powerful that
it may offset the âbrain drainâ costs to the southern countries sending
the migrants. Putnam cites evidence of yet greater positive effect,
including a World Bank study that estimates that increasing annual
northward immigration by only 3 percentage points might produce net
benefits greater than meeting all national (U.S.) targets for
development assistance plus canceling all Third World debt plus
abolishing all barriers to Third World trade.
A further reason to address those suffering the most is simply this:
Here, you can make the most difference.
6. Consult and negotiate.
When I was responsible for sanctions policy on Iraq at the UK Mission to
the United Nations, we were often approached by campaigning NGOs who
wanted us to alter our policies, and lift or amend sanctions in order to
end the humanitarian suffering in Iraq. They were right, of course, but
that didnât mean that they were effective.
In general, I avoided meeting these campaigners, well aware that I would
be subjected to a rhetorical finger-wagging session. It was difficult
for campaigners to find out who was dealing with Iraq in our mission,
and we didnât make it easy for them (itâs still very difficult, even
though now the mission has the inevitable official website, as opaque as
the smoked glass at the missionâs entrance). Only rarely did the
campaigners manage to identify me, and persuade me to meet them.
Such meetings were tedious and predictable. Invariably, the campaigners
would march into my office, then lecture me about the immorality of what
my government was doing, demanding changeâbut rarely specifying in any
detail what that change should be: just change! Discussion would be
tense and confrontational; the meetings would end with much relief, for
me at least. I sensed too that the objective for the campaigners was
often the fact of the meeting, which they could now parade as effective
action on their part, the meeting alone amounting to a victory. Of
course, it was not.
No doubt such lobbying made them feel better. But the effect on me was
to make me more determined to avoid such future encounters. Thanks to
the superficiality of the campaignersâ arguments, I was able easily to
dismiss them. They forgot that I worked on Iraq full-time every day, and
was steeped in the arguments and data to justify and defend our
policies.
Two academics from Notre Dame University in Indiana used a different
approach. They approached the individual officials involved in the
British and U.S. governments, asking to collect information about our
policies. They were polite and patient. They came to meet me several
times. After several meetings, they offered a detailed set of proposals
to change our policy, ideas that addressed our concerns to limit Iraqâs
potential to rearm while minimizing the potential negative humanitarian
effects of sanctions. The U.S. State Department held a discussion
meeting with many officials concerned to meet the academics and hear
their proposals. Eventually, their ideas were adopted as
BritishâAmerican policy and led to a major amendment of sanctions
policy, which was put into place in 2002.[170]
It was too late, and such a policy should have been enacted from the
beginning of comprehensive sanctions on Iraq in 1990. But the point is
clear.
Negotiation should ideally be direct, not through intermediaries. When
my wife and I bought our apartment in New York City, we were represented
in the negotiations by our real estate agent and eventually by a lawyer.
The negotiations quickly deteriorated. Every move by the seller was
scrutinized for deviousness, every motive and communication was
immediately placed under suspicion. When the seller sought to delay the
sale after we had agreed a price, this was seized upon as a sign of âbad
faith.â Lawyers reported antagonistic exchanges. As stalemate beckoned,
we proposed a meeting with the sellers. Tense and anticipating a
conflict, we arrived at the apartment, to findâneedless to sayâa
perfectly affable couple who merely wanted to stay in the apartment for
a few weeks before their new home was ready. For them the alternative
was taking their small children to live in a hotel.
7. âBig picture, small deeds.â
The innovation company ?What If! offers this maxim as a way to overcome
the inertia that too often stymies change. ?What If! trains employees in
how to be innovative but found that sometimes, though inspired by their
training away-day, their trainees would still fail to implement the
techniques they had learned. It was simply too overwhelming to change
the prevailing culture of their everyday workplace. To counter this
problem, ?What If! proposed a simple philosophy: Keep in mind the
overall change you wish to achieve, but act a little every day to make
it reality.
Though transposed to the corporate world, this technique echoes the
âsmall stepsâ proposed by Mahatma Gandhi to achieve profound and
enduring change. There is an ancient Chinese proverb to the same effect
(the Internet tells me): âIt is better to take many small steps in the
right direction than a great leap forward then stumble backward,â sage
advice that Mao Zedong clearly ignored in forcing Chinaâs Great Leap
Forward in the 1960s that forced peasants from their land and led to the
starvation and death of perhaps more than thirty million. Perhaps
recognizing this catastrophe, Maoâs successor Deng Xiaoping proposed a
more pragmatic method of change: âcrossing the river by feeling the
stones.â
This metaphor is both more compelling and offers a more pragmatic
approach: Stones are palpable, material, solid. The steps of any
strategy should be concrete; not rhetorical but practical. Internet
campaigns clearly fail this criterion; volunteering at a local school
does not. Mahatma Gandhi distilled the epic struggle against British
colonial rule into a simple but practical act that anyone could
undertake: making salt.
And the goal must be epic. The spirit soars at the momentous challenge,
not the banal. Break that challenge down into small, practical, daily
tasks, and get to work. Though the steps toward it may be humble, find a
goal that is great: End poverty, prevent war, save the planet. Locate
your objective, grasp your flag, then march deliberately toward the
enemy. If you do so with courage and conviction, others will surely
follow.
8. Use nonviolence.
Alexander Berkman was an anarchist who passionately detested the
widespread exploitation and abuse of workers in industrial America of
the late nineteenth century. An immigrant from Russia, he was influenced
by anarchist thinkers and groups in New York City, where he became a
close friend of the famous anarchist Emma Goldman. As told by Goldman in
her autobiography, My Life, and Berkman in his Prison Memoirs of an
Anarchist, both were deeply affected by the Haymarket affairâor
massacre, as it is sometimes known: the name of the event an indicator,
as it often is, of the prejudices of the namer.
On May 4, 1886, at Haymarket Square in Chicago, at a rally in support of
striking workers, an unknown person threw a bomb at police as they
dispersed the gathering. The bomb blast and ensuing gunfire resulted in
the deaths of eight police officers and an unknown number of civilians.
In the trial that followed, eight anarchists were tried for murder
despite paltry evidence against them. Four were put to death, and one
committed suicide in prison. The judge declared, âNot because you have
caused the Haymarket bomb, but because you are Anarchists, you are on
trial.â To this day, debate continues about the true identity of the
bomber.
It is clear from both Goldmanâs and Berkmanâs memoirs that they were
radicalized by what they saw as a profound injustice. Both came to
believe that only dramatic, and if necessary violent, actsâthe
attentatâwould galvanize the working population to rise up against a
deeply unjust system. The opportunity for such an act was soon to
present itself.
In June 1892, workers at a steel plant in Homestead, Pennsylvania, were
locked out after pay negotiations failed between the Carnegie Steel
Company and the Amalgamated Association of Iron and Steel Workers. The
result was one of the first organized strikes in American labor history.
Andrew Carnegie had placed his factories, and indeed later his
industrial empire, under the control of Henry Clay Frick. Carnegie
publicly supported the rights of workers to join unions and employ
collective bargaining. Privately, however, he encouraged Frick to break
the strike, and with it, the union.
Frick locked the union workers out and placed barbed-wire fences,
searchlights and watchtowers around the factory. He hired nonunion
workers to take the strikersâ jobs and get the factory going again, but
they were unable to break through the unionâs picket lines. So Frick
hired three hundred armed guards from the Pinkerton Detective Agency to
break the picket lines. When the Pinkerton guards arrived at the factory
on the morning of July 6, a gunfight broke out. Nine union workers and
seven guards were killed during the fight, which lasted twelve hours.
There was widespread outrage at Frickâs actions and the violent attack
of the âPinkertons.â Berkman and Goldman decided to assassinate Frick.
This was the opportunity for the violent attentat to rouse the working
class to revolt. There was no viler capitalist than Frick: For a while,
he was known as âAmericaâs most hated man.â In his memoir, Berkman
recounts his romantic fascination with the extreme act:
Could anything be nobler than to die for a grand, a sublime Cause? Why,
the very life of a true revolutionist has no other purpose, no
significance whatever, save to sacrifice it on the altar of the beloved
People.
Berkmanâs execution of the plan, however, was amateurish. His plan was
to assassinate Frick and commit suicide afterward; Goldmanâs role was to
explain Berkmanâs motives after his death. First, Berkman tried to make
a bomb, but he failed. Berkman and Goldman then pooled their meager
savings to buy a handgun and a suit for Berkman to wear for the
assassination attempt.
On July 23, 1892, Berkman entered Frickâs office armed with a gun and a
sharpened steel file. Frick dived under a chair and began to yell.
Berkman shot Frick three times, then grappled with him and stabbed him
in the leg. Others in the office came to Frickâs rescue and beat Berkman
unconscious. He was convicted of attempted murder and given a
twenty-two-year prison sentence. Frick survived the attack.
As he later related in his memoir, Berkman encountered a Homestead
striker soon after his imprisonment. Berkman immediately romanticizes
the man as the embodiment of the workersâ struggle. He is enthralled to
meet an actual striker, a true-blooded member of the working classes.
Here at last Berkman would find his vindication. But the meeting
produces nothing but bitter disappointment. The striker decries
Berkmanâs assassination attempt. âWe are law-abiding people,â he says,
adding that the workers donât want anything to do with the âanachrists,â
as he misnames them.
Other workers on whose behalf Berkman made the attentat were not
impressed either. There was no worker uprising as a result of Berkmanâs
effort; his attack was widely condemned, including by unions, workers
and even other anarchists. Negative publicity from the attempted
assassination resulted in the collapse of the Homestead strike.
Twenty-five hundred men lost their jobs, and most of the workers who
stayed had their wages halved.
If not violence, then what? All too often, the debate is framed as
violence or nothing; pacifism as mere inactivity. As the world
contemplated how to respond to Colonel Gadhafiâs brutal repression of
unrest in Libya, media commentators dwelt on the debate over the
imposition of no-fly zones or other forms of military intervention,
ignoring the many various nonmilitary but nonetheless coercive measures
available: These were complicated, and thus ill-suited to the Punch and
Judy requirements of sound-bite debate.[171] The whole framing of such
debates suggests that violence is strong, the absence of violence weak.
Pacifism is invariably portrayed as a kind of âdo nothingâ philosophy.
Nonviolence resolves this problem. Nonviolent methods are not doing
nothing. Instead, they are forceful methods that can be highly effective
but avoid injury and bloodshed, while gaining moral authority from the
rejection of violence.
To get down to specifics, nonviolent action can take many different
forms. In his essential and concise essay âFrom Dictatorship to
Democracy,â Gene Sharp lists no fewer than 198 different nonviolent
methods, but here are three:[172]
BoycottâThe word âboycottâ entered the English language thanks to
Captain Charles Boycott, the land agent of an absentee landlord in
Ireland. In 1880, harvests had been poor, so the landlord offered his
tenants a 10 percent reduction in their rents. The tenants demanded a 25
percent reduction, but were refused. Boycott then attempted to evict
eleven tenants from the land. The Irish nationalist Charles Stewart
Parnell proposed that ostracism was more powerful than violence: Greedy
landlords and land agents like Boycott should be made pariahs. Despite
the short-term economic hardship they incurred, Boycottâs workers
stopped work in the fields and stables, as well as in his house. Local
businessmen stopped trading with him, and the local postman refused to
deliver mail. Boycott soon found himself isolated and unable to hire
anyone to harvest the crops. Eventually, fifty outsiders volunteered to
do the work, but they had to be escorted by a thousand policemen and
soldiers, despite the fact that local leaders had said that there would
be no violence, and none in fact materialized. This protection ended up
costing far more than the harvest was worth. After the harvest, the
âboycottâ was successfully continued.
Gandhi organized a boycott of British goods. In Montgomery, Alabama,
African-Americans boycotted segregated buses. The National Negro
Convention boycotted slave-produced goods in 1830. Today boycotts are
even easier to organize, thanks to the Internet. The Dutch bank ING was
forced to cancel bonuses for its senior staff after thousands of its
customers threatened to withdraw their deposits, and thus risk a run on
the bank. A Facebook and Twitter boycott campaign erupted after news
emerged that the chief executive was to be awarded a ÂŁ1 million bonus
despite the bank having received âŹ10 billion in state aid to keep
afloat, had frozen pensions and given staff only a 1 percent pay rise.
Dutch politicians later voted for a 100 percent retrospective tax on all
bonuses paid to executives at institutions that had received state aid
as a result of the financial crisis.[173]
IsolateâThe withdrawal of social approval for individuals is distressing
to those subjected to it. Public shaming is an underutilized tool. To
politicians and public figures who bask in public attention, its denial
can be painful indeed.
In New York City, a group of women were fed up with the harassment they
routinely faced on public subways or the street, ranging from unwelcome
sexual comments to groping and stalking. Frustrated with cultural
attitudes that suggested such abuse was an inevitable price of being a
woman, they founded a group to fight back, called âI holla backâ
(www.ihollaback.org). Emily May founded Hollaback with friends five
years ago. Today it has chapters in six American cities, along with
others in Britain, Canada and Australia. The group has recently
developed an iPhone application to allow women immediately to log and
report such incidents, and, if possible, photograph the perpetrators.
The aim is to produce a comprehensive pictureâand identify âhotspotsââof
such harassment, citywide and even nationwide. Reports will be forwarded
to police for action, including particular zones of repeated activity.
But there are obvious obstacles for the police to press convictionsâthey
cannot solve the problem alone. By identifying and exhibiting the
photographs of perpetrators, the group also hopes to shame the men who
carry out the abuse, and create new cultural attitudes to replace the
old: to render harassment socially unacceptable.[174]
In a more international context, a white farmer in newly independent
Zimbabwe once told me that the economic and political isolation of white
minority-dominated Rhodesia may not have undermined the economy
sufficiently to force the Rhodesian government to give up its apartheid
practices. We could survive economically, she told me, but once we were
under international sanctions, she said, we knew one thing with
certaintyâthat white minority rule could not last forever.
SabotageâThis method is to be used only in the most extreme
circumstances of gross injustice and repression, when other nonviolent
methods have failed. A recent illustration of the inherent risks and
ambiguous consequences of sabotage, even of the nonviolent kind, is the
story of the Stuxnet computer worm, which appears to have been
deliberately designed to interfere with Iranâs nuclear program. The worm
was highly sophisticated, suggesting that states (perhaps the United
States) were behind its creation. Concealing itself in the operating
system of computers that control industrial mechanisms, Stuxnet
reportedly works by speeding up the gas centrifuges used to enrich
uranium so that the centrifuges are damaged or destroyed. All the while,
the control systems continue to indicate that everything is normal. The
effects of Stuxnet are not clear, and Iran has admitted to only limited
damage from the virus. Illustrating the dangers of using such
techniques, however, there is now debate that the way has been cleared
for others to use similar devicesâwhich are effectively sabotage, albeit
by the most modern methods. In effect, a new front has been opened in
conflict, with few rules to govern it. As one journalist put it: âWe
have crossed a threshold and there is no turning back.â[175] There are
now belated calls for new international agreements to prohibit such
cyberwarfare, while others comment that enforcement of such rules would
in any case be all but impossible, given the intrinsic anonymity and
complexity of the Web. If you are going to use these tools, it would be
wise to be sure that they cannot then be turned against you. Hence the
requirement to use nonviolent sabotage only in extremis.
But for all the drawbacks of sabotage, it has one signal and perhaps
overriding virtue: It doesnât kill people.
In Wim Wendersâs film Wings of Desire, an old man is in a library
contemplating wartime photographs of dead children. He is very elderly
and perhaps dying. He thinks to himself, âMy heroes are no longer
warriors and kings, but the things of peaceâŠ. But so far no one has
succeeded in singing an epic of peace. What is it about peace that its
inspiration is not enduring? Why is its story so hard to tell?â
9. Kill the King!
Chess may be useless as a metaphor for international relations but it
carries one very important lesson. The only point of the game is to take
the opponentâs king. All other moves, and elegant plays with bishop or
pawns, are but preliminary to this object. Do not be satisfied with
process, but only with results. A campaign to end genocide, richly
adorned with expensive video and glamorous celebrities, is worth nothing
if it doesnât save a single life. Donât campaign for others to perform
the action required to achieve change: Do it yourself. Sending a text
message or signing an Internet petition is likely to achieve nothing,
given that so little went into it.
The measure of any political action is not how many hits you get on the
campaign website, how many followers you may have on Twitter, or
supporters on your Facebook page. The measure is effects in the real
world on the thing you are trying to change: Are there fewer nuclear
weapons, has the dictator been overthrown, is one child saved from
starvation?
Alexander the Great always aimed his forces at his enemyâs strongest
point. When that fell, the enemy collapsed. Kill the King!
Individually, these principles are unexceptionable. Who can object to
nonviolent, step-by-step action, negotiated with those affected, and
designed to address those most suffering? But taken together, these
principles in fact amount to a radically different form of political
action from the contemporary cultural model, which seems by contrast to
amount to very little: Vote for the government, maybe campaign a little
to ask others to do things you want, and, if youâre directly concerned,
perhaps lobby government. The principles suggested above offer a rather
more vigorous, directed but above all effective, even transformative,
course of action. This is perhaps why there is such establishment
hostility to these methods, and indeed to the word âanarchism,â
including the very peaceful and collaborative form proposed here: The
employment of these methods will actually change things, including by
changing the way that things change. Those who benefit from the current
status quo donât want you to know that.
One person following these principles will not cause a global
revolution, though it may revolutionize their own lives. But the action
of one may stimulate others. And if many adopt these principles, a
revolution, a leaderless revolution, will eventually become manifest.
In Tolstoyâs War and Peace, some of the greatest scenes are those
depicting the battles of the Franco-Russian wars. Cannonballs from
Napoleonâs artillery whizz overhead, cavalry horses rear and flare at
fusillades of musket fire, men quiver with fear and red flows their
blood.
In one scene during the Battle of Austerlitz, the Russian troops are
taken by surprise by advancing French columns that suddenly emerge from
the engulfing fog. As the French fire scatters them, the Russian front
collapses and men flee in disarray. Weeping with anger and shame as he
contemplates imminent defeat, Prince Andrew picks up a standard that a
retreating officer has let fall. Heedless of the danger and the bullets
cracking all around him, he gives a cry âpiercing as a childâsâ and runs
forward.[176]
His singular action is enough to rally the disordered infantrymen around
him. Suddenly, one soldier moves, and then another, and soon the whole
battalion runs forward shouting âHurrah!â and overtakes him. Surrounded
by charging troops, Prince Andrew runs forward, now just twenty paces
from the French guns, so close that he sees the fear and anger on the
gunnersâ faces. Prince Andrew is struck down; others seize the flag to
maintain the advance.
The battle is, however, lost. Later, Prince Andrew, now captured, lies
gravely wounded in a French dressing station. Napoleon visits the
injured Russians. Close to death, Prince Andrew is unmoved by the sight
of his erstwhile hero. Looking into Napoleonâs eyes, âPrince Andrew
thought of the insignificance of greatness, the unimportance of life
which no one could understand, and the still greater unimportance of
death, the meaning of which no one alive could understand or explain.â
Tolstoyâs battle scenes are of the microcosmic actions upon which pivots
victory or defeat. These actions are not the function of the decisions
of generals or emperors; they are the contingent decisions of individual
officers and soldiers, like the courageous if ultimately futile charge
of Prince Andrew. In an earlier chapter, the Battle of Schöngrabern is
turned by the decision of one man, TimĂłkhin, to charge the French lines,
armed only with a sword. Such actions, almost random in appearance, are
for Tolstoy what matters, not grand strategy or great men.
In his seminal essay âThe Hedgehog and the Fox,â Isaiah Berlin analyzed
Tolstoyâs view of history. War and Peace, according to Berlin,
illustrates Tolstoyâs skepticism of an account that suggested that
events were under the control of leaders, states or governments. Such
history, Tolstoy believed, accounted for not more than 0.001 percent of
human affairs; it was, moreover, basically false. At Austerlitz, the
Russian czar and his generals are described standing on a hilltop
observing their troops descend into the thick fog enveloping the valley
beneath them. It is a figurative illustration of their true knowledge,
Tolstoy suggests. The chief Russian general, KutĂșzov, enjoys heroic
stature in Russian history, but Tolstoy portrays him groaning helplessly
as his troops are attacked by surprise. Only Prince Andrew is decisive
in response to the emerging catastrophe, and his response is not to
issue orders but to seize the fallen flag and advance.
In Tolstoyâs descriptions, real life was far too complex and contingent
to be controlled by those at the summit of the pyramid. In fact, they
could not be expected to understand it at all, because they were not
part of it or close enough to witness it. Those who claimed such
understanding were either naive or were claiming knowledge for some
other purposeâto wield power, for instance. In fact, as War and Peace
shows, it is those at the base of the pyramid who make history, even if
they do not know it.
This chimes with our own intuition. Battles are as life: the strange and
inconstant mix of circumstance, random events and our own volition. Each
is crucial; none is separable. The abstraction from this mix into a
linear, polished narrative is inherently false. Equally false is any
claim that human action is driven by a singular motive, such as the
requirement to âmaximize utility,â as some economists would claim. Under
scrutiny, any event, however great or small, is revealed as a fantastic
and hugely complex mix of influence and causation, some inconsequential,
some crucial. There is no base, no bottom to these causes and effects,
all are contingent upon others.
Tolstoyâs hostility was directed against those who pretended that
history was of great men and their decisions, a depiction he believed
fundamentally inaccurate and dishonest. But it is not only historians
who must reduce. Governments too are required to aggregate the worldâs
incredible complexity into simple truths, to take the billions of
actions and wishes of their populations and claim that they can be
aggregated. This adduces no malign purpose to governments; they have no
alternative but to reduce in this way. They are required to do so in
order to claim that they understand, in order that they can produce
policies and decisions that offer to arbitrate the complexity.
âThe Hedgehog and the Foxâ is celebrated as a superb analysis of
Tolstoyâs writing and historical views. Oddly, however, Berlin does not
explore how Tolstoyâs writing, and the view of history intrinsic in it,
informed the writerâs politics, instead concentrating on the more
mystical aspects of Tolstoyâs thought. For Tolstoy believed that all
authority impeded the power of independent action by individualsâand
that only the individual had any authentic understanding of their
circumstance and how to change it. Tolstoy was an anarchist.
Tolstoy believed that it was those at the base of the pyramidâthe foot
soldiers on the battlefields of Borodino or Austerlitzâwho in fact made
history. The âgreat menâ and generals who claimed to understand it had
not a clue. For Tolstoy, it was ironic that historians looked to the
generals and leaders for the decisions that determined history, rather
than the infantry. More ironic still was that the infantrymen did so
too.
The dominating thought-systems of the twentieth century hold only
fragmentary clues to the necessary remedies today. Communism offered a
spurious equality at the sacrifice of individual liberty. Capitalism
offers liberty at the expense of social justice, harmony and that
essential sense of individual or shared meaning.
But both left and right do, however, offer hints of a new and stronger
philosophy. The greatest strength of the right has been its appeal to
individual enterprise and self-expression, freed of the deadening burden
of government. That of the left is its recognition that we are not
separated from one another, that community embraces and succors all,
opposing injustice, inequality and a merely selfish and ultimately
divisive individualism. We are all better off together.
But both the economic theory underlying capitalism and communist
orthodoxy offer a very limited and ultimately negative view of the
human. In neoclassical economic theory, it is claimed without evidence
that people are basically self-seeking, that they want above all the
satisfaction of their material desires. The ultimate objective of
mankind is economic growth, and that is maximized only through raw, and
lightly regulated, competition. If the rewards of this system are spread
unevenly, that is a necessary price. Others on the planet are to be
regarded as either customers, competitors or factors of production.
Effects upon the planet itself are mere âexternalitiesâ to the model,
with no reckoning of the costâat least for now. Nowhere in this analysis
appear factors such as human cooperation, love, trust, compassion or
hatred, curiosity or beauty. Nowhere appears the concept of meaning.
What cannot be measured is ignored. But the trouble is that once our
basic needs for shelter and food have been met, such factors may be the
most important of all.
In Marxist theory, the proletariat should eventually be freed of all
burdens, including of government. But in practice, all communist systems
rapidly established and maintained huge bureaucracies, with their
privileged elites, to instruct the people on their best interests. Never
were they to be asked what these might be. Those who offered a
dissenting voice were repressed, often with great cruelty. In
suppressing the anarchists of the Spanish republic, or the Bolsheviks of
the Kronstadt rebellion in 1921, the Communists showed their true
colors. Communism could never mean freedom from authority. That
revolution would never be permitted. The people were not to be trusted.
The methods discussed here instead imply a different view of mankind.
That people can be trusted successfully to manage their own affairs, to
negotiate with one another, to regulate their own societies from the
bottom upâby moral rules, rather than coercion and punishment. That
there is more available than the ugliness, conflict and emptiness of
contemporary society. Cynics will argue that such trust is misplaced,
and that conflict is inevitable. But the evidence from the few occasions
when people have been given true agency over their affairs suggests
rather the opposite: respect, consensus, or at worst an acceptance of
difference. If all authority disappeared today, our current condition of
mistrust and fear would guarantee the âwar of all against all.â But the
practices offered here would, with time, build trust anew. It even may
be built into something never experienced before, something
extraordinary and beautifulâa new society, governed by itself.
The preparation of this book has concluded just as something
extraordinary has begun. In the Middle East, mass protests have driven
dictators from power in Tunisia and Egypt. In Libya, an uprising, with
outside military support, has deposed the repressive Gadhafi regime. And
in America and Europe, mass popular protest has broken out against the
injustice of the current political and economic system. The Occupy Wall
Street movement may currently comprise only a few thousand people, but
it seems to represent a much wider disillusionment and anger with the
status quo. As I write these words, the protests have spread across the
United States and Western Europe.
There is a whiff of revolution in the airâand not only in the Middle
East. We have perhaps arrived at one of those moments of history where
fundamental change becomes possible, as people awaken to the profound
injustices, but also incapability, of the current dispensation. In an
echo of Thomas Kuhnâs theory of paradigm shifts in scientific belief,
the old paradigm of politics and economics is appearing more and more
inadequate. A new paradigm cries out to emerge.
As this book has argued, protest alone is unlikely to be sufficient when
the political system, although ostensibly democratic, has been co-opted
by the rich and the powerful. It is implausible to expect such a system
to deliver, for instance, necessary banking reform, when banking CEOs
enjoy far greater access to the political system than ordinary voters.
Just read the newspapers.
Instead, a new system needs to be created. What that system should
consist of has been laid out in this book. At Zuccotti Park in downtown
Manhattan, where the Occupy Wall Street protests are centered, some of
the attributes of a new system are already evident.
Instead of a hierarchy, decisions among the protesters are made by
consensus. Everyone who wants to gets a chance to speak. Each night, a
âgeneral assemblyâ of the protesters is convened. There are no leaders,
but it is organized. And, amazingly, everyone respects the common rules.
When one speaks, nobody interrupts. Though the police have banned
bullhorns and microphones, across the square other people echo the words
of the speaker so that everyone of the hundreds present can listen.
Paradoxically, this has had the effect of binding the group more closely
together. Even the act of one person speaking is now, thanks to the
âhuman mikeâ more involving. Astonishingly, it feels like an intimate
conversation, but among hundreds of people.
But the drawbacks of this form of protest are also evident. There is no
list of demands. No one claims to speak for all the protesters, so there
is no single common message save, perhaps, âEnough!â This has confounded
many commentators and journalists, accustomed perhaps to more directed
and traditional forms of protest. What do you want? they ask. But if one
would-be leader were to stand up with a manifesto, others would surely
protest that no one has the right to sum up their demands. As I heard
one man exclaim, with some passion, âI donât want anyone to speak for
me!â
A more succinct plea for direct involvement in politics and our future
could hardly be spoken.
But for such protests to amount to anything, change must be inspired
that can be transmitted across the system, and not confined to a few
thousand idealists on the streets. It must be change that anyone, with a
will, can undertake.
What might this consist of?
The economy can be changed from the inside out by altering the basic
model of the company, from privately owned profit-seeking, to
cooperative benefit. Cooperative companies, owned by their employees
(or, rather, partners) can be both competitive but also fair, and more
fulfilling for all involved. They can hardwire justice as part of their
constructionâfor instance, by declaring a commitment that the highest
paid employee is paid no more than, say, five times the lowest. By
making every worker a partner, they can create an entirely different
culture of the workplace, where everyone has a voiceâand a stakeâin
success, in contrast to the latent antagonism between highly paid bosses
and minimally paid employees.
Then the choice is for all of us to encourage such companies with our
patronage. Thus, this culture, this new way of doing things, can spread,
an organic change to the nature of the economy. As cooperative companies
multiply, they can form collaborative networks, where
business-to-business transactions reinforce the trend, which one day may
then become the norm. The genesis of such networks is already visible,
in efforts like solidarityNYC.org, a website that lists the many
businesses that promote valuesâsustainability, economic justiceâother
than mere profit. Already, the site covers a vast range of goods and
services, from food basics to financial services. It can be done, but it
involves a choice.
Other changes are possible too, though none will come about by the
natural forces of the marketâor by government legislation.
How might we replace the currently iniquitous and risky financial
sector, where risk taking has been insured by the taxpayer but the
profits go only to the bankers, a system that is not only grossly
unfair, but also has put the entire global economy in jeopardy? In
Canada, the third largest national bank is a credit union. Illustrating
the stranglehold of the profit-seeking banks on Washington, such a
national bank is all but impossible in the U.S., such are the obstacles
in federal legislation, the result of intensive and wholly
self-interested lobbying by the commercial banks.
But it is not implausible to imagine a cooperatively owned bank that is
not only national, but international, and able to reap the economies of
scale currently enjoyed only by the big private banks. Cynics will
snigger at the idealism of such a venture, but the cynic, as Oscar Wilde
once observed, knows only the price of everything, not its value. No one
pretends that the challenge is easy, but to imagine it is a start.
It is the same story with politics or, to put it more accurately, the
method of deciding our future. It is hard to find anyone in America who
still believes in the current political system. Indeed, even politicians
must attack âpolitics as usualâ in order to stand a chance of being
elected. Yet here too, there is widespread cynicism that any improvement
is possible. The problem seems just too big. We shrug and sigh with
deepening despair, but nothing is done to change it.
Taking control of our affairs must start with doing just that. The
necessary change will not come from above, however much we wish for it.
The habit of taking a full part in decisions about the things that
matter to us must start small, like the participatory decision-making at
Zuccotti Park. At the schools our children attend, parents and teachers
can form collective groups to debate the schoolâs business. Whatever the
rules of the school, those that run it, including the local authorities,
must pay heed
The same can be done at other local institutions, including hospitals or
parks. Participationâand government of our own affairsâstarts to become
habitual and the norm. Local residents can come together to debate local
concerns, from muggings to tree-planting. This is how self-government
can begin.
And this is key. At no point does this book propose violent revolution,
or the overthrow of the existing system, or indeed anything illegal
except perhaps in resisting the most vicious repression. This is a
revolution that can, and perhaps should, come about gradually, changing
minds and customs day by day. It is a revolution that will come about
through small actions, starting with a few, but then spreading to the
many, a revolution that will come about through demonstrating the value
of this new way of doing thingsâshow, donât tellâand neither forcing
others nor lecturing them, and least of all ramming change down
unyielding throats.
Gradually then, and by force of example, self-government of the many by
the many can become the norm. Networks of cooperation will emerge,
reinforcing positive change elsewhere. Borders need not be an obstacle.
In a highly connected world, they are arguably less and less relevant.
The most effective international networks of the twenty-first century
have been terrorists and criminal syndicates. They have already
recognized and exploited the true nature of the world today. We must
replace them with better and more powerful bonds of mutual cooperation,
untrammeled by archaic boundaries.
Ultimately, such bonds offer a greater stability than the fragile if
logical-seeming architecture of state-based interaction, which is in
fact secured upon very uncertain foundations: the false calculus of a
stateâs âinterests.â Instead, these would be deeper and broader flows of
collaboration, comprising the real and enacted interests and ideals of
peoples cooperating, en masse. Indeed, the failure of the state-based
system in managing our most worrying problemsâeconomic volatility,
climate changeâindicates that the system itself may now be the problem,
for it is more perpetuating this instability than solving it.
Again, this is not to propose the abolition of the international
diplomatic system, or the demolition of the United Nations. Instead, it
is about a more fundamental shift in our modelsâand practiceâof human
cooperation. But it is a shift comprising the doing of a new way, slowly
replacing the old, simply by being better and rendering the earlier
obsolete.
After working within government, I stopped believing that protest or
campaigning can deliver real justice and enduring change, even if such
methods can call attention to urgent need. The current system is far too
deeply entrenched. Small but important battles for justice may be
wonâfor instance, to legalize gay marriage, but overall the war is still
being won by those who put profit before people, exploitation over the
environment, and who claim states matter more than the peoples who make
them. Sorry to say, but those who believe that others should be led,
told or coerced, not inspired, are winning. These cynics are far fewer
in number than those who want a better way. But they have the better
weaponsâpolitical access and the abiding power of money over numbers.
And their most powerful weapon is secretâit is our own acquiescence and
belief in the immutability of the system.
In her brilliant analysis of the recent financial collapse, and how the
irresponsible actions of a tiny number of bankers ruined the livelihoods
of millions, the Financial Times journalist Gillian Tett offers a
compelling hypothesis of how the disaster came about: âIn most
societies, elites try to maintain their power not simply by garnering
wealth, but also by dominating the mainstream ideologies, in terms of
both what is said and what is not discussed. Social âsilencesâ serve to
maintain power structures, in ways that participants often barely
understand themselves let alone plan.â[177]
Somehow, the neat logic of neoclassical economics and representative
democracy has created a mental cage for our minds, and ambitions. In
theory, such systems are ideal; but in practice, their imperfections are
ever more evident. And yet the theoretical logic is so often repeated,
it is as if an insurmountable wall surrounds our imagination: We can see
nothing beyond, and dare not even conceive it. We have been numbed into
inaction.
In the current way of things, the blatant selfishness, neglect and
cruelty of the few is almost easier to stomach than the feeble apathy of
those who claim that nothing better is possible, and that this is just
the way things are, ordained by unarguable theory if not by some supreme
power. This is exactly how the silence is perpetuated; this is exactly
how the status quo is maintained.
Such numbed passivity is a denial of our very humanityâand moreover
leaves the field empty for the foe. It is inhuman to tolerate the rank
and visible suffering of others. To believe the patent falsehood that
the few who rule know better than the many is as demeaning to the rulers
as to the ruled. It is pathetic to witness the injustice of the status
quo and yet do nothing, however slight, to amend it. Above all, this
inaction in the face of inequity and looming crisis is to render
ourselves less than we are.
There is thrill in the fight, even if there must also be fear. As
Spartacus gloriously put it in the eponymous movie, âIâd rather be here,
a free man among brothers, facing a long march and a hard fight, than to
be the richest citizen in Rome, fat with food he didnât work for, and
surrounded by slaves.â
But this adventure will not happen of its own accord.
This book is not proposing a revolution against government, but one in
our own attitudes. The individual is the most effective agent in
altering their immediate circumstances. Thus, they are the most
effective agent, when acting collectively, in effecting global changeâin
anything. Moreover, action opens a possibility that is strange and
unfamiliar, a world without limits: to realize at last fully what one
is, what we are as humans. This is not an immutable or logical force
that we can simply observe and idly comment upon. It requires summoning
up our own dark forces, our fear, our hunger, our ideals: It requires
action.
The alternatives are grim to contemplate. The slow but inevitable
decline in state power can be arrested, but only by governments
acquiring more power, thereby constraining our own freedom and
exacerbating many of the pernicious trends already here identified. The
growing sense of disorder will attract those who offer to calm the
stormy waters, proclaiming order and certainty in place of chaos.
Twenty-first-century fascism probably wonât look much like
twentieth-century fascism. We are too inoculatedâone hopesâagainst the
crude semiotics of the swastika and black shirts and the devastating
violence of the Holocaust. It will come in a different form, cleverly
argued and convincingly presented. Instead of Nazis gathering in Munich
beer halls, it may start on a website, for technology is indifferent to
democrats or fascists. Indeed, jihadist terrorists share with
twentieth-century European fascists their absolutism and willingness to
sacrifice innocent life in the construction of a greater societyâand
they are not alone in this inhuman calculus. Meanwhile, a new breed
emerges of European anti-immigration politicians and their American
analogues, with smart suits and whitened teeth. As the disorder grows,
so too, with inevitability, will emerge those who promise to tame it
with authoritarianism and, inevitable but admitted only sotto voce,
coercive force.
The choice will become clearer: to cede our voice to those louder, to
watch while governments, corporations and criminal networks joust for
control, or to join battle for agency over affairs that are rightfully
our own.
There is no easy answer to the problems that confront humanity in the
twenty-first century; it would be foolish to place our faith in one form
of managementâgovernmentâto solve them. Whether environmental
degradation, incipient political violence, economic volatility or a host
of other dangers, the evidence is stark of governmentâs waning powers.
If others are not to exploit this instability, there is but one
alternative: to step in ourselves.
The goal cannot be defined neatly, as a concrete system or a state of
affairs. It is instead a method, a process, a meansâwhich is itself an
end. And by its nature, no one can define where that process may lead.
Critics can paint that blank canvas with nightmares; I can suggest
instead a future of cooperation, justice, mutual understanding and a
deeper sense of purpose upon this crowded planet. If this path is taken,
a vista of possibility may open up, beyond the dull limits of the ideas
that today dominate our conception of society and ourselves. The limits
are of conventional thought; the possibility is of us, ourselves: the
human.
Somewhere along the way, anaesthetized by vacuous but incessant
politics, ubiquitous advertising and the flickering screen, we have
forgotten that we are at our best in adventure, compassion for others
and the aspiration for something greater. When confronted by danger and
unfathomable challenge, as we surely are, only then are we truly alive.
Words like âmeaning,â âpurposeâ and âsolidarityâ capture a small sense
of this richness, but in fact it comprises much, much more. It is
nothing less than the human project, lived to the fullest. No longer a
life of mere silent acceptance, but instead the imagining and
construction of a true and direct democracy of the people, a vibrant but
just economy and, with these prizes, a better world.
Even failure is better than acquiescence.
More than a dozen people helped with the research for this book over the
five years I spent preparing it. I would like particularly to thank Tait
Foster, who gave me a great deal of excellent, prompt and accurate
research help.
There were many others who read the book, listened to its ideas and
provided suggestions and helpful criticism. Many people, therefore,
should share the credit for the book, and I thank them sincerely, while
all errors of course remain my own. They include:
Rob Akam, Ardian Arifaj, Stephanie Blair, Lyle Berman, Lili Birnbaum,
John Brademas, Jake Camara, Royston Coppenger, David Cornwell, Neill
Denny, Joy de Menil, Anna Dupont, Mark Earls, Susanna Emmet, Nick
Fraser, Karl French, Sasha FrĂšre-Jones, Katie Genereux, Ed Harriman,
Arya Iranpour, Ian Irvine, Mladen Joksic, Tina Kraja, Jordan Kyle,
Alnoor Ladha, Horatia Lawson, Ann Lee, Neil Levine, Andrew Lewis,
Professor Catherine Lu, Joshua Marston, Catherine Martin, Charlotte
Meyer, Professor Laila Parsons, Vincent Pouliot, Catherine Ross,
Clementine Ross, Ivo Ross, Karmen Ross, Oliver Ross, Paddy (Alan) Ross,
Victoria (Tori) Rowan, Jeffrey Rubin, Iain Scollay, Imran Shafi,
Angharad Thain, Inigo Thomas, Professor Rob Wisnovsky and Melissa
Withers.
I want to thank my colleagues at, and the board members of, Independent
Diplomat, and Whitney Ellsworth in particular, who have been very
patient in tolerating the preparation of this book, and the voluble
expression of its ideas, sometimes in very primitive form. I am
profoundly grateful to my wife, Karmen, who has accompanied me in the
long journey of this book, and remains, as ever, my chief inspiration
and most acute critic. More than anyone, she has helped me cut through
the wooliness and hypocrisies of political convention, including most
particularly my own, to the necessary truths of injustice.
I am especially grateful to David Rosenthal at Blue Rider Press for
supporting this book, and for his acute advice and criticism, and to
Aileen Boyle and other colleagues at Blue Rider, and to Dorian Hastings,
for their rapid and sensitive encouragement and support. And I thank my
editor at Simon & Schuster (UK), Mike Jones, who shepherded the book
when it must have seemed a doomed venture. Iâm deeply indebted to my
agents in the UK and U.S., respectively Jonny Geller at Curtis Brown and
George Lucas at Inkwell Management. Without their help and
encouragement, at times in dark days, this book would not have come into
being.
[1] A crucial factor behind the crisis wrought by the selling of âcredit
default options (or swaps)â in the 2008 financial crisis was that these
products, initially designed to spread risk, in actual practice obscured
it, because purchasers of the CDOs did not properly understand the risk
they comprised.
[2] âThe Flash Crash: Autopsy,â Economist, Oct. 7, 2010.
[3] Alex Evans of Chatham House originated this term.
[4] âFood and Water Driving 21^(st)-Century African Land Grab,â
Observer, Mar. 7, 2010.
[5] âImmeasurable loss,â Economist, Nov. 12, 2008.
[6] As reported in Financial Times, Nov. 9, 2010.
[7] State Department Assistant Secretary for Human Rights Mike Posner,
reported in âClinton Defends Human Rights Approach,â New York Times,
Dec. 14, 2009.
[8] Colum Lynch, âU.N. Takes Stock of Its Diminished Influence,â Sept.
13, 2010,
.
[9] Parag Khanna, âFuture Shock: Welcome to the New Middle Ages,â
Financial Times, Dec. 29, 2010.
[10] Timothy Garton Ash, âTimothy Garton Ash in Davos: Illiberal
Capitalism and New World Disorder,â posted to his listserve, Jan. 28,
2011.
[11] The head of the British armed services, Sir David Richards, told
the BBC in November 2010 that Al Qaeda could only be âcontainedâ not
defeated, saying that you cannot defeat âan idea.â BBC website, âWest
Cannot Defeat Al Qaeda, Says U.K. Forces Chief,â Nov. 14, 2010.
[12] âClimate Change Diplomacy: Back from the Brink,â Economist, Dec.
16, 2010.
[13] The so-called Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro.
[14] âAs Jobs Fade Away,â Economist, May 6, 2010.
[15] Bob Diamond, the chief executive of Barclays Bank, said, âThere was
a period of remorse and apology; that period needs to be over.â His
expected bonus that year was over ÂŁ3 million.
[16] Joseph Rowntree Foundation.
[17] âChina to Alter Taxes in Attempt to Cut Wealth Gap,â Financial
Times, Apr. 20, 2011.
[18] âIndiaâs Boom Fails to Feed the Hungry,â Financial Times, Dec. 23,
2010.
[19] The letter set out the legal justificationâself-defenseâunder
Article 51 of the UN Charter for the United Kingdomâs participation in
the allied invasion.
[20] Economist, May 6, 2010.
[21] AFP, âAl-Qaeda Vows to Continue Parcel Bomb Attacks,â Nov. 20,
2010.
[22]
C. J. Chivers, The Gun (New York: Simon & Schuster, 2010).
[23] Small Arms Survey (Geneva: Graduate Institute of International and
Development Studies, 2009).
[24] Steve Graham, âFrom Helmand to Merseyside: Unmanned Drones and the
Militarization of UK Policing,â Open Democracy, Sept. 27, 2010;
.
[25] Dana Priest and William M. Arkin, âMonitoring Americaâ and âTop
Secret America,â Washington Post, Dec. 20, 2010;
.
[26] Mark Easton, âLife in UK âHas Become Lonelier,ââ BBC website,
; see Mark Eastonâs blog.
[27] John T. Cacioppo and William Patrick, Loneliness: Human Nature and
the Need for Social Connection (New York: Norton, 2008).
[28] As an official working during the first Gulf War with Iraq in 1991,
I had as one of my duties to count Saddamâs tanks and soldiers in such a
way as to affirm the claim, not strictly true but made by a politician
and therefore requiring some kind of validation, that Iraq had âthe
third largest army in the world.â This claim could only be âprovenâ if
all of the reserve forces of the Iraqi army were included in the count,
but were ignored in counting the armies of other competitors for the
third place slot (India, the United States, Russia).
[29] âIraq Warns of More Suicide Missions,â BBC website, Mar. 29, 2003.
[30] Dexter Filkins, The Forever War (New York: Vintage Books, 2008).
[31] BBC website, Apr. 5, 2003;
.
[32] See, for example, Robert Pape, âSuicide Terrorism and Democracy,â
Cato Institute, Policy Analysis No. 582, Nov. 1, 2006, and other such
arguments by Pape.
[33] See, for instance, Assaf Moghadam, âMotives for Martyrdom: Al
Qaida, Salafi Jihad, and the Spread of Suicide Attacks,â International
Security 33:3, 2009.
[34] The PKK in Turkey fights for a Kurdish homeland.
[35] Max Hastings, Retribution: The Battle for Japan 1944â45 (New York:
Vintage, 2009).
[36] See âSetback for U.S. Mortgage Sector,â Financial Times, April 30,
2010, quoting a study of the same date by the Kellogg School of
Management at Northwestern University.
[37] âA Framework for Pro-environmental Behaviors,â Department for
Environment, Food and Rural Affairs DEFRA), 2008;
.
[38] Kees Keizer, Siegwart Lindenberg and Linda Steg, âThe Spreading of
Disorder,â Science Express, Nov. 20, 2008.
[39] Brooks Barnes, âClaudette Colvin: From Footnote to Fame in Civil
Rights History,â New York Times, Nov. 26, 2009.
[40] David J. Garrow, quoted in Barnes, âClaudette Colvin: From Footnote
to Fame in Civil Rights History.â
[41] In this book, itself influential, Malcolm Gladwell suggests that a
few highly connected people influence the choices of everyone else, what
he calls the âLaw of the Few.â Another bookâThe Influentialsâsimilarly
claims that âone American in 10 tells the other 9 how to vote, where to
eat, and what to buy.â
[42] The picture can be found online at
www.nytimes.com/interactive/2008/08/28/us/politics/20080828_OBAMA_PANO.html?scp=2&sq=obama%20denver%20speech&st=cse.
[43] OpenSecrets.org.
[44] Morning Edition, NPR, Feb. 9, 2009.
[45] Robert Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American
Community (New York: Simon & Schuster, 2001).
[46] Horst SchlÀmmer, a mock politician played by a well-known German
comedian.
[47] âBefore Election, Not a Voter Was Stirring,â New York Times, Aug.
20, 2009.
[48] OpenSecrets.org.
[49] âThe Road to Riches Is Called K Street,â Washington Post, June 22,
2005.
[50] âHow BP Drafted Brusselsâ Climate Legislation,â www.Spinwatch.org,
Dec. 15, 2010.
[51] This trend is well documented in many democratic systems. See, for
instance, Peter Mair and Ingried van Biezen, âParty Membership in Twenty
European Democracies: 1980â2000,â Party Politics, Jan. 2001; Robert
Putnam, Democracies in Flux: The Evolution of Social Capital in
Contemporary Society (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); and most
recently, Paul Whiteley, âIs the Party Over? The Decline of Party
Activism and Membership across the Democratic World,â paper presented at
University of Manchester conference, April 2009.
[52] The source is worldpublicopinion.org, whose survey âWorld Public
Opinion on Democracy,â a twenty-country global public opinion poll on
democracy and governance, found that in every nation polled, publics
support the principles of democracy. At the same time, in nearly every
nation, majorities are dissatisfied with how responsive their government
is to the will of the people. For a more detailed analysis, see:
=
[53] âCuomo Accepts Millions from the Interests He Assails,â New York
Times, June 23, 2010.
[54] Senator Fritz Hollings, interviewed on PBS NewsHour. [NEED DATE;
NOT FOUND (about K Street/lobbyists]
[55] Center for Responsive Politics.
[56] See Nina Bernstein, âCity of Immigrants Fills Jail Cells with Its
Own,â New York Times, Dec. 27, 2008.
[57] BBC News. [NEED DATE?]
[58] One of the clients of The Gabriel Company, headed by Edward
Gabriel, former U.S. Ambassador to Morocco is, of course, Morocco (U.S.
Department of Justice, Foreign Agents Registration Act [FARA] listings).
[59] âAmerican Lobbyists Work for Ivorian Leader,â New York Times, Dec.
23, 2010.
[60] âU.S. Approved Trade with Blacklisted Nations,â New York Times,
Dec. 23, 2010.
[61] âWhile Warning about Fat, U.S. Pushes Cheese Sales,â New York
Times, Nov. 6, 2010.
[62] Private Eye, Mar. 18, 2011.
[63] âSome Philanthropists Are No Longer Content to Work Quietly,â New
York Times, Nov. 7, 2008.
[64] Urban Institute, National Center for Charitable Statistics.
[65] Grant Jordan and William Maloney, âThe Rise of Protest Business in
Britain,â in J. W. van Deth, ed., Private Groups and Public Life (New
York: Routledge, 1997).
[66] âAt National Review, a Threat to Its Reputation for Erudition,â New
York Times, Nov. 17, 2008.
[67] âThe Daily Me,â New York Times, Mar. 19, 2009.
[68] âThe Big Sort,â Economist, June 19, 2008 .
[69] Though there is not the space here to explore this phenomenon
fully, this sortingâor to put it more bluntly, segregationâby political
views, which also occurs according to income, religion and race, is a
characteristic of complex systems. Economist Thomas Schelling won the
Nobel prize in economics for explaining how the choice made by a few,
say, Democrats, to live in a particular location can, over time,
transform or âtipâ a hitherto mixed neighborhood into one that is
uniformly of one political persuasion. Even if individuals are tolerant
at the micro level, over time a neighborhood will become segregated, a
phenomenon called âmicro level tolerance; macro level segregation.â
[70] I was the strategy coordinator at the UN Mission in Kosovo (UNMIK)
from 2003 to 2004.
[71] The deaths were later found to have been accidental.
[72] Human Rights Watch, www.hrw.org.
[73] Fareed Zakaria, âWhat America Has Lost: Itâs Clear We Overreacted
to 9/11,â Newsweek, Sept. 4, 2010.
[74] Rebecca Solnit, A Paradise Built in Hell: The Extraordinary
Communities That Arise in Disasster (New York,: Viking, 2009).
[75] Letter from Professor Robert H. Wade Financial Times, Jan. 4, 2010.
[76] âFrom Behind Bars, Madoff Spins His Story,â Financial Times, Apr.
8, 2011.
[77] SEC, Office of Inspector-General Report, case number OIG-509;
.
[78] See, for instance, âReport Details How Madoffâs Web Ensnared
S.E.C.,â New York Times, Sept. 3, 2009.
[79] âChief Regulator Resigns after Strong Criticism,â Financial Times,
May 28, 2010.
[80] online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/MarkopolosTestimony20090203.pdf.
[81] Joe Nocera, âMadoff Had Accomplices: His Victims,â New York Times,
Mar. 13, 2009.
[82] The full name of the bill is the âWall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act of 2009.â
[83] âWall Street to Sidestep Volcker Rule,â Financial Times, Nov. 10,
2010.
[84] Letter from Professor Anat Admati of Stanford University and
nineteen others, âHealthy Banking System Is the Goal, Not Profitable
Banks,â Financial Times, Nov. 9, 2010.
[85] Clive Crook, âWe Have Failed to Muffle the Banks,â Financial Times,
Sept. 12, 2010.
[86] âDimon Warns of Bank âNail in Coffin,ââ Financial Times, March 30,
2011.
[87] âThe Bipartisanship Racket,â New York Times, Dec. 19, 2010.
[88] See Gary Wolf, âWhy Craigâs List Is Such a Mess,â Wired, Aug. 24,
2009.
[89] Mark Pesce at the Personal Democracy Forum, New York City, 2008.
[90] The New York Times reported that âStacy Snyder, then a 25-year-old
teacher in training at Conestoga Valley High School in Lancaster, Pa.,
posted a photo on her MySpace page that showed her at a party wearing a
pirate hat and drinking from a plastic cup, with the caption âDrunken
Pirate.â After discovering the page, her supervisor at the high school
told her the photo was âunprofessional,â and the dean of Millersville
University School of Education, where Snyder was enrolled, said she was
promoting drinking in virtual view of her underage students. As a
result, days before Snyderâs scheduled graduation, the university denied
her a teaching degree.â Jeffrey Rosen, âThe Web Means the End of
Forgetting,â New York Times, July 19, 2010.
[91] The Business and Human Rights Council is one example.
[92] www.sourcemap.org.
[93] âFrom Behind Bars, Madoff Spins His Story,â Financial Times, Apr.
8, 2011.
[94] That NGO is International Crisis Group, whose local researcher,
Ardian Arifaj, contributed to the preparation of this section; see the
full Crisis Group report on the 2004 violence at their website,
www.crisisgroup.org.
[95] Eight Serbs and eleven Albanians were killed in the violence;
International Crisis Group.
[96] Kosovo became a state on Feb. 17, 2008. Independent Diplomat has
advised various of Kosovoâs governments and the multiparty negotiating
team in this process.
[97] An international embargo was in theory supposed to stop arms
supplies to both sides, but its enthusiastic enforcement by Britain,
France and others had the principal effect of denying arms to the
Republicans. Nazi Germany and Mussoliniâs Italy, meanwhile, breached the
embargo to support the Francoists with impunity. A similar situation
arose during the breakup of Yugoslavia in the 1990s when a UN arms
embargo, proposed and enforced by the UK, U.S. and others, failed to
diminish the military effectiveness of the genocidal armies of the
Bosnian Serbs (mainly because they already enjoyed the considerable
military resources of the former Yugoslav army). The UN embargo,
however, considerably hindered the defenses of their victims, the
Bosnian Muslims and Croats. The effect of that embargo therefore, as
with Spain in the 1930s, was to deliver a military advantage to the
fascist aggressor. In the 1930s, this was indeed the intent.
[98] Anthony Beevor, The Battle for Spain: The Spanish Civil War
1936â1939 (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 2006).
[99] In its first ten years of operation, the court has failed to secure
any convictions.
[100] www.notonourwatchproject.org.
[101] Edmund Sanders, âIs the Darfur Bloodshed Genocide? Opinions
Differ,â Los Angeles Times, May 4, 2009.
[102] Rob Crilly has made this accusation in his book Saving Darfur,
Everyoneâs Favourite African War (London: Reportage Press, 2010); see
also:
.
[103] The laughably named lordsoftheblog.net.
[104] âChinese Communist Party Opens Online Forum,â Financial Times,
Sept. 14, 2010, including quotation from Russell Leigh Moses, a
Beijing-based political analyst.
[105] âAthens on the Net,â New York Times, Sept. 13, 2009.
[106] www.seeclickfix.com.
[107] BBC News website. [ provide URL, date?]
[108] In American prisons, the proliferation of smart phones has allowed
criminals to continue to organize drug trafficking and gang activity
outside even while incarcerated; Facebook, Twitter and e-mail
listservees were used to coordinate recent protests across several
prisons (New York Times, âOutlawed, Cellphones Are Thriving in Prisons,â
Jan. 2, 2011).
[109] Alan Boswell, âSudanâs Government Crushed Protests by Embracing
Internet,â McClatchy Newspapers, Apr. 7, 2011.
[110] âChinaâs Censors Tackle and Trip over the Internet,â New York
Times, Apr. 7, 2010.
[111] At the Personal Democracy Forum, New York City, June 2010.
[112] Jeffrey Rosen, âGoogleâs Gatekeepers,â New York Times, Nov. 30,
2008.
[113] âThe Daily Me,â New York Times, Mar. 19, 2009.
[114] âU.S. Warns of Terror Groupsâ Western Recruits,â Financial Times,
Oct. 6, 2010.
[115] The so-called digital divide.
[116] See www.americaspeaks.org: âUnified New Orleans Planâ; this site
also has many other examples of deliberative democracy in action.
[117] Cass Sunstein, Going to Extremes: How Like Minds Unite and Divide
(New York: Oxford University Press, 2009); Sunstein is now an adviser to
the Obama White House.
[118] âHow to Get a Better Informed European Public,â Financial Times,
June 3, 2009.
[119] A senior Labour government minister, Peter Hain, for instance,
chose Homage as âthe book that changed my lifeâ in the New Statesman.
[120] Partido Obrero de UnificaciĂłn Marxista, or Workersâ Party of
Marxist Unification.
[121] George Orwell, Homage to Catalonia (Boston: Houghton Mifflin
Harcourt, 2010), p. 104.
[122] Arendt coined the term, in describing Nazi Adolf Eichmann during
his trial: âthe banality of evil.â
[123] Christopher Browning, Ordinary Men: Reserve Police Battalion 101
and the Final Solution in Poland (New York: Harper Perennial, 1993).
[124] Benedict Carey, âDecades Later, Still Asking: Would I Pull That
Switch,â New York Times, July 1, 2008.
[125] Dr. Jerry M. Burger, âReplicating Milgram: Would People Still Obey
Today?â American Psychologist, Jan. 2009.
[126] In former colonies that are now members of the British
Commonwealth, British representations are not known as embassies but as
High Commissions.
[127] Professor Joy Gordon, Invisible War: The United States and the
Iraq Sanctions (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2010).
[128] As the UKâs Middle East and Iraq âexpertâ at the UN from 1998 to
2002, I was required to read a thick folder of intelligence every day on
Iraq, its WMD and efforts to rearm. There was not a single report
suggesting a connection between the Saddam regime and Al Qaeda, nor
would such a connection be plausible given the radically different
natures of these entitiesâone secular and Baâathist, the other
fundamentalist and Islamist. The head of Britainâs Secret Intelligence
Service (often known as MI6) also confirmed the absence of connection.
[129] International Maritime Bureau.
[130] See, for instance, Alan Beattie, âWealthy Countries Fail to Hit
Aid Target,â Financial Times, Feb., 16, 2010.
[131] âMillennium Goalsâ (editorial), Financial Times, Sept. 21, 2010.
[132] Full title De la maniÚre de négocier avec les souverains, de
lâutilitĂ© des negotiations, du choix des ambassadeurs et des envoyez, et
des qualitez necessaries pour réussir dans ces employs.
[133] Unpublished research by Independent Diplomat.
[134] These arguments are more fully discussed in my earlier book
Independent Diplomat: Dispatches from an Unaccountable Elite.
[135] By contrast, an excellent account of the review conference is
online: Rebecca Johnson, âNPT: Challenging the Nuclear Powersâ Fiefdom,â
June 15, 2010;
.
[136] See Alexander Golts, âAn Illusory New START,â Moscow Times, Mar.
30, 2010.
[137] EastWest Institute, âRe-framing Nuclear De-Alert: Decreasing the
Operational Readiness of U.S. and Russian Arsenals,â 2009;
.
[138] Reported in ScienceDaily, Dec. 11, 2006, from the annual meeting
of the American Geophysical Union in San Francisco, where twin papers on
this topic by scientists from Rutgers University, the University of
Colorado at Boulder, and the University of California at Los Angeles
were announced.
[139] Ayman al-Zawahiri, The Exoneration: A Treatise Exonerating of the
Nation of the Pen and the Sword of the Denigrating Charge of Being
Irresolute and Weak (2008), referred to in Rolf Mowatt-Larssen, âAl
Qaedaâs Nuclear Ambitions,â Foreign Policy Nov. 16, 2010.
[140] See Seymour Hersh, âThe Online Threat: Should We Be Worried About
Cyber War?â New Yorker, Nov. 1, 2010.
[141] See Niall Ferguson, âComplexity and Collapse: Empires on the Edge
of Chaos,â Foreign Affairs, Mar./Apr. 2010.
[142] Professor Page teaches complexity theory at the University of
Michigan and presents the invaluable primer on complexity theory,
âUnderstanding Complexityâ a DVD-based course from The Teaching Company.
[143] See www.commonsecurityclub.org.
[144] Weâve got time to help:
wevegottimetohelp.blogspot.com
/.
[145]
, citing M. K. Gandhi, Satyagraha in South Africa (Ahmedabad: Navajivan,
1928), pp. 109â10
[146]
, citing journalist Webb Miller.
[147] Judith Brown, the eminent historian of Gandhi, reaches a more
nuanced view of the Salt Satyagraha, and indeed Gandhiâs movement of
civil resistance, in her excellent essay âGandhi and Civil Resistance in
India, 1917â47,â in Adam Roberts and Timothy Garton Ash, eds., Civil
Resistance and Power Politics (New York: Oxford University Press, 2009).
The essay is well worth reading for those interested in judgments of the
effectiveness of Gandhiâs methods.
[148] Ernesto âCheâ Guevara, Guerrilla Warfare (New York: Penguin Books,
1961).
[149]
, citing Alain Gresh, âThe Dream of Better World Is Back,â Le monde
diplomatique, May 8, 2009.
[150] The POLISARIO Front, the political representatives of the Sahrawi
people, is a client of Independent Diplomat.
[151] Nelson Santos, East Timorâs permanent representative to the United
Nations, in conversation with the author.
[152] âGroup of Bed-Stuy Men, We Make Us Better, Escorts Pedestrians in
Wake of Robberies,â New York Daily News, Nov. 30, 2010.
[153] Guy Dinmore, âNaples Fights to Reclaim the Mafia Badlands,â
Financial Times, Sept. 27, 2010.
[154] Raghuram G. Rajan, Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still
Threaten the World Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press,
2010).
[155] According to economist Raghuram Rajanâs calculations, for every
dollar of growth in income between 1976 and 2007, 58 cents went to the
top 1 percent of households. The other 99 percent of American families
had to scrap over the 42 cents of loose change. The result was a country
as unequal as it had been just before the Wall Street crash of 1929âand
with much the same results. The Guardian, âWhat the ÂŁ35,000 Cocktail
Taught Us,â August 3, 2010.
[156] Transcript and recording available at
www.johnlewispartnership.co.uk.
[157] âCase Study: How to Cope with a Slump in Demand,â Financial Times,
Dec. 23, 2010.
[158] See the review of Kotlikoffâs book: Martin Sandbu, âA Less
Wonderful Life for Bankersâ Financial Times, Mar. 22, 2010.
[159] See Elinor Ostromâs excellent âmeta-researchâ article âA
Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action:
Presidential Address, American Political Science Association, 1997,â
American Political Science Review 92(1): 1â22.
[160] The Heritage Foundation published an interesting but not
comprehensive analysis of principles to observe in health care
cooperatives: Edmund Haislmaier , Dennis Smith and Nina Owcharenko,
âHealthcare Cooperatives, Doing It the Right Wayâ June 18, 2009,
available at
.
[161] ForestEthics.org.
[162] www.cdproject.net.
[163] âBanks Grow Wary of Environmental Risks,â New York Times, Aug. 30,
2010.
[164] See, for instance, the Business and Human Rights Resource Centre
at www.business-humanrights.org, or www.climatecounts.org.
[165] This is a paraphrasing of what Bernard-Henri LĂ©vy said during a
discussion at the New York Public Library on Sept. 16, 2008. Itâs
possible that I recorded this statement incorrectly, in which case my
apologies to the reader and âBHL.â
[166] If in doubt about this question, please consult my testimony to
the Butler inquiry in 2004, and to the Chilcot inquiry in 2010, both
available at relevant websites, or upon request.
[167] Peter Singer, The Life You Can Save: Acting Now to End World
Poverty (New York: Random House, 2009).
[168] www.thelifeyoucansave.com.
[169] Robert D. Putnam, âE Pluribus Unum: Diversity and Community in the
21^(st) Century,â 2006 Johan Skytte Prize Lecture, in Scandinavian
Political Studies 30:2, 2007.
[170] The new sanctions policy altered controls on exports to Iraq so
that everything was permitted except goods that appeared on a âcontrol
listâ of items that might be used for weapons manufacture. Previously,
nothing could be exported except goods which were expressly permitted,
case-by-case, by the UN sanctions committee (with some exceptions).
[171] You will find further discussion of these options on my personal
website, www.carneross.com, and in my opinion article âLetâs Boycott,
Isolate and Sabotage Gaddafi,â Financial Times, Mar. 10, 2011.
[172] I also recommend Mark Kurlanskyâs Nonviolence: The History of a
Dangerous Idea (New York: Modern Library, 2009).
[173] See âDutch Bankersâ Bonuses Axed by People Power,â Observer, Mar.
27, 2011.
[174] See âHelping Women Fight Back Against Street Harassment, Seconds
After It Occurs,â New York Times, Nov. 8, 2010.
[175] See this invaluable article on Stuxnet: Michael Joseph Gross, âA
Declaration of Cyber-War,â Vanity Fair, Apr. 2011.
[176] Quotations from Leo Tolstoy, War and Peace, are from the Louise
and Aylmer Maude translation (New York: Macmillan, 1943).
[177] Gillian Tett, Foolâs Gold: The Inside Story of J. P. Morgan and
How Wall St. Greed Corrupted Its Bold Dream and Created a Financial
Catastrophe (New York: Free Press, 2009).