💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 5210.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 05:33:24. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

🚧 View Differences

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Monetary policy - When will they learn?

2014-10-14 12:57:41

Oct 14th 2014, 9:40 by R.A. | LONDON

THE monetary economics of a world in which interest rates are close to zero are

not especially mysterious. Stimulating the economy at that point requires

central banks to raise expected inflation. Disinflation, by contrast, results

in passive tightening, since the central bank can't lower its policy rate and

since the real interest rate is the policy rate less expected inflation. In

this world, the downside risks are much larger than those to the upside. There

is infinite room to raise interest rates if inflation runs uncomfortably high

(one might even welcome that opportunity to push rates up as that would reduce

the probability that rates would fall to zero again in future). But there is no

room to reduce interest rates if inflation is running to low. That, in turn,

forces central banks to use unconventional policy or run psychological

operations to try to boost expectations. Central banks are not very good at

those sorts of things.

You need to overshoot, in other words, because undershooting feeds on itself.

The zero lower bound is a heavy drag on an economy that must be thrown off by

rapid growth. If a central bank is too cautious it will not simply fail to

escape the ZLB; the effort of trying to provide stimulus through unconventional

routes may lead to stimulus fatigue. The central bank may simply become less

willing to take the necessary expansionary steps, creating an increased risk

that the weight of the ZLB drags the economy beneath the waves.

Fatigue may be setting in at the Federal Reserve, which is expected to end its

asset-purchase programme at its meeting later this month. Hawkish members of

the Federal Open Market Committee are seizing on a relatively low and falling

unemployment rate and on good hiring numbers as evidence that the economy can

stand on its own. And if the Fed's main policy rate were at 4% rather than just

above 0%, they might have a point. But the FOMC ought to have learned by now

that an economy at the ZLB does not function like an economy in which interest

rates are well above zero.

The threat is clear enough. Inflation in America is below the Fed's 2% target

and looks to be falling again. The disinflationary winds blowing in from abroad

are strengthening to a gale. Commodity prices are tumbling; cheaper resources

will have a direct disinflationary impact in America but also signal a

weakening global economy which should itself reduce inflationary pressures.

Inflation in the euro zone has tumbled to 0.3%, and with many of the euro

area's large economies in or near recession the downside economic risks in

Europe are substantial. In Britain, which alongside America is the closest

thing the rich world has to an economic success story, inflation has dropped

sharply to just 1.2%, and markets are revising outward the date at which the

Bank of England is expected to raise interest rates.

American markets are once again hunkering down for a bout of disinflation.

Expectations for inflation over the next five years have fallen half a

percentage point since July, to around 1.5%: a level at which the Fed has

previously moved to begin new asset purchases. The yield on long-term

Treasuries is tumbling again; the 10-year is down to around 2.2%, from nearly

3% earlier this year. Equity prices are sinking while the dollar is rising

sharply. And futures markets now suggest the first increase in the Fed's main

policy rate will not occur until January of 2016.

My question for the Fed is: what happens when disinflation continues in

November and December after the Fed has termintated its asset purchase

programme? Is it prepared to start purchases up right away, or will it wait to

see whether things turn around? If so, how long is it prepared to wait? What is

the plan here? Employment growth is not going to continue at current rates for

very long if inflation expectations continue to behave this way while interest

rates are at zero.

There are so many ways things around the rich world could go very badly in

coming months. The euro zone, in particular, is entering a new and dangerous

crisis phase, with Germany seemingly committed to fiscal tightening even as its

economy falls into recession alongside France and Italy. A renewed dip into

recession could lead to revolt, in markets or in the political systems of

peripheral economies that have had enough of economic contraction forever.

The sensible course is what it has been for the last six years: keep pushing

until the economy is well clear of danger. If inflation gets up to 3% or 4% or

5%, well, there are far worse things, and the response is simple enough:

tighten policy. Erring in the opposite direction may end up far more costly,

however. As, I fear, we all may learn.