💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › james-guillaume-ideas-on-social-organization.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:16:47. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Ideas on Social Organization
Author: James Guillaume
Date: 1876
Language: en
Topics: after the revolution, education, organization
Source: Retrieved on 23 April 2011 from http://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/guillaume/works/ideas.htm
Notes: Written: August 1874;   Source: Bakunin on Anarchy, translated and edited by Sam Dolgoff, 1971.

James Guillaume

Ideas on Social Organization

I

The ideas outlined in the following pages can be effectively achieved

only by means of a revolutionary movement. It takes more than a day for

the great flood to break the dyke; the floodwaters mount slowly,

imperceptibly. But once the crest of the flood is reached, the collapse

is sudden, the dyke is washed away in the winking of an eye. We can

distinguish, then, two successive acts, the second being the necessary

consequence of the first. At first there is the slow transformation of

ideas, of needs, of the motives for action germinating in the womb of

society; the second begins when this transformation is sufficiently

advanced to pass into action. Then there is a brusque and decisive

turning point — the revolution — which is the culmination of a long

process of evolution, the sudden manifestation of a change long prepared

for and therefore inevitable.

No serious-minded man would venture to predict exactly how the

Revolution, the indispensable condition for social renovation, will come

about. Revolution is a natural fact, and not the act of a few persons;

it does not take place according to a preconceived plan but is produced

by uncontrollable circumstances which no individual can command. We do

not, therefore, intend to draw up a blueprint for the future

revolutionary campaign; we leave this childish task to those who;

believe in the possibility and the efficacy of achieving the

emancipation of humanity through personal dictatorship. We will confine

ourselves, on the contrary, to describing the kind of revolution most

attractive to us and the ways it can be freed from past errors.

The character of the revolution must at first be negative, destructive.

Instead of modifying certain institutions of the past, or adapting them

to a new order, it will do away with them altogether. Therefore, the

government will be uprooted, along with the Church, the army, the

courts, the schools, the banks, and all their subservient institutions.

At the same time the Revolution has a positive goal, that the workers

take possession of all capital and the tools of production. Let us

explain what is meant by the phrase “taking possession.”

Let us begin with the peasants and problems concerning the land. In many

countries, particularly in France, the priests and the bourgeoisie try

to frighten the peasants by telling them that the Revolution will take

their land away from them. This is an outrageous lie concocted by the

enemies of the people. The Revolution would take an exactly opposite

course: it would take the land from the bourgeoisie, the nobles, and the

priests and give it to the landless peasants. If a piece of land belongs

to a peasant who cultivates it himself, the Revolution would not touch

it. On the contrary, it would guarantee free possession and liquidate

all debts arising from the land. This land which once enriched the

treasury and was overburdened with taxes and weighed down by mortgages

would, like the peasant, be emancipated. No more taxes, no more

mortgages; the land becomes free, just like the man!

As to the land owned by the bourgeoisie, the clergy, and the nobles —

land hitherto cultivated by landless laborers for the benefit of their

masters — the Revolution will return this stolen land to the rightful

owners, the agricultural workers.

How will the Revolution take the land from the exploiters and give it to

the peasants? Formerly, when the bourgeois made a political revolution,

when they staged one of those movements which resulted only in a change

of masters dominating the people, they usually printed decrees,

proclaiming to the people the will of the new government. These decrees

were posted in the communes and the courts, and the mayor, the

gendarmes, and the prosecutors enforced them. The real people’s

revolution will not follow this model; it will not rule by decrees, it

will not depend on the services of the police or the machinery of

government. It is not with decrees, with words written on paper, that

the Revolution will emancipate the people but with deeds.

II

We will now consider how the peasants will go about deriving the

greatest possible benefit from their means of production, the land.

Immediately after the Revolution the peasants will be faced with a mixed

situation. Those who are already small proprietors will keep their plots

of land and continue to cultivate it with the help of their families.

The others, and they are by far the most numerous, who rented the land

from the big landowners or were simply agricultural wage laborers

employed by the owners, will take collective possession of the vast

tracts of land and work them in common.

Which of these two systems is best?

It is not a matter of what is theoretically desirable but of starting

with the facts and seeing what can be immediately achieved. From this

point of view, we say first that in this mixed economy the main purpose

of the Revolution has been achieved: the land is now the property of

those who cultivate it, and the peasants no longer work for the profit

of an idle exploiter who lives by their sweat. This great victory

gained, the rest is of secondary importance. The peasants can, if they

wish, divide the land into individual parcels and give each family a

share. Or else, and this would be much better, they can institute common

ownership and cooperative cultivation of the land. Although secondary to

the main point, i.e., the emancipation of the peasant, this question of

how best to work the land and what form of possession is best also

warrants careful consideration.

In a region which had been populated before the Revolution by peasants

owning small farms, where the nature of the soil is not very suitable

for extensive, large-scale cultivation, where agriculture has been

conducted in the same way for ages, where machinery is unknown or rarely

used — in such a region the peasants will naturally conserve the form of

ownership to which they are accustomed. Each peasant will continue to

cultivate the land as he did in the past, with this single difference:

his former hired hands, if he had any, will become his partners and

share with him the products which their common labor extracts from the

land.

It is possible that in a short time those peasants who remain small

proprietors will find it advantageous to modify their traditional system

of labor and production. If so, they will first associate to create a

communal agency to sell or exchange their products; this first

associated venture will encourage them to try others of a similar

nature. They would then, in common, acquire various machines to

facilitate their work; they would take turns to help each other perform

certain laborious tasks which are better accomplished when they are done

rapidly by a large team; and they would no doubt finally imitate their

brothers, the industrial workers, and those working on big farms, and

decide to pool their land and form an agricultural association. But even

if they linger for sonic years ill the same old routine, even if a whole

generation should elapse before the peasants ill some communes adopt the

system of collective property, it would still not constitute a serious

hindrance to the Revolution. The great achievements of the Revolution

will not be affected; the Revolution will have abolished agricultural

wage slavery and peonage and the agricultural proletariat will consist

only of free workers living ill peace and plenty, even in the midst of

the few remaining backward areas.

On the other hand, in large-scale agricultural operations, where a great

number of workers are needed to farm vast areas, where coordination and

cooperation are absolutely essential, collective labor will naturally

lead to collective property. An agricultural collective may embrace an

entire commune [autonomous regional unit] and, if economically necessary

for efficiency and greater production, many communes.

In these vast communities of agricultural workers, the land will not be

worked as it is today, by small peasant owners trying without success to

raise many different crops on tiny parcels of unsuitable land. There

will not be growing side by side oil one acre a little square of wheat,

a little square of potatoes, another of grapes, another of fodder,

another of fruit, etc. Each bit of land tends, by virtue of its physical

properties, its location, its chemical composition, to be most suitable

for the successful cultivation of certain specific crops. Wheat will not

be planted on soil suitable for grapes, nor potatoes on soil that could

best be used for pasture. The agricultural community, if it has only one

type of soil, will confine itself to the cultivation of crops which can

be produced ill quantity and quality with less labor, and the community

will prefer to exchange its products for those it lacks instead of

trying to grow them in small quantity and poor quality on unsuitable

land.

The internal organization of these agricultural communities need not

necessarily he identical; organizational forms and procedures will vary

greatly according to the preferences of the associated workers. So long

as they conform to the principles of justice and equality, the

administration of the community, elected by all the members, could be

entrusted either to an individual or to a commission of many members. It

will even be possible to separate the different administrative

functions, assigning each function to a special commission. The hours of

labor will be fixed not by a general law applicable to an entire

country, but by the decision of the community itself; but as the

community contracts relations with all the other agricultural workers of

the region, an agreement covering uniform working hours will probably be

reached. Whatever items are produced by collective labor will belong to

the community, and each member will receive remuneration for his labor

either in the form of commodities (subsistence, supplies, clothing,

etc.) or in currency. In some communities remuneration will be in

proportion to hours worked; in others payment will be measured by both

the hours of work and the kind of work performed; still other systems

will be experimented with to see how they work out.

The problem of property having been resolved, and there being no

capitalists placing a tax on the labor of the masses, the question of

types of distribution and remuneration become secondary. We should to

the greatest possible extent institute and be guided by the principle

From each according to his ability, to each according to his need. When,

thanks to the progress of scientific industry and agriculture,

production comes to outstrip consumption, and this will be attained some

years after the Revolution, it will no longer be necessary to stingily

dole out each worker’s share of goods. Everyone will draw what he needs

from the abundant social reserve of commodities, without fear of

depletion; and the moral sentiment which will be more highly developed

among free and equal workers will prevent, or greatly reduce, abuse and

waste. In the meantime, each community will decide for itself during the

transition period the method they deem best for the distribution of the

products of associated labor.

III

We must distinguish different types of industrial workers, just as we

distinguished different kinds of peasants. There are, first of all,

those crafts in which the tools are simple, where the division of labor

is almost nonexistent, and where the isolated worker could produce as

much alone as he would by associated labor. These include, for example,

tailors, shoemakers, barbers, upholsterers, and photographers. It must,

however, be remarked that even in these trades, large-scale mass

production can be applied to save time and labor. What we say,

therefore, applies primarily to the transitional period.

Next in order are the trades requiring the collective labor of numerous

workers using small hand-operated machinery and generally employed in

workshops and foundries, printing plants, woodworking plants,

brickworks, etc.

Finally, there is the third category of industries where the division of

labor is much greater, where production is on a massive scale

necessitating complicated and expensive machinery and the investment of

considerable capital; for example, textile mills, steel mills,

metallurgical plants, etc.

For workers operating within the first category of industry, collective

work is not a necessity; and in many cases the tailor or the cobbler may

prefer to work alone in his own small shop. It is quite natural that in

every commune there will be one or perhaps several workers employed in

each of these trades. Without, however, wishing to underestimate in any

way the importance of individual independence, we think that wherever

practical, collective labor is best; in a society of equals, emulation

stimulates the worker to produce more and heightens morale; further,

work in common permits each worker to learn from the experience and

skill of the others and this redounds to the benefit of the unit as a

whole.

As to the workers in the remaining two categories, it is evident that

collective labor is imposed by the very nature of the work and, since

the tools of labor are no longer simple individual tools but machines

that must be tended by many workers, the machines must also be

collectively owned.

Each workshop, each factory, will organize itself into an association of

workers who will be free to administer production and organize their

work as they think best, provided that the rights of each worker are

safeguarded and the principles of equality and justice are observed. In

the preceding chapter, while discussing the associations or communities

of agricultural workers, we dealt with management, hours of labor,

remuneration, and distribution of products. The same observations apply

also to industrial labor, and it is therefore unnecessary to repeat them

here. We have just said that particularly where an industry requires

complicated machinery and collective labor, the ownership of the

machinery of production should also be collective. But one point remains

to be clarified. Will these tools belong to all the workers in each

factory, or will they belong to the corporation comprising all the

workers in each particular industry? [Corporation here is equivalent to

industrial union.]

Our opinion is that the second of these alternatives is preferable.

When, for example, on the day of the Revolution, the typographical

workers of Rome take possession of all the print shops of Rome, they

will call a general meeting and proclaim that all the printing plants in

Rome are the property of the Roman printers. Since it will be entirely

possible and necessary, they will go a step further and unite in a pact

of solidarity with all the printing workers in every city of Italy. The

result of this pact will be the organization of all the printing plants

of Italy as the collective property of the typographical federation of

Italy. In this way the Italian printers will be able to work in any city

in their country and have full rights and full use of tools and

facilities.

But when we say that ownership of the tools of production, including the

factory itself, should revert to the corporation, we do not mean that

the workers in the individual workshops will be ruled by any kind of

industrial government having the power to do what it pleases with the

tools of production. No, the workers in the various factories have not

the slightest intention of handing over their hard-won control of the

tools of production to a superior power calling itself the

“corporation.” What they will do is, under certain specified conditions,

to guarantee reciprocal use of their tools of production and accord to

their fellow workers in other factories the right to share their

facilities, receiving in exchange the same right to share the facilities

of the fellow workers with whom they have contracted the pact of

solidarity.

IV

The commune consists of all the workers living in the same locality.

Disregarding very few exceptions, the typical commune can be defined as

the local federation of groups of producers. This local federation or

commune is organized to provide certain services which are not within

the exclusive jurisdiction or capacity of any particular corporation

[industrial union] but which concerns all of them, and which for this

reason are called public services. The communal public services can be

enumerated as follows:

A. Public works (housing and construction)

All houses are the property of the commune. The Revolution made,

everyone continues for the time being to live in the same quarters

occupied by him before the Revolution, except for families which had

been forced to live in very dilapidated or overcrowded dwellings. Such

families will be immediately relocated at the expense of the commune in

vacant apartments formerly occupied or owned by the rich.

The construction of new houses containing healthy, spacious rooms

replacing the miserable slums of the old ghettos will be one of the

first needs of the new society. The commune will immediately begin this

construction in a way that will not only furnish work for the

corporations of masons, carpenters, ironworkers, tilers, roofers, etc.,

but will also provide useful work for the mass of people who, having no

trade, lived in idleness before the revolution. They would be employed

as laborers in the immense construction and road-building an d paving

projects which will then be initiated everywhere, especially in the

cities.

The new housing will be constructed at the expense of the commune, which

means that in exchange for the work done by the various building

corporations these corporations will receive from the commune vouchers

enabling them to acquire all commodities necessary for the decent

maintenance and well-being of their members. And since the new housing

has been constructed at public expense, this system will enable and

require free housing to be available for all.

Free housing might well cause serious disputes because people living in

bad housing will compete with each other for the new accommodations. But

we think that it would be a mistake to fear serious friction, and for

the following reasons: First we must concede that the desire for new and

better housing is a legitimate and just demand; and this just demand

will stimulate the building workers to make even greater efforts to

speed construction of good housing.

But while awaiting new construction people will have to be patient and

do the best they can with the existing facilities. The commune will, as

we have said, attend to the most pressing needs of the poorest families,

relocating them in the vast palaces of the rich; and as to the rest of

the people, we believe that revolutionary enthusiasm will stimulate and

inspire them with the spirit of generosity and self-sacrifice, and that

they will be glad to endure for a little longer the discomforts of poor

housing; nor will they be inclined to quarrel with a neighbor who

happens to have gotten a new apartment a little sooner. In a reasonably

short time, thanks to the prodigious efforts of the building workers

powerfully stimulated by the demand for new housing, there will be

plenty of housing for all and everyone will be sure to find satisfactory

accommodations.

All this may seem fantastic to those whose vision goes no further than

the horizon of bourgeois society; these measures are, on the contrary,

so simple and practical that it will be humanly impossible for things to

go otherwise. Will the legions of masons and other building workers be

permanently and incessantly occupied with the construction of new

housing worthy of a civilized society? Will it take many years of

incessant labor to supply everyone with good housing? No, it will take a

short time. And when they will have finished the main work, will they

then fold their arms and do nothing? No, they will continue to work at a

slower pace, remodeling existing housing; and little by little the old

somber quarters, the crooked filthy streets, the miserable houses and

alleys that now infest our cities will disappear and be replaced by

mansions where the workers can live like human beings.

B. Exchange

In the new society there will no longer be communes in the sense that

this word is understood today, as mere political-geographical entities.

Every commune will establish a Bank of Exchange whose mechanics we will

explain as clearly as possible.

The workers’ association, as well as the individual producers (in the

remaining privately owned portions of production), will deposit their

unconsumed commodities in the facilities provided by the Bank of

Exchange, the value of the commodities having been established in

advance by a contractual agreement between the regional cooperative

federations and the various communes, who will also furnish statistics

to the Banks of Exchange. The Bank of Exchange will remit to the

producers negotiable vouchers representing the value of their products;

these vouchers will be accepted throughout the territory included in the

federation of communes.

Goods of prime necessity, i.e., those essential to life and health, will

be transported to the various communal markets which, pending new

construction, will use the old stores and warehouses of the former

merchants. Some of the markets will distribute foodstuffs, others

clothes, others household goods, etc.

Goods destined for export will remain in the general warehouses until

called for by the communes.

Among the commodities deposited in the facilities of the Bank of

Exchange will be goods for consumption by the commune itself, such as

food, lumber, clothes, etc., and goods to be exchanged for those

produced by other communes.

At this point we anticipate an objection. We will probably be asked:

“the Bank of Exchange in each commune will remit to the producers, by

means of vouchers, the value of their products, before being sure that

they are in demand; and if these products are not in demand, and pile up

unused, what will be the position of the Bank of Exchange? Will it not

risk losses, or even ruin, and in this kind of operation is there not

always the risk that the vouchers will be overdrawn?”

We reply that each Bank of Exchange makes sure in advance that these

products are in demand and, therefore, risks nothing by immediately

issuing payment vouchers to the producers.

There will be, of course, certain categories of workers engaged in the

construction or manufacture of immovable goods, goods which cannot be

transported to the repositories of the Bank of Exchange, for example,

buildings. In such cases the Bank of Exchange will serve as the

intermediary; the workers will register the property with the Bank of

Exchange. The value of the property will be agreed upon in advance. and

the bank will deliver this value in exchange vouchers. The same

procedure will be followed in dealing with the various workers employed

by the administrative services of the communes; their work resulting not

in manufactured products but in services rendered. These services will

have to be priced in advance, and the Bank of Exchange will pay their

value in vouchers.

The Bank of Exchange will not only receive products belonging to the

workers of the commune; it will correspond with other communes and

arrange to procure goods which the commune is obliged to get from

outside sources, such as certain foodstuffs, fuels, manufactured

products, etc. These outside products will be featured side by side with

local goods. The consumers will pay for the commodities in the various

markets with vouchers of different denominations, and all goods will be

uniformly priced.

It is evident from our description that the operations of the Bank of

Exchange do not differ essentially from the usual commercial procedures.

These operations are in effect nothing but buying and selling; the bank

buys from the producers and sells to the consumers. But we think that

after a certain length of time the functions of the Banks of Exchange

will be reduced without inconvenience and that a new system will

gradually replace the old system: exchange in the traditional sense will

give way to distribution, pure and simple. What do we mean by this?

As long as a product is in short supply it will to a certain extent have

to be rationed. And the easiest way to do this would be to sell these

scarce products at a price so high that only people who really need them

would be willing to buy them. But when the prodigious growth of

production, which will not fail to take place when work is rationally

organized, produces an oversupply of this or that product, it will not

be necessary to ration consumption. The practice of selling, which was

adopted as a sort of deterrent to immoderate consumption, will be

abolished; the communal banks will no longer sell commodities, they will

distribute them in accordance with the needs of the consumers.

The replacement of exchange by distribution will first, and in a

comparatively short time, be applied to articles of prime necessity, for

the workers will concentrate all their efforts to produce these

necessities in abundance. Other commodities, formerly scarce and today

considered luxuries, will in a reasonable length of time be produced in

great quantity and will no longer be rationed. On the other hand, rare

and useless baubles, such as pearls, diamonds, certain precious metals,

etc., will cease to have the value attributed to them by public opinion

and will be used for research by scientific associations, as components

of certain tools, e.g., industrial diamonds, or displayed as curios in

museums of natural history.

C. Food Supply

The question of food supply is a sort of postscript to our discussion of

exchange. What we said about the organization of the Bank of Exchange

applies in general to all products, including foodstuffs. However, we

think it useful to add in a special section a more detailed account of

the measures dealing with distribution of the principal food products.

At present the bakeshops, meat stores, wine and liquor shops, imported

food stores, etc., are all surrendered to private industry and to

speculators and these, by all kinds of fraud, enrich themselves at the

expense of the consumers. The new society must immediately try to

correct this situation by placing under communal public service the

distribution of all the most essential foodstuffs.

This must be borne in mind: we do not mean to imply that the commune

will take possession of certain branches of production. No. Production

in the true sense of the term will remain in the hands of the

associations of producers. But, for example, what is involved in the

production of bread? Nothing beyond the growing of wheat. The farmer

sows and reaps the grain and transports it to the warehouses of the Bank

of Exchange; his function as producer ends at this point. Grinding grain

into flour or changing flour into bread is not production; it is work

similar to that performed by various employees in the communal markets,

work designed to put a food product, bread, at the disposal of the

consumer. The same goes for meat, etc.

Thus viewed, it is only logical that the processing and distribution of

foodstuffs — baking, slaughtering, winemaking, etc. — should be

performed by the commune. Thus, wheat from the warehouses of the commune

will be ground into flour in the communal flour mill (which will be

shared with several communes); the flour will be transformed into bread

in the communal bakeries and delivered to the consumers in the communal

markets. It will be the same for meats: the animals will be slaughtered

in the communal slaughterhouse and cut up in the communal butcher shops.

Wines will be preserved in the communal wine cellars and bottled and

distributed by special employees. Finally, all the other perishable food

commodities will be kept fresh in communal warehouses and kept in glass

enclosures in the communal markets.

Above all, immediate efforts must be made to institute the free

distribution of certain essential foods, such as bread, meat, wine,

dairy products, etc. When abundant food is available and free for all,

civilization in general will have taken a giant step forward.

D. Statistics

The main function of the Communal Statistical Commission will be to

gather and classify all statistical information pertaining to the

commune. The various corporations or associations of production will

constantly keep up-to-date records of membership and changes in

personnel so that it will be possible to know instantly the number of

employees in the various branches of production.

The Bank of Exchange will provide the Statistical Commission with the

most complete figures and all other relevant facts on the production and

consumption of goods. By means of statistics gathered from all the

communes in a region, it will be possible to scientifically balance

production and consumption. In line with these statistics, it will also

be possible to add more help in industries where production is

insufficient and reduce the number of men where there is a surplus of

production. Statistics will also make it easy to fit working hours to

the productive needs of society. It will be equally possible to

estimate, not perfectly, but enough for practical purposes, the relative

value of the labor time involved in the various products, which will

serve as the criteria for the prices of the Banks of Exchange.

But this is not all. The Statistical Commission will be able to perform

some of the functions that are today exercised by the civil state, for

example, recording births and deaths. We do not include marriage because

in a free society, the voluntary union of a man and a woman will no

longer be an official but a purely personal matter, not subject to, or

requiring, public sanction.

There are many other uses for statistics: in relation to diseases,

weather phenomena, in short, all facts which regularly gathered and

classified can serve as a guide to the development of science and

learning in general.

E. Hygiene

Under the general heading Hygiene, we have assembled the various public

services which are indispensable to the maintenance of public health.

First, of course, are medical services, which will be free of charge to

all the inhabitants of the commune. The doctors will not be like

capitalists, trying to extract the greatest possible profits from their

unfortunate patients. They will be employed by the commune and expected

to treat all who need their services. But medical treatment is only the

curative side of the science of health care; it is not enough to treat

the sick, it is also necessary to prevent disease. This is the true

function of hygiene....

F. Security

This service embraces the necessary measures to guarantee to all

inhabitants of the commune the security of their person and the

protection of their homes, their possessions, etc., against deprivation

and accident (fire, floods, etc.).

There will probably be very little brigandage and robbery in a society

where each lives in full freedom to enjoy the fruits of his labor and

where almost all his needs will be abundantly fulfilled. Material

well-being, as well as the intellectual and moral progress which are the

products of a truly humane education, available to all, will almost

eliminate crimes due to perversion, brutality, and other infirmities. It

will nevertheless still he necessary to take precautions for the

security of persons. This service, which can be called (if the phrase

has not too bad a connotation) the Communal Police, will not be

entrusted, as it is today, to a special, official body; all able-bodied

inhabitants will be called upon to take turns in the security measures

instituted by the commune.

It will doubtless be asked how those committing murder and other violent

crimes will be treated in the new equalization society. Obviously

society cannot, on the pretext of respect for individual rights — and

the negation of authority, permit a murderer to run loose, or wait for a

friend of the victim to avenge him. The murderer will have to be

deprived of his liberty and confined to a special house until he can

without danger be returned to society. How is the criminal to be treated

during his confinement? And according to what principles should his term

be fixed? These are delicate questions on which opinions vary widely. We

must learn from experience, but this much we already know: that thanks

to the beneficent effects of education (see below) crimes will he rare.

Criminals being an exception, they will be treated like the sick and the

deranged; the problem of crime which today gives so many jobs to judges,

jailers, and police will lose its social importance and become simply a

chapter in medical history.

G. Education

The first point to be considered is the question of child support (food,

clothes, toys, etc.). Today parents not only support their children but

also supervise their education. This is a custom based on a false

principle, a principle that regards the child as the personal property

of the parents. The child belongs to no one, he belongs only to himself;

and during the period when he is unable to protect himself and is

thereby exposed to exploitation, it is society that must protect him and

guarantee his free development. It is also society that must support him

and supervise his education. In supporting him and paying for his

education, society is only making an advance “loan” which the child will

repay when he becomes an adult producer.

It is society and not the parents who will be responsible for the upkeep

of the child. This principle once established, we believe that we should

abstain from specifying the exact manner in which this principle should

be applied: to do otherwise would risk trying to achieve a Utopia.

Therefore the application must be left to free experimentation and we

must await the lessons of practical experience. We say only that

vis-Ă -vis the child, society is represented by the commune, and that

each commune will have to determine what would be best for the

upbringing of the child; here they would have life in common, there they

would leave children in care of the mother, at least up to a certain

age, etc.

But this is only one aspect of the problem. The commune feeds, clothes,

and lodges the children, but who will teach them, who will develop their

best characteristics and train them as producers? According to what plan

and principles will their education be conducted?

To these questions we reply: the education of children must be

integrated; that is, it must at the same time develop both the physical

and mental faculties and make the child into a whole man. This education

must not be entrusted solely to a specialized caste of teachers; all

those who know a science, an art, or a craft can and should be called

upon to teach.

We must distinguish two stages in the education of children: the first

stage, where the child of five or six is not yet old enough to study

science, and where the emphasis is on the development of the physical

faculties; and a second stage, where children twelve to sixteen years of

age would be introduced to the various divisions of human knowledge

while at the same time learning one or more crafts or trades through

practice.

The first stage, as just mentioned, will be devoted to development of

the physical faculties, to strengthening the body and exercising the

senses. Today the powers of hearing, seeing, and manual dexterity are

incompletely and haphazardly developed: a rational education, on the

contrary, will by special systematic exercises develop these faculties

to the highest possible degree. And as to hands, instead of making

children only right-handed, attempts will be made to render children

equally proficient in the use of the left hand.

And while the senses are developed and bodily vigor is enhanced by

intelligent gymnastic exercises, the culture of the mind will begin, but

in a spontaneous manner; the child win naturally and unconsciously

absorb a store of scientific knowledge. Personal observation, practical

experience, conversations between children, or with persons charged with

teaching — these will be the only form of instruction children will

receive during this first period.

No longer will there be schools, arbitrarily governed by a pedagogue,

where the children wait impatiently for the moment of their deliverance

when they can enjoy a little freedom outside.

In their gatherings the children will be entirely free. They will

organize their own games, their talks, systematize their own work,

arbitrate disputes, etc. They will then easily become accustomed to

public life, to responsibility, to mutual trust and aid. The teacher

whom they have themselves chosen to give them lessons will no longer be

a detested tyrant but a friend to whom they will listen with pleasure.

During the second stage, the children, being ages twelve to sixteen,

will successively study in a methodical manner the principal branches of

human knowledge. They will not be taught by professional teachers but by

lay teachers of this or that science, who are also part-time manual

workers; and each branch of knowledge will be taught not by one but by

many men, all from the commune, who have both the knowledge and the

desire to teach. In addition, good books on the subject studied will be

read together, and intelligent discussion will follow, thereby lessening

the importance attached to the personality of the teacher.

While the child is developing his body and learning the sciences, he

will begin apprenticeship as a producer. In the first stage of his

education, the need to repair or modify toys will introduce the child to

the use of simple tools. During the second stage, he will visit

different factories and, stimulated by his liking for one or more

trades, will soon finally choose the trade in which he will specialize.

The apprentices will be taught by men who are themselves working in the

factories, and this practical education will be supplemented by lessons

dealing with theory.

In this way, by the time a young man reaches the age of sixteen or

seventeen he will have been introduced to the range of human knowledge,

learned a trade, and chosen the discipline he likes best. Thus he will

be in a position to reimburse society for the expenses involved in his

education, not in money but by useful work and respect for the rights of

his fellow human beings.

In conclusion, we should make a few remarks on the relationship between

the child and his family. There arc people who assert that the program

of placing the child in the custody of society means “the destruction of

the family.” This doctrine is devoid of sense. As long as the

concurrence of two individuals of different sexes is necessary for

procreation, as long as there are fathers and mothers, the natural

connection between the parents and the child can never be obliterated by

social relations.

Only the character of this connection will be modified. In antiquity the

father was the absolute master of the child. He had the power of life

and death over him. In modern times paternal authority has been subject

to certain restrictions. What, then, could be more natural, than that a

free egalitarian society should obliterate what still remains of this

authority and replace it with relations of simple affection?

We do not claim that the child should be treated as an adult, that all

his caprices should be respected, that when his childish will stubbornly

flouts the elementary rules of science and common sense we should avoid

making him feel that he is wrong. We say, on the contrary, that the

child must be trained and guided, but that the direction of his first

years must not be exclusively exercised by his parents, who are all too

often incompetent and who generally abuse their authority. The aim of

education is to develop the latent capacities of the child to the

fullest possible extent and enable him to take care of himself as

quickly as possible. It is painfully evident that authoritarianism is

incompatible with an enlightened system of education. If the relations

of father to son are no longer those of master to slave but those of

teacher to student, of an older to a much younger friend, do you think

that the reciprocal affection of parents and children would thereby be

impaired? On the contrary, when intimate relations of these sorts cease,

do not the discords so characteristic of modern families begin? Is not

the family disintegrating into bitter frictions largely because of the

tyranny exercised by parents over their children?

No one can therefore justly claim that a free and regenerated society

will destroy the family. In such a society the father, the mother, and

the children will learn to love each other and to respect their mutual

rights; at the same time their love will be enriched as it transcends

the narrow limits of family affection, thereby achieving a wider and

nobler love: the love of the great human family.

V

Social organization cannot be restricted to the local commune or the

local federation of producers’ groups. We will see how social

organization is expanded and completed, on the one hand by the

establishment of regional corporative federations comprising all the

groups of workers in the same industry; and on the other by the

establishment of a federation of communes.

We have already indicated in Section III what a corporative federation

is. Such organizations in a rudimentary form exist in present society.

All workers in a given trade or craft belong to the same organization,

for example, the federation of typographical workers. But these

organizations are a very crude sketch of what they will become in the

new society. The corporative federations will unite all workers in the

same industry; they will no longer unite to protect their wages and

working conditions against the onslaughts of their employers, but

primarily to guarantee the mutual use of the tools of production which

are the property of each of these groups and which will by a reciprocal

contract become the collective property of the whole corporative

federation. In this way, the federation of groups will be able to

exercise constant control over production, and regulate the rate of

production to meet the fluctuating consumer needs of society.

The corporative federation will operate in a very simple fashion. On the

morrow of the revolution, the producers’ groups [local unions] belonging

to the same industry will find it necessary to send delegates from city

to city to exchange information and learn from each other’s experience.

These partial conferences will prepare the way for a general congress of

the corporative federation to be held at some central point. This

congress will formulate a federative contract which will be submitted

for the correction and approval of all the groups of the corporative

federation. A permanent bureau, elected by the congress and responsible

to it, will serve as the intermediary link between the groups of the

federation and between the federation and all the other corporative

federations.

When all the branches [industries], including the agricultural

organizations, have been organized in this manner, they will constitute

a vast federative network spanning the whole country and embracing all

the producers, and therefore all the consumers. The statistics of

production, coordinated by the statistical bureaus of every corporative

federation, will permit the determination in a rational manner of the

hours of labor, the cost price of products and their exchange value, and

the quantities in which these products should be produced to meet the

needs of the consumers.

People impressed by the hollow declamations of the so-called democrats

will perhaps demand that all these details should be settled by a direct

vote of all the members of the corporative federations. And when we

reply in the negative they will accuse us of despotism; they will

protest against what they consider to be the authority of the bureaus,

arguing that the bureaus should not be invested with the exclusive power

to deal with such grave problems and to make decisions of the greatest

importance. Our answer will be that the tasks performed by the permanent

bureaus do not involve the exercise of any authority whatsoever. They

concern only the gathering and classification of information furnished

by the producers’ groups. Once this information is combined and made

public, it will be used to help fix prices and costs, the hours of

labor, etc.

Such operations involve simple mathematical calculations which can yield

only one correct result, verifiable by all who have access to the

figures. The permanent bureau is simply charged to ascertain and make

the facts known to everyone. Even now, for example, the postal service

performs a somewhat similar service to that which the bureaus of the

corporative federations will render in the future; and we know of no

person who complains that the post office abuses its authority because

it collects, classifies, and delivers the mail without submitting every

operation to universal suffrage.

Furthermore, the producers’ groups forming the federation will intervene

in the acts of the bureau in a far more effective and direct manner than

simply by voting. For it is they who will furnish all the information

and supply the statistics, which the bureau only coordinates. The bureau

is merely the passive intermediary through which the groups communicate

and publicly ascertain the results of their own activities. The vote is

a device for settling questions which cannot be resolved by means of

scientific data, problems which must be left to the arbitrary decision

of numbers. But in questions susceptible to a precise scientific

solution there is no need to vote. The truth cannot be decided by vote;

it verifies and imposes itself by the mighty power of its own evidence.

But we have only dealt with one half of the extracommunal organization;

the federative corporations will be paralleled by the establishment of

the Federation of Communes.

VI

The revolution cannot be confined to a single country: it is obliged

under pain of annihilation to spread, if not to the whole world, at

least to a considerable number of civilized countries. In fact, no

country today can be self-sufficient; international links and

transactions are necessary for production and cannot be cut off. If a

revolutionary country is blockaded by neighboring states the Revolution,

remaining isolated, would be doomed. just as we base ourselves on the

hypothesis of the triumph of the Revolution in a given country, we must

also assume that most other European countries will make their

revolutions at the same time.

In countries where the proletariat has managed to free itself from the

domination of the bourgeoisie, the newly initiated social organizations

do not have to conform to a set pattern and may differ in many respects.

To this day there are many disagreements between the socialists of the

Germanic nations (Germany and England) and those of the Latin and Slavic

countries (Italy, Spain, France, and Russia). Hence, it is probable that

the social organization adopted by the German revolutionists, for

example, will differ on some or many points from what is introduced by

the Italian or French revolutionaries. But these differences are not

important insofar as international relations are concerned; the

fundamental principles of the Revolution (see Sections I and II above)

being the same, friendly relations and solidarity will no doubt he

established between the emancipated peoples of the various countries.

It goes without saying that artificial frontiers created by the present

governments will be swept away by the Revolution. The communes will

freely unite and organize themselves in accordance with their economic

interests, their language affinities, and their geographic

circumstances. And in certain countries like Italy and Spain, too vast

for a single agglomeration of communes and divided by nature into many

distinct regions, there will probably be established not one but many

federations of communes. This will not be a rupture of unity, a return

to the old fragmentation of petty, isolated, and warring political

states. These diverse federations of communes, while maintaining their

identity, will not be isolated. United by their intertwining interests,

they will conclude a pact of solidarity, and this voluntary unity

founded on common aims and common needs, on a constant exchange of

informal, friendly contacts, will be much more intimate and much

stronger than the artificial political centralization imposed by

violence and having no other motive than the exploitation of peoples for

the profit of privileged classes.