💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › sylvia-pankhurst-communism-and-its-tactics.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 14:08:26. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Communism and its Tactics
Author: Sylvia Pankhurst
Language: en
Topics: Soviets, Council Communism, industrial revolution
Source: Retrieved on Nov. 17, 2021 from https://www.marxists.org/archive/pankhurst-sylvia/communism-tactics/index.htm
Notes: Two versions of Communism and its Tactics were serialised in Workers Dreadnought, the first between November 1921 and March 1922, the second – evidently left unfinished – between January and March 1923. The first parts of each were essentially identical, however the other parts were substantially re-written for the 1923 serialisation. The version copied here is the original 1921/22 version.

Sylvia Pankhurst

Communism and its Tactics

Part One: Workers Dreadnought, November 26th, 1921

Under Communism all shall satisfy their material needs without stint or

measure from the common storehouse, according to their desires. Everyone

will be able to have what he or she desires in food, in clothing, books,

music, education and travel facilities. The abundant production now

possible, and which invention will constantly facilitate, will remove

any need for rationing or limiting of consumption.

Every individual, relying on the great common production, will be secure

from material want and anxiety.

There will be no class distinctions, since these arise from differences

in material possessions, education and social status — all such

distinctions will be swept away.

There will be neither rich nor poor. Money will no longer exist, and

none will desire to hoard commodities not in use, since a fresh supply

may be obtained at will. There will be no selling, because there will be

no buyers, since everyone will be able to obtain everything at will,

without payment.

The possession of private property, beyond that which is in actual

personal use, will disappear.

There will be neither masters nor servants, all being in a position of

economic equality — no individual will be able to become the employer of

another.

All children will be educated up to adult age, and all adults will be

able to make free, unstinted use of all educational facilities in their

abundant leisure.

Stealing, forgery, burglary, and all economic crimes will disappear,

with all the objectionable apparatus for preventing, detecting and

punishing them.

Prostitution will become extinct; it is a commercial transaction,

dependent upon the economic need of the prostitute and the customer’s

power to pay.

Sexual union will no longer be based upon material conditions, but will

be freely contracted on the basis of affection and mutual attraction.

The birth of children will cease to be prevented by reason of poverty.

Material anxiety being removed, and the race for wealth eliminated,

other objects and ambitions will take the place of the personal struggle

for individual material existence; since all will benefit from the

labour of all honour will be done, not to the wealthy, as at present,

but to those who are skilful and zealous in the common service.

Emulation in work will take the place of emulation in wealth.

With the disappearance of the anxious struggle for existence, which saps

the energy and cripples initiative, a new vigour, a new independence

will develop. People will have more courage to desire freedom, greater

determination to possess it. They will be more exacting in their demands

upon life, more fastidious as to their choice of a vocation. They will

wish to work at what they enjoy, to order their lives as they desire.

Work will be generally enjoyed as never before in the history of

mankind.

The desire for freedom will be tempered by the sense of responsibility

towards the commonweal, which will provide security for all.

Public opinion provides a stronger, more general compulsion than any

penal code, and public opinion will strongly disapprove idleness and

waste.

To secure the abundant production necessary to Communism, and to cope

with the ever-growing complexity of modern life and requirements,

large-scale production and co-operative effort is necessary. The people

of today would not be willing to go back to producing everything by hand

in domestic workshops; were they to do so, they could not maintain the

population in comfort and with reasonable leisure. The people of today

would be unwilling to abandon all the productive factories, the trains,

the electric generating stations and so on. The retention of such things

necessitates the working-together of large numbers of people. As soon as

numbers of people are working together and supplying with their products

numbers of other people, some sort of organisation of work and of

distribution becomes inevitable. The work itself cannot be carried on

without organisation. In each industry, either the workers concerned in

the work must form and control the organisation, or they will be under

the dominion of the organisers. The various industries are interlocked

in interest and utility; therefore the industrial organisations must be

interlocked.

When wages have disappeared, when all are upon a basis of economic

equality, when the position of manager, director, organiser, etc.,

brings no material advantage, the desire for it will be less widespread

and less keen, and the danger of oppressive action by the management

will be largely nullified. Nevertheless, management imposed on unwilling

subordinates will not be tolerated; where the organiser has chosen the

assistants, the assistants will be free to leave, or change him; where

the assistants choose the organiser, they will be free to change him.

Co-operation for the common good is necessary, but freedom, not

domination, is the goal.

Since co-operative work and mutual reliance on mutual aid renders some

kind of organisation necessary, the best possible form of organisation

must be chosen: the test of its worth is its efficiency and the scope

for freedom and initiative it allows to each of its units.

The Soviet structure of committees and delegates, built up from the base

of the workshop and village assembly, presents the best form of

organisation yet evolved; it arises naturally when the workers are

thrown upon their own resources in the matter of government.

The Soviet structure will undoubtedly be the organisational structure of

Communism, at any rate for some time to come. We live always, however,

in a state of flux, and there is and happily can be, no permanence about

human institutions; there is always the possibility of something higher,

as yet undiscovered.

The overthrow of Capitalism precedent to the establishment of Communism

will be resisted by the possessors of wealth. Thus Capitalism will only

be overthrown by revolution.

The revolution can only come when conditions are ripe for it; but

opportunities may be missed: the rising may fail to take place at the

opportune moment, or it may fail by mismanagement of the proletarian

forces. A partial success may be achieved, and if Capitalism is not

completely destroyed, it may afterwards re-establish itself, as it

speedily did in Hungary, as it is gradually doing in Russia.

Part Two: Workers Dreadnought, December 3rd 1921

Since the overthrow of capitalism would be resisted by the possessors of

wealth, whether this were effected by Act of Parliament or by a sudden

revolt of the people, it is absolutely necessary for the Communists to

prepare the working class for such resistance. Many people still doubt

that capitalist resistance to the overthrow of capitalism will go to the

length of civil war, yet there is abundant contemporary evidence to

prove that such resistance will be made.

Here in Britain we have the Ulster capitalists’ preparations for armed

resistance to the Asquith Home Rule Act. The civil war threats and

preparations by Ulster Capitalism were and are supported by British

Toryism. That is why it succeeds. Since British and Ulster landlords and

capitalists have thought it worthwhile to resort to the extreme of civil

war on the Irish question how absolutely certain it is that they would

do so to prevent the establishment of Communism and proletarian rule!

In Finland, in Central Europe, in Russia, the same thing has been seen;

when capitalism is in danger capitalism resorts to force of arms to

protect itself. In Italy too, the fascisti, with their armed attacks on

Communists, Socialists, Trade Unionists, and Co-operators; attacks

organised by the Capitalists who use these disorderly bands as their

tools, are but another evidence of the same fact: when the established

order is in danger its beneficiaries arm to protect it; its supporters

and opponents come to blows, civil war breaks out and for the time being

peace is no more.

Is that as it should be? It is as it is. The inevitable must be

recognised and prepared for. A determined struggle for supremacy

inevitably accompanies the overthrow of capitalism.

Experience shows that the crisis arises suddenly: the old relationship

has been growing more and more strained, and suddenly the bonds are

snapped and the storm bursts. We do not say that a Parliamentary crisis

could not be the last straw that would precipitate the revolution, but

in none of the contemporary revolutions has this been so. We have now

the experience of Russia, Finland, Germany (where there have been a

revolution and several attempts at further revolution), in Austria and

Hungary to look to.

Great economic pressure, fired by a great rebellion against the actions

and ideology of those who have been in power, is the factor which

produces the proletarian revolution. Parliament must be overthrown with

the capitalist system if the proletarian revolution is to succeed there

must be a clean break with the old institutions of Government; the

revolution must create its own instrument.

Parliament would have to be sacrificed with the overthrow of capitalism,

even were it conceivable that an Act of Parliament will formally abolish

the capitalist system. The capitalists would resist by force the first

attempt to put the Act into practice, and Parliament is not the body

that could carry the proletarian revolution through to success in face

of capitalist revolt, which would be one of both armed and passive

resistance.

The workers would be compelled to meet such a revolt with all the forces

at their disposal; their most characteristic weapon is their industrial

power, for the effective wielding of which they would have to be

co-ordinated industrially. Every industry would be divided against

itself; the owners and part of the management would take the capitalist

side, the mass of the workers the side of the working class. As in all

the countries where the revolutionary crisis has appeared, the naval and

military forces would be divided in the same way, though the old

training and discipline would probably cause a larger proportion of the

working class rank-and-file to support the side of the master class than

would be the case in industry.

A little consideration of such a situation must reveal to anyone who

thinks seriously that Parliament and the local governing bodies; the

county and borough councils, the boards of guardians, and so on, could

not be the guiding and co-ordinating machinery of such a struggle; that

such machinery could take no other form than that of the Soviets.

Even in a war between rival capitalist governments Parliament becomes a

cipher in the struggle; the machinery that carries out the war is the

Cabinet composed of the heads of the various Departments of State, all

very much controlled by the expert managers of those departments. On the

military side the political and military heads of the War Office work in

contact with a machine which is composed of all the officers from the

highest to the lowest in the army, and the men under their command. On

the industrial side the political and technical heads of the departments

work through a machine which is composed of the owners, managers and

workers in all industries, factories, workshops.

So it will be in the proletarian revolution, but this being a struggle

between the workers and their masters, the officers and the managers

will be proletarian leaders chosen by their fellows. And contact with

the rank and file will be by delegates and mass meetings. The services

of the rank [and] file will not be based on compulsion and wagery, but

on consent and enthusiasm and a voice in responsibility for aims and

policies.

War experience will show us that even capitalism found that shop

stewards and councils on which Trade Union officials co-operated with

the management were helpful in securing greater output, which was

necessary to their success in war.

Some people may say that the Soviets could be abandoned and Parliament

reverted to after the clash of civil war had passed; and that, as they

hope there may be no such clash, they will not interest themselves in

the question of Soviets. Further consideration should show them,

however, that even were hope of avoiding a struggle with capitalism

justified, Parliament would have to go and the Soviets would become

necessary at least for some time after the overthrow of capitalism.

Consider the position here in London with capitalism abolished; the

tubes, trams and buses, the main line stations, the docks, the

reservoirs, the gas works, the electric generating stations, the

bakeries, food preserving, clothing and other factories, the

slaughter-houses, butchers, bakers, greengrocers, grocers and other

wholesale and retail shops and the markets. Millions of people are

waiting for their daily supply of milk and bread to be brought round to

them, to find their daily supply of provender in the shops where they

deal, their habitual means of transport. If any of these things stop,

then at least some people will not arrive at their daily work, and

masses of others may thus be deprived of accustomed necessaries. Perhaps

the workers are already engaged in a general strike; perhaps the wheels

of industry and transport are already dislocated, and everyone is

already living a hungry, makeshift existence.

Whichever way it be, everything has to be reorganised and built up on a

new basis; production for use, not for profit, and capitalism is

overthrown. Undoubtedly some of those who used to manage the big

concerns under the old system have refused to function any more;

undoubtedly many others can not be trusted to occupy such important

positions of trust; already they have shown their hostility and have

taken to sabotage. And there are the people, the hungering millions of

all sorts, clamouring to have their wants supplied, each with their

peculiarities, their likes and dislikes, their reasonable and

unreasonable prejudices, and crowds of them ready to start looting if

they are kept waiting or denied what they are accustomed to have and

what they think is their due. Everyone, both as worker and consumer, has

new hopes and desires and new claims upon life, for has not the Workers’

Revolution come? Everyone demands more leisure and more congenial

labour, more food, more clothes, more pleasure; only the patient people

are prepared to wait, and everyone is finding his daily work, assuming

he is prepared to do it as of old, quite dislocated. Everyone, too, is

demanding a new independent status, and a share in deciding how things

shall be done.

Imagine bringing unfortunate Parliament into such a dilemma. Frank

Hodges and T.C. Cramp besieged by a mob of Westminster housewives who

cannot obtain either fish or butter. Will Thorne, who is told the

electricity supply is cut off in all the suburbs. Ramsay Macdonald, some

of whose constituents are tramping to London to tell him that Leicester

can get no coal.

The only chance for that Parliament would be to call the Industrial

Soviets into being!

As to the borough councils: we remember the little matter of the food

rationing, and the groups of housewives here and there who, through the

muddles of the local food committee and the Ministry of Food, found

themselves as “outlanders” prohibited from buying at the shops where

they had hitherto dealt, and unable to procure commodities anywhere

else.

The only people who could deal with the great new situation would be the

people who do the work and the people who use the produce. All

interlocked as they are in this busy hive of overcrowded life the

Soviets would be the only solution. The workers in the factory in a

turmoil of dislocation would come together and talk the matter over;

appoint one of their number to answer the telephone, another to fetch

supplies; others to take stock; others, according to their capacities,

to mind the various machines, others to acquaint the absentees that the

factory is at work again, others as organisers and instructors. They

would send to the workers in other factories for more supplies and

organise exchanges.

The women rushing frantically about in search of supplies, and

threatening to start looting and rioting because their children are

hungry, would be called together by the more level-headed, would

enumerate their wants and place their demands before the workers

responsible for production and transport.

Part Three: Workers Dreadnought, December 10 1921

In Russia all this was done, and over vast districts, under the spur of

need without preliminary thought or organisation.

In this country the workers cannot leave things to chance. Capitalism is

highly organised here and will defeat the workers’ revolution again and

again, unless the workers are organised efficiently. Moreover, in London

and in the vast chains of towns which form our industrial districts we

are so closely massed on the ground, so absolutely dependent on food

brought in from outside, and upon the collective service of the whole

industrial community, that unless production and distribution is well

organised we must speedily starve.

It will go hard with us if we have not created the machinery before the

hour of revolution strikes.

The machinery of the Soviets must obviously follow, and does so far as

it is successful, the lines of need. Each workshop has its meetings and

elects its delegates to a factory committee. The factory will also have

its mass meetings of all workers on occasion. Every factory will be

united to the factories of the same industry in the district through its

committee of delegates, and in the same way will be co-ordinated with

every factory in the same industry in the country. These are the bodies

which will meet and discuss what concerns the industry, but for matters

which concern the district in which the workers live and work they will

go to mass meetings or send delegates to committees from all the

industries in the district. The housekeepers will have their own

meetings also, and they, too, will go to mass meetings or send delegates

to the producing industries when arrangements are to be made between

them.

All this will be done purely by way of managing affairs so that all may

be, as far as possible, satisfied that the needs of all may be explained

and understood by those who have to supply them.

But there should be no compulsion; some people may say: “What the

majority decide is good enough for me.” Others will say: “I like to have

a voice in it.” As a rule, when things affecting a group of people who

are working together come up for decision everyone of the group will

join in and give his or her opinion, and generally the thing will be

decided by mutual agreement.

The Dictatorship of the Proletariat

The dictatorship of the proletariat is a much misused phrase; when

Communism is in being there will be no proletariat, as we understand the

term today, and no dictatorship.

The dictatorship, so far as it is genuine and defensible, is the

suppression by Workers’ Soviets of capitalism and the attempt to

re-establish it. This should be a temporary state of war. Such a period

will inevitably occur, we believe, because we do not believe that the

possessors of wealth will submit to the overthrow of capitalism without

resistance. On the contrary, [we] believe the owners will fight to

preserve capitalism by every means in their power.

Whilst the capitalists are openly fighting the workers who have seized

the power, fighting them openly and secretly in armed battalions in

guerilla bands, by ambush assasination bombs, sabotage, spies; then the

proletariat must maintain a vigilant war service and dictatorship. The

situation in Ireland before the truce is a little like what a

proletarian dictatorship may have to cope with.

Once, however, the war is over, once the capitalist and his allies have

given up any serious attempt to re-establish capitalism, then away with

dictatorship; away with compulsion.

Compulsion of any kind is repugnant to the Communist ideal. No-one may

make a wage-slave of another; no-one may hoard up goods for himself that

he does not require and cannot use; but the only way to prevent such

practices is not by making them punishable; it is by creating a society

in which no-one needs to become a wage slave, and no-one cares to be

cumbered with a private hoard of goods when all that he needs is readily

supplied as he needs it from the common storehouse.

Compulsory education for children has been a protection for children in

this capitalist society when parents are poor and grasping enough to

desire the earnings of their children or to suffer from the burden of

their maintenance, but when all things that nature and mankind produce

are free in abundance for the asking what parents would deny education

to their children; what children would submit with the school-door

freely open?

Part Four: Workers Dreadnought, December 24th 1921 and January 21st

1922

We have seen that the Soviets are destined both to provide the

organisational machinery of Communist society and to act as the

instrument of the proletarian dictatorship during the transitional

period in which, whilst capitalism has been overthrown, the dispossessed

owners have not yet settled down to accept the new order. The Soviets

may also conduct the fight for the actual overthrow of Capitalism,

though in Russia the power was actually seized by the Bolshevik Party;

then handed to the Soviets.

Let us consider the essential structure of the Soviet, its particular

characteristic, wherein lies its special fitness to function as the

administrative machinery of the Communist community.

The Soviet is constructed along the lines of production and

distribution; it replaces not merely Parliament and the present local

governing bodies, but also the capitalists, managerial staffs and

employees of today with all their ramifications. The functional units of

the Soviets are the groups of workers of all grades, including those

engaged in management in the factory, the dockyard, the mine, the farm,

the warehouse, the office, the distributive store, the school, the

hospital, the printing shop, the laundry, the restaurant, and the

domestic workers in the communal household, the street or block of

dwellings.

The generally accepted theoretical structure of the Soviet community is

as follows:

Industrial Co-ordination

The Workshop Committee: comprising all the workers in the shop.

The Factory Committee: comprising delegates from the Workshop

Committees.

The District Committee: comprising delegates from the factory or

sub-district committees of the workers in the industry, and from

district committees of distributive workers engaged in distributing the

products of the industry.

The National Committee: composed of delegates from district committees.

Inter-industrial Co-ordination

District and Sub-District Committees: Delegates from district or sub

district committees of industries (including factories, docks, farms,

laundries, restaurants, centres of distribution, schools, domestic

workers, parks, theatres, etc., workers in all branches of social

activity being represented).

National Committee: comprising delegates of district committees of all

industries and works of social activity.

Thus there is a dual machinery: 1. For the organisation and

co-ordination of each industry and social activity; 2. for the linking

together of all industries and social activities.

The network of committees of delegates which makes up the framework of

the Soviets and links the many productive groups, and also individual

producers should not be regarded as a rigid, cast-iron machinery, but as

a convenient means of transacting necessary business, a practical method

of inter-organisation which gives everyone the opportunity of a voice in

social management. The members of a community are dependent upon each

other. The cotton spinning mill is operated by a number of groups of

workers practising various crafts. The workers in the spinning mill are

dependent for the execution of their work on the cotton growers, the

railwaymen, the mariners, and the dockers, who provide them with the raw

material of their trade. They are dependent on machine makers, miners,

electricians and others for the machinery of spinning and the power to

run it, and on the weaver, the bleacher, the dyer, the printer, the

garment worker and upholsterer to complete the work they have begun. In

order that the spinners may do their work they are also dependent on

builders, decorators, furniture makers, food producers, garment makers,

and innumerable others whose labours are necessary to maintain them in

health and efficiency.

At present it is the employer who directs, the merchant who co-ordinates

and distributes social production. When capitalism is destroyed another

medium of direction, co-ordination and distribution must be discovered,

the productive processes must not fall into chaos. The Soviets will

supply the necessary medium of co-ordination and direction; but they

must become a medium of convenience, not of compulsion; otherwise there

can be no genuine Communism.

In Russia the Soviet constitution has only been very partially applied,

and has not been theoretically regular in structure, and is still

constantly subject to large modifications.

The Russian Soviets had not been created in advance in preparation for

the revolution of March, 1917: they sprang into life in the time of

crisis. They had arisen in the revolution of 1905, but had died away at

its fall. The March, 1917, revolution only created Soviets in a few

centres, and though their number grew and was added to by the November

Bolshevik revolution, even yet the network of Soviets is incomplete.

Kameneff, reporting on this question to the seventh all-Russian Congress

of Soviets in 1920, stated that even where Soviets existed their general

assemblies were often rare, and when held frequently only listened to a

few speeches and dispersed without transacting any real business.

Nevertheless, the Soviet government had claimed that the number of

Soviets actually functioning has grown continuously; yet it freely

admits that the Soviets have taken neither so active nor so responsible

a part as they should in the creation and management of the new

community. Russia’s “new economic policy” of reversion to capitalism

strikes at the root of the Soviet idea and destroys the functional

status of the Soviets.

Russia’s special difficulties in applying the Soviet system were

inherent in the backward state of the country which had only partially

progressed from feudalism into capitalism. In industry the small home

producer still accounted for 60 per cent of Russia’s industrial

production. In agriculture the peasants had not yet been divorced from

the land as is the case in England, where we have long had a completely

landless class of rural workers. In Russia the ideal of the land worker

was to produce for himself on his own holding and to sell his products,

not to work in co-operation with others. The Russian peasants, vastly

outnumbering the rest of the population, were all but unanimous in their

demands. Those who had no land were determined to get a piece for

themselves, and those who had a little piece of land wanted more. Though

their individualism was tempered by the old custom of periodically

re-dividing the land and other village traditions, the peasants were an

influence against Communism. Nevertheless, their ancient village

council, the Mir, a survival from the period of primitive Communism, had

somewhat prepared them for the Soviets.

In the scattered village communities the occupational character of the

Soviet is apparently somewhat submerged in the territorial; yet all the

subsidiary crafts of the villages are attendant on the great industry of

agriculture. Ties of common interest and mutual dependence, which are

the life-blood of the Soviet, are clearly apparent between the land

workers and the various craftsmen of the village. The blurring of the

occupational character of the village Soviet does not detract from its

function of an administrative unit in harmony with the actual conditions

of the country. On the other hand, the fact that the town Soviets could

not supply it with the industrial products it needed, by weakening the

link of mutual usefulness, making the usefulness merely one-sided,

removed the natural impetus of the Soviets of the villages to link

themselves for utilitarian reasons with the Soviets of the towns.

Production by individual producers who are competing with each other

creates sources of conflict which are antagonistic to the Soviet. The

strongest and most useful Soviet must always be that which is formed of

those who are working together and who realise at every turn that they

are dependent on each other. The necessity for the Soviet becomes more

pronounced and its work more varied the more that work is carried on in

common and the more closely the lives of the people are related to each

other. Mankind is gregarious; the degree of gregariousness in human

beings is partly dependant on material conditions, partly on inclination

(which is doubtless largely, if not wholly, the slow product of long

environment). As humanity secures a completer mastery over matter,

individual choice as to how life shall be spent, becomes broader and

more free; science will more and more enable desire to determine the

degree of industrial concentration. Our civilisation has perhaps nearly

reached the limit of the tendency to gather together ever greater and

greater numbers of workers, performing some tiny mechanical operation as

attendants to machinery. Perhaps the future has in store for us an

entirely opposite development. That would not effect the fact that the

Soviet must find its most congenial soil in a society based on mutual

aid and mutual dependence.

In the industrial centres where it might have been expected that the

occupational basis of the Soviet would have been adhered to, the

structure of the Russian Soviets was irregular from the theoretical

standpoint. The Soviets, instead of being formed purely of workers in

the various industries and activities of the community, were composed

also of delegates of political parties, political groups formed by

foreigners in Russia, Trades Councils, Trade Unions and co-operative

societies. Pravda of April 18th, 1918, published the following

regulations for the Moscow Soviet elections:—

The intention in giving representation to these various interests was,

of course, to disarm their antagonism to the Soviet power and to secure

their co-operation instead; but the essential administrative character

of the Soviets was thereby sacrificed. Constituted thus they must

inevitably discuss political antagonisms rather than the production and

distribution of social utilities and amenities.

The industrial unions, economic councils and co-operative societies

which have been a feature of Soviet Russia (the two former having

representation in the Soviets) have no place, because they have no

reason for existence, under an efficient Soviet system, in which they

would be absorbed into the occupational Soviets and indistinguishably

fused with them.

Industrial unions can have no reason for existence if the Soviets are

fulfilling efficiently their proper function as the administrative

machinery of the Communist community, for the Soviets should cover the

same constituencies as the industrial unions. The industrial unions will

only exist so long as there is either a conflict between the workers and

the Soviets (which are theoretically the organs of the workers), or in

case the Soviets are failing to administer industry or administer it

efficiently. The very existence of the Industrial Union, unless it be

merely a social club, denotes an antagonism between the members of the

union and those who are administering industry; unless, on the other

hand, the Soviets are failing to administer industry and the unions are

formed for that purpose. In Russia, as a matter of fact, the continued

existence of the industrial unions is due to the fact that there it

antagonism between the workers and those who are administering industry.

In a theoretically correct Soviet community the workers, through their

Soviets, which are indistinguishable from them, should administer. This

has not been achieved in Russia.

Co-operatives have no place in a genuine Soviet community. If they are

distributive organisations purely, they should be the distributive

branches of the industrial Soviets. If they are organs of buying and

selling, they are survivals of capitalism and must disappear under

Communism. If they are associations of producers they can only differ

from industrial Soviets in so far as they exact payment in cash or kind

for their produce instead of distributing it freely. In so far as they

exact payment or practice barter, they have no place in a Soviet

community.

The curious overlapping patchwork which has hitherto made up the Russian

Soviet system should by no means be slavishly copied. The Russians

themselves have emphasised that. Nevertheless, the recent tactics which

they have induced the Third International to adopt do not indicate that

they have a clear perception that a highly organised industrial

community may build the new Communist order on the theoretically correct

foundation of the occupational Soviets.

Part Five: Workers Dreadnought, January 28th 1922

Zinoviev, at the Second Congress of the Third International in Moscow,

introduced a Thesis declaring that no attempt should be made to form

Soviets prior to the outbreak of the revolutionary crisis. It was argued

that, as such bodies would be powerless, or nearly so, their formation

might bring the conception of the Soviets into proletarian contempt. The

Thesis was adopted by the Congress, without discussion, and thereby

became an axiom of the Third International.

The question as to whether the mere borrowed term, Soviet, shall be

reserved for use in the actual crisis of revolution is of small

importance though, if not used previously, it would probably miss being

adopted as the slogan of the revolution.

The question of postponing the creation of the actual organisation till

the hour of a revolutionary crisis is, on the other hand, a fundamental

one.

The idea expressed and insisted upon in that Thesis of Zinoviev’s was

that the Soviet must be a great mass movement, coming together in the

electrical excitement of the crisis; the correctness of its structure,

its actual Sovietness (to coin an adjective), being considered of

secondary importance. A progressive growth, gradually branching out till

the hour of crisis; a strong and well-tried organisation is not

contemplated by the Thesis. The need for carefully conceived structure

is ignored. Propaganda for the Soviets alone is recommended.

Russia’s dual Revolution was an affair of spontaneous outbursts, with no

adequate organisation behind it. The Trade Unions, always a feeble

growth, were crushed by the Czardom at the outbreak of the great war of

1914. The Revolutionary political parties could call for a revolution;

they could not carry it through: that was accomplished by the action of

the revolutionary elements in the Army and Navy, in the workshops, on

the railways, and on the land. That these revolutionaries at the point

of production were mainly unorganised was a disability, not an

advantage. In Russia the government first of the Czar, then of Kerensky,

crumbled readily under the popular assault. The disability arising from

the disorganised state of the workers was not felt in its full

weightiness until after the Soviet Government had been established. Then

it was realised that, though the Soviets were supposed to have taken

power, the Soviet structure had yet to be created and made to function.

The structure is still incomplete: it has functioned hardly at all.

Administration has been largely by Government departments, working often

without the active, ready co-operation, sometimes even with the

hostility of groups of workers who ought to have been taking a

responsible share in administration. To this cause must largely be

attributed Soviet Russia’s defeat on the economic front.

It would be monstrous folly for workers in other countries, especially

in highly industrialised countries where Capitalism is old, to imitate

Russia’s unpreparedness. We in Britain have an infinitely stronger

Capitalism to overturn: we have greater opportunities of creating the

organisation necessary to fight it.

This organisation must be able both to attack and destroy Capitalism in

the final struggle, and also to replace the administrative machinery of

Capitalism. Moreover it must be animated by the will to these

achievements.

We have at present no such organisation in this country.

Our Trade Unions have neither the will, nor the capacity for the

purpose. We are nearest industrial unionism in mining and transport and

on the land, but even there we have several competing Unions in each

industry. In the textile, metal, food preparing, wood-working, clothing,

and building industries, we have a multiplicity of little-co-ordinated

organisations. Moreover, the great mass of the workers is divided into

two sections: the skilled and the unskilled: organised into quite

separate Unions and divided by impassable barriers which have been

jealously erected and maintained by the skilled workers.

The structure of the Trade Unions is antiquated and fruitful of delays.

It is highly undemocratic, some Unions have first and second class

members, the former, of ten or more years’ standing, alone being

eligible for office; some elect their executive for eight years or some

other long term; some hold no general congress of branch

representatives. The rank and file members of the Unions have little or

no voice in deciding the larger issues of policy. The executive usually

determining the policy to be pursued at national conferences with other

bodies. The rules, which are registered with the capitalist Government’s

Registrar General, cannot be changed without long and hard effort. Under

normal circumstances it must take many years to change them appreciably.

The rules and structure of the Unions would place a handicap upon any

serious attempt that might be made to remould the Unions in order that

they might function with some sort of efficiency in the attack on

Capitalism and in the administration of industry after Capitalism were

overthrown.

The rules and structure are even a serious handicap in the daily

struggle to palliate Capitalism, which is what the Unions exist for.

The Union officials who, almost to a man, desire the retention of the

capitalist system, fear, above all things, any serious attack upon it,

are aided and protected in their conservatism by the Union rules.

The reactionary officials have, however, a stronger buttress and

protection in the backward masses, who vastly outnumber the awakened

workers in the Trade Unions. It is only in the advanced stages of the

Revolution that the great masses will discern the gulf between

themselves and their reactionary leaders. This is one of the reasons why

another organisation is necessary. Such an organisation must reveal to

the masses the true character of their leaders, and offer them an

alternative policy.

The Trade Unions are composed of masses of workers who did not become

members of the Unions with the object of changing the social system, but

merely to palliate it. Latterly men and women have even been forced into

the Unions, because Trade Unions had become strong enough to insure that

those who refused to join would have difficulty in obtaining employment.

With such a membership, the Trade Unions are naturally timid,

conservative bodies, apt to oppose drastic change and unready to take

any bold initiative.

We believe that such Trade Unions can never deliberately precipitate a

revolution. In this matter, theory is supported by experience. In Russia

the revolution was not made by the hardly-existing Trade Unions. After

the first revolution the Central Council of Soviets laboured to form

Trade Unions. Some of the Unions it had formed then opposed retention of

power by the Soviets, worked against all tendencies towards Communism,

and gave their support to the demand for a bourgeois republic, with

Capitalism re-established in power.

In Germany, the Trade Unions, so far from leading the various

proletarian uprisings, took no official part except to oppose them.

To administer in place of Capitalism, as well as to overthrow it, the

workers should be organised with all, and more than all, the efficiency

and coherence of Capitalism. In this country, Capitalism itself, though

tremendously better equipped than in Russia under the Czardom, still

lacks co-ordination. As a medium for supplying the people’s needs, it

suffers on the one hand from the competition and overlapping of private

interests; and, on the other, from shortage and lack in districts where

the small means of the people do not render it profitable to supply them

efficiently. Every day British Capitalism is remedying some of its

organisational defects, at least, some of those due to its own internal

capitalist rivalries.

From banking, where we have nearly arrived at a single trust, to

tea-shops, where Lyons is absorbing competitor after competitor,

co-ordination and the elimination of competition is going on constantly.

Trustification has not yet developed nearly so far in Britain as in

Germany, where the combination of the powerful capitalist, Stinnes,

links up coal and ore mining, smelting, and the manufacture, shipping

and marketing of all sorts of metal goods; forestry, wood-working,

paper-making, printing and publishing; tram, train, and sea travel, and

the provision of hotel accommodation; the production and supply of

electricity in all its branches, and a host of other activities.

British Capitalist organisation will rapidly become more closely knit

under pressure of the competition which is rising up against it all over

the world: in Britain’s own colonies and dominions, in America, in the

growing industrialism of Poland, Italy, and other European countries,

above all in Germany, whose Capitalism, still more since the war that

was meant to crush it, is Britain’s keenest rival.

We should welcome the trustification of industry, in so far as it is a

co-ordination along the lines of convenience and utility in producing

and distributing what is needed by the populace. We should welcome it

also because it provides the means of linking up the workers into a

closely-knit fighting organisation; an organisation which can step in

and displace the capitalist, and, having done so, shall be able to carry

on production and distribution.

Such an organisation may be built up by organising the workers in the

co-ordinated centres of production and distribution along the lines of

the Trust itself. The Trade Unions are not thus organised.

Although Trustification has not yet developed very far in Britain,

British employers of labour are much better organised than British

workers. Employers’ Associations and Trade Journals bind the employers

together in all industries, and a much greater degree of solidarity is

shown by the employing class than by the working class when a trade

dispute arises. In this country Trade Unionism has never achieved the

general strike: it has even shrunk from attempting any large-scale

sympathetic strike. In this respect British Trade Unionism is behind

that of most European countries. Both ideologically and structurally it

is distinctly outdistanced by its continental contemporaries. Indeed, it

is solely on the size of its membership that the British Trade Union

movement has claimed to be the strongest in the world. As a body of

action it would gain in strength if it could be ruthlessly pruned of its

more backward members.

The trustification and co-ordination of industry under Capitalism has

for many years been causing a perpetual discussion upon industrial

unionism to be carried on in the Labour movement; but the result in

actual improvements in the Union structure has been surprisingly small.

That rapid wartime growth, the Shop Stewards’ organisation, in a few

months co-ordinated the workers in the munition factories and shipyards

with an efficient completeness the Trade Unions had never approached,

and made the Stewards’ movement a coherent acting force, such as the

Trade Unions had never been. This development shows that the task of

organising the workers in accordance with Capitalist organisation, in

which the Trade Unions have hitherto failed, may readily be accomplished

by building upon a new basis, unhindered by the trammels of the old

machinery and the prejudices and vested interests of the old officials.

It may, perhaps, be objected that since the Shop Stewards’ organisation

dwindled at the close of the war and has all but passed away, there are

elements of permanency in the Trade Unions which the Shop Stewards did

not possess. That is true. The Trade Unions remained in possession of

their accumulated funds, and were adding to these funds week by week,

for the workers continued paying their Trade Union dues week by week;

although the Trade Unions were functioning only as benefit societies,

whilst the rank and file workers themselves were doing, through their

shop committees and their elected stewards, the work for which the

Unions were created. The Unions retained possession of the funds and the

friendly benefits. When the boom in production passed and unemployment

became rife in the land, the workers unready for the time being to

safeguard their status in the workshop, were glad to fall back on the

friendly benefits of the Union.

Part Six: Workers Dreadnought, February 4th 1922

As we have seen, the main purpose of the Soviets is to minister to the

needs of the people, in clothing, housing, education, recreation,

transport and so on. The workers who are responsible for these services

are linked together in their Soviets for the purposes of their work. The

Soviet structure is efficient, because it is formed on the lines

necessitated by the work; also because it gives every worker a

responsible share in the common effort, and thereby encourages the

co-operative impulse. Even under Capitalism the merits of the workshop

council, which is the germ of the Soviet, have been discovered, not only

by the workers, but by the capitalist himself. During the war, when the

Shop Stewards’ Movement flourished, employers actually initiated the

formation of shop councils and the election of workers’ stewards.

The employers did so, not merely to forestall the rebel elements, but

rather because, in the great stress of war-time and with a tremendous

influx of new workers, the shop council organisation would minimise the

cost of management, reduce the number of paid supervisors required, and

the difficulty of maintaining discipline, and increase the output by

producing a spirit of willingness amongst the workers who were

responsive to the patriotic appeals to produce more.

Mr. Charles Reynold, of the big engineering firm of that name, recently

gave an address on workshop committees and the control of industry: he

described how the works committee at his firm holds monthly meetings

with the management to discuss wages and conditions of labour, and all

questions of management. He declared that the confidential financial

information presented to the directors is communicated to the works

committee, and the result is the creation of a sense of responsibility,

an understanding of the management point of view, and the acceptance of

changes with comparatively little friction.

From the class-war standpoint this information does not gratify us, and

presumably the scheme is part of some profit-sharing arrangement. It is

nevertheless testimony to the value of the workshop council from the

administrative efficiency standpoint, although under Capitalism the shop

council has, of course, no real power, and only a leading-strings share

of responsibility. Reynold’s is but one of many capitalist firms which

are endeavouring, in the interests of efficiency, to secure the

co-operation of their workers, though capitalist conditions prevent the

co-operation from being genuine on either side. The growth of Whitleyism

shows that the intelligent British capitalists are beginning to

understand that men and women only give their best when they give of

their free will, feeling that they are responsible entities. This truth

is too often forgotten by those who once preached it, when they attain

to official positions, whether in Russia, or in Britain.

The trend of the times supports the view that the Soviet Government made

a serious blunder when it decided (and put into practice its decision)

that “workers’ control of industry” is only a slogan useful for securing

the overthrow of the capitalist, and must be discarded, once the workers

have turned out the capitalist, in favour of management by an individual

or committee appointed by some centralised authority.

A careful and candid survey of the Russian attempt to establish

Communism will some day reveal, more clearly than at present, the

proportional weight of the causes which have led to its failure. That it

has failed for the present, and that only a powerful new impetus can

stop the present retrogression in Russia we are compelled to admit.

Such a candid survey will provide evidence as to how far the Russian

failure has been due to the capitalist resistance to Communism; how far

to the unreadiness of the population; how far to the mistakes of the

Communists, and especially to the mistakes of the Soviet Government.

The question of workers’ control of industry will bulk largely in this

connection.

Viewed from the standpoint of efficiency as a fighting force, it is

notorious that never were strikes so swiftly, solidly and successfully

effected in this country as those of the war-time Shop Stewards’

movement. A rank and file chorus complaining of the inefficiency,

inactivity and lack of class solidarity shown by the reactionary Trade

Union leaders is constantly rising and falling. During the Dublin

Lock-Out of 1912, during the railway strike of 1919 and the coal strike

of 1921, it swelled with indignation, but only the workers organised in

the workshop committees have taken large-scale action, except at the

bidding of the Union officials. This is not unnatural: until both the

individual workers and the workers in each individual firm feel that

others will act with them, they shrink from taking action which, if not

supported, will lead to their victimisation.

To recapitulate: the Soviets, or workers’ occupational councils, will

form the administrative machinery for supplying the needs of the people

in Communist society; they will also make the revolution by seizing

control of all the industries and services of the community.

Though in Russia the revolution was accomplished by Soviets which sprang

up spontaneously in some places and by unorganised mob risings, this was

only possible, because the government of Russia had broken down,

Capitalism was weak and of limited extent, and the entire country in a

state of chaotic disorder.

Here in Britain the machinery of the Soviets must be prepared in

advance. In all the industries and services, revolutionary workers, who

are habitually at work there and know the ropes, must be prepared to

seize and maintain control.

The Trade Unions do not provide this machinery: they are not competent,

either to seize, control, or to administer industry. They are not

structurally fitted to administer industry, because their organisations

do not combine all the workers in any industry, and they are not

efficiently co-ordinated. Their branches are constructed according to

the district in which the worker resides, not according to where he

works.

The Trade Unions are, moreover opposed to revolutionary action: their

object is to secure palliations of the capitalist system, not to abolish

it.

British experience has shown that the workers’ council system is

efficient both as an engine for fighting the employer, and as a means of

administrating the industry. Experience has also shown that under

favourable conditions it can be built up with remarkable rapidity.

Experience in those European countries where the workers and their

organisations have been tested in the revolutionary fight, has shown

that the workers’ council is always the organ of the workers’ struggle.

The Trade Unions, having tried unsuccessfully to avert the contest, in

each case threw the weight of their influence on to the side of

preserving the established order, and opposed every effort of the

workers and their councils to overpower the employing class.

The evidence given by J.H. Thomas in his libel case against the

Communist and its officials reveals the attitude which he will adopt in

the event of any struggles for Proletarian power in this country. J.H.

Thomas must not be regarded as an exception: the British Trade Union

officials will all adopt the same attitude. Some will denounce the

revolutionary workers on platforms, openly proclaiming their allegiance

to the Crown, the Government and the employing class; others will merely

hold aloof from the revolutionaries and in the Trade Union conferences

will vote against the Unions joining the revolutionaries in the

struggle. If they do not advise Trade Union members to give actual

assistance to the Government in coercing the revolutionaries, they will

at least advise their members to assist the cause of re-establishing the

disturbed capitalist order by remaining quietly at work — the obedient

servants of the capitalist employer, or of the capitalist Government.

This is the part which the Trade Unions and their officials have played

in every one of the many recent proletarian uprisings in other

countries: this is the part which J.H. Thomas and his colleagues will

play here. J.H. Thomas differs only in degree from his colleagues who

belong to the Reformist School. The British Trade Union movement and its

officials belong to the same school as the Trade Unions and Trade Union

officials of Europe and America.

The Trade Unions have too loose and uncoordinated a structure to make

the revolution: they are ideologically opposed to it: therefore they

will fight it.

The workers’ councils, co-ordinated industrially and nationally along

the lines of production and distribution, are the organs which are

structurally fitted to give the workers greatest power in the control of

industry. If that power is to be used to overthrow the present system,

the councils, which together will form a “One Big Union” of workers’

committees in all industries, should be built, from the first, with the

object of taking control.

In Germany, where the methods necessary for waging the proletarian

struggle are being forged during the struggle, the Revolutionary

Workers’ Union, the A.A.U., is a fighting force which has had to be

reckoned with. Its growth has been accelerated by the fact that the

reactionary Trade Unions have expelled their revolutionary members.

Part Seven: Workers Dreadnought, March 11th 1922

The great task of the Communist revolution is ideologic. Communism

entails the creation of an altogether new attitude of mind towards all

social relationships, and the development of a host of new habits and

impulses. In discarding our purse and our financial anxieties and

calculations, in removing the dependence of the propertiless upon the

propertied, we shall change the entire configuration of life. Communism

will create for us a great fraternity, a great trustfulness, arising

from a great security, an abundant enthusiasm for productive labour,

because such labour will benefit all, and all will share responsibility

for it.

Communism necessitates the creation of a great initiative, which shall

animate the entire people.

Under Capitalism the masses are as a flock of sheep driven by their

owners. Under Communism, on the contrary, they will be free

co-operators, producing, inventing, studying, not under the compulsion

of law, or poverty, or the incentive of individual gain, but from

deliberate choice and with an eager zest for achievement. Communism will

provide the material and spiritual conditions which will make voluntary

co-operative labour possible. Only by willing service and intelligent

initiative can true Communism develop.

The establishment of the Communist life entails a complete breach, both

in practice and in ideas, with Capitalism and its machinery. The

Parliamentary system is the characteristic machinery of the capitalist

State; it has grown up with great similarity in all the countries which

have built up their own capitalism. In countries where an alien

Capitalism dominates the native populace, the Parliamentary system of

the dominant aliens extends the tentacles of its power to the subject

country. It sends its officials overseas to rule the natives, entirely

discarding its pretended dependence on the consent of the governed and

its boasted representative character.

Parliament has been in large measure the co-operative society of the

landlords and capitalists through which they have policed the

proletariat at home and maintained their power abroad.

The great landlords originally used lawless force and violence for

seizing their estates. In the latter half of the fifteenth century they,

as feudal lords, drove the peasants, who had the same feudal right to

the land as they, from their holdings. The feudal lords usurped the

lands which were held and used in common. These things they did in

defiance of law and custom, and without waiting to obtain the assent or

assistance of Parliament.

Later on, however, the feudal lords found it convenient to give

Parliamentary sanction to their robbery of the peasants, and to enact

legislation to complete their usurpation of the land. Sitting in

Parliament, the lords proceeded thereafter to abolish their own merely

feudal tenure of the land, and by creating the modern right of private

property in land, they made themselves its absolute owners.

Before they had legalised the expropriation of the peasants, the lords

in Parliament enacted legislation to force the peasants they were

driving from the land to become their wage-slaves. From the reign of

Henry VII, legislation began for the coercion of the dispossessed. We

all know that for begging, or wandering without means of subsistence,

the landless people were whipped and branded, their ears were sliced,

and on a third arrest they were executed. An Act of Edward VI condemned

the idler to be the slave of whoever denounced him. He could be sold,

bequeathed, or hired as a slave. Any-one might make slaves of his

children. Vagabonds, as the dispossessed were called, might be made into

parish slaves, condemned to labour for the inhabitants. Only in the

reign of Anne, when an industrial proletariat sufficient for the needs

of farmers and manufacturers had been developed, were such statutes

repealed. So long ago as 1349, Parliament, in the Statute of Labourers,

fixed maximum wages to prevent the proletariat from asserting itself to

the inconvenience of the employing classes. Maximum wage legislation was

maintained thereafter as long as any serious tendency to labour scarcity

could give the workers a powerful lever in forcing up their wages.

Parliament has remained the employers’ co-operative society for

dragooning the workers, in spite of all the extensions of the franchise

which have taken place. When a serious labour scarcity arose in our

time, during the great European war of 1914-19, Parliament enacted the

Munitions Act, to prevent the workers taking advantage of the situation.

Neither in this present period of great unemployment, nor at any other

time in history, has Parliament fixed maximum wages to protect the

workers when the employers have been taking advantage of a Labour

surplus to depress the wages of their employees below the subsistence

level. The rates of wages fixed by the Agricultural Wages Boards during

the war, were, in reality, a method of attaining by subtle means, the

object which the Munitions Act achieved in other industries: namely a

check on the bargaining power of Labour during a period of unexampled

labour scarcity.

From the early laws against the industrial combination of the workers

(maintained by the coercive power of the state as long as the ruling

classes considered them necessary) down to our modern D.O.R.A. and

E.P.A. and the strike-breaking machinery employed by the government in

the last railway and mining strikes, Parliamentary Government has never

failed to protect the possessions of the landlords and capitalists, and

to employ whatever coercive measures have been necessary to provide the

landlords and capitalists with disciplined workers.

Parliament and its accessories have been fashioned by the ruling classes

for their service. The Courts of Law are strongholds of tradition and

privilege, and appointment to the judicial Bench is made obscurely and

arbitrarily by the Government.

In case of dispute, the Government-appointed irremovable judges

interpret the Parliament-made law. The Government-hired prosecutor — who

may even be a member of the Government, is leagued with the

Government-appointed judge against the accused. All the force of the

Government police assists the prosecution. In political trials,

acquittals are remarkably rare. The judges, drawn from the privileged

class, almost invariably decide against the popular cause.

The local governing bodies have no power to legislate or initiate: they

merely administer the Acts of Parliament under the cramping supervision

of Government Departments, which make rules interpreting the Acts of

Parliament. Either with, or without Parliamentary sanction, Government

departments determine what the local authorities shall spend, by

limiting their power to levy Rates and to contract loans, and by

prohibiting them from trading, except by special permission of the

Government.

As to Parliament itself, its powers have been almost all annexed by the

Cabinet.

The King, who is supposed to obey the Government, decides when

Parliament shall assemble. The Government decides what subjects

Parliament shall discuss, and on what it shall legislate. The Government

drafts the legislation. If a measure be amended in a manner displeasing

to the Government, the Government withdraws the measure, and either

drops it altogether, or re-introduces it in another form. Parliament

cannot proceed with any measure unless the Government desire it.

The Speaker and Chairman of Committee appointed by the Government,

control the debate and interpret the rules of procedure. Parliamentary

discipline is exceedingly strict. No one may speak until called upon by

the Speaker, or Chairman of Committee, and the Speaker, or Chairman, may

stop any speech, and even prevent the asking of a question, on the

ground, either that it is out of order or “it is not in the public

interest” that a reply be given. There is no appeal from the ruling of

the Chair, which is enforced by the officials of the House, who at once

eject any Member failing to obey the Chair.

The Government must have a majority in the House of Commons, or it

cannot remain in power. That majority is composed of Party hacks with no

chance of being returned to Parliament, except by the aid of the Party

machinery and funds. They will not vote against the Government, because

to do so would be to incur the ostracism of the Party leaders, and

consequently of the Party; such ostracism would inevitably mean the loss

of their Parliamentary seats at the next election. The Party man who

disobeys his Party must either retire from politics, or become a

candidate of the opposite Party (if it will have him, which may not be

the case). Many years have passed since a Government was turned out by a

hostile Parliamentary vote of its supporters. Even its political

opponents are apt to shrink from defeating a Government on a critical

issue, which would mean its resignation, for that in most cases entails

a General Election. A General Election is of all things that which is

most detested by the average Member of Parliament. It means for him an

election campaign of tremendous exertion, in which he is compelled to

speak at an extraordinary number of meetings, besides canvassing voters

and calling on people of influence. Moreover, he may lose his seat, and

thus suffer the defeat of many of his ambitions, as well as the loss of

an income of four hundred pounds a year. The Member of Parliament

prepared to take a line independent of his Party on any subject of

importance is exceedingly rare. He is soon eliminated from Parliament.

The Prime Minister is chosen by the Sovereign from amongst the most

prominent leaders of the Party which gains the majority of the

Parliamentary seats in the General Election. Persons of powerful

influence, of course, make representations to the Sovereign, and the

Party caucus and its rival big-wigs all put in their word. What private

understandings and guarantees are exacted the people do not know. The

Sovereign appoints the rest of the Cabinet on the advice of the Prime

Minister, who is influenced, of course, by the powerful personages who

provide Party funds, who control Party newspapers, and who are powerful

in banking and other circles able to sabotage the Government activities.

The wire-pulling and intrigue that surround the making of Cabinets have

only been slightly revealed in the memoirs of some of the privileged few

who have been behind the scenes.

The policies of Government Departments are supposed to be controlled in

general outline by the Cabinet as a whole, and in fuller detail by the

Minister at the head of each Department who is appointed by the Prime

Minister. The Departments are vast and deal with vast work; the Cabinet

of party hacks and political adventurers knows little of the

Departments. The responsible Minister, who usually remains in a

particular Department no more than a year or two at most, and often no

more than a few months, rarely learns much about his work; the permanent

officials are the real masters of the administrative detail, and their

policy is broadly that of the prevailing capitalist opinion current at

the time. Lavish extravagance on Departmental expenditure, and ruthless

parsimony towards the people, the great unofficial, unprivileged masses,

who are treated as tiresome mendicants, is the outstanding

characteristic of administration by Government Departments.

Members of Parliament know little of the doings of Government

Departments. The debates, held twice or thrice a year, and the

questions, to which cursory answers are given and on which no discussion

is permitted, are the only opportunities by which Members may acquire

information. Ministers in charge of Departments report once or twice a

year what they choose of what their Departments have done.

Members of Parliament may move to reduce the amount Parliament is to

vote for the Department in question, as a protest against something that

displeases them, or as a matter of political form. Such motions are

usually defeated or withdrawn. If, however such a motion be carried, the

Government may resign, if the question involved be important. Generally,

in such rare cases, the Government brings the vote up again another day,

and, by rallying its supporters, it defeats the motion. Perhaps as a

result of the incident the Minister whose Department has been

criticised, moves on to another Department. His old place is taken by

one whose policy differs but little from his own.

The House of Commons has no effective check on the doings of the

Cabinet: it knows very little of what the Cabinet is actually about; the

Press is given more information on questions of State than are the

ordinary Members of Parliament.

The House of Lords, with its hereditary members, can check and thwart

the doings of the Government more effectively than can the House of

Commons, although its power is specifically limited. Its Members are not

dependent on the machinery of the Party to secure their election. Their

Parliamentary seats are theirs for life: no-one can dislodge them. The

older Lords, at least, are probably no longer seeking the favour of

Party leaders and Members of the Government to assist their personal

fortunes. Though, perhaps, less open to personal corruption than the

ambitious political hacks of the House of Commons, the Members of the

House of Lords are, of course, even more surely lined up as one man

against the emancipation of the proletariat and in defence of the

present system.

In all this the electors are remote outsiders. They have no hold on the

Members of the House of Commons who are supposed to represent them. They

must decide for which candidate to vote on the general programme of the

Party promoting the candidature, for, if returned, the Member will have

no power except through his Party. No item of the Party programme is

binding, no pledge given by the candidate or his Party can be relied on.

The programme is enunciated during the election in vaguely-worded

speeches and manifestos, every point in which will probably be

discarded. Not until the next election will the voter have another

chance to pass judgement on the actions of the candidate who won the

seat in his local constituency, or on those of the Government in power.

The Member, meanwhile, has probably been merely a cipher in Parliament;

the Government has done nothing pleasing to the elector; but the

opposing Party, in the vague compound of catch-cries called its

programme, offers nothing that promises satisfaction. The constituency

is vast: the electors have no personal knowledge of either candidate.

The election is decided by such questions as which Party machine has

most systematically traced the absent voters and made the best

arrangements to bring them to the poll, which Party has the most motor

cars lent to it for taking voters on free rides to the polling booth,

which Party is served by the local paper having the largest circulation

in the district.

Even were it possible to democratise the machinery of Parliament, its

inherently anti-Communist character would still remain. The King might

be replaced by a President, or all trace of the office abolished. The

House of Lords might disappear, or be transformed into a Senate. The

Prime Minister might be chosen by a majority vote of Parliament, or

elected by referendum of the people. The Cabinet might be chosen by

referendum, or become an Executive Committee elected by Parliament. The

doings of Parliament might be checked by referendum.

Nevertheless, Parliament would still be a non-Communist institution.

Under Communism we shall have no such machinery of legislation and

coercion. The business of the Soviets will be to organise the production

and supply of the common services; they can have no other lasting

function.