💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › karl-hess-community-technology.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:51:54. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Community Technology
Author: Karl Hess
Date: 1979
Language: en
Topics: community, community building, technology
Source: Retrieved 11/06/2022 from https://ad-store.sgp1.digitaloceanspaces.com/VONU/2022/02/Community%20Technology%20by%20Karl%20Hess%20PDF%20Official.pdf

Karl Hess

Community Technology

Foreword

We as anarchists have a long journey ahead of us. However, we have an

abundance of philosophical, ethical, and strategic theory that provides

us with a basis for anarchism and a path toward it.

One aspect that is necessary as well as prevalent in Karl Hess’ work is

to alter our relationship with production in order to create the

material base (material condition/ facts on the ground) for human

freedom and flourishing. Hess’ work is more relevant than ever before.

As humans, we have outsourced the production of our wants and needs to

institutions and corporations. Because of this, the progression of

production and technology has expanded to serve institutions and

corporations at the expense of our own wealth, freedom, and autonomy.

This is what must be changed. We must regain control of the apparatus

that directly effects our lives. We must build the means of production,

infrastructure, technology, and institutions that serve us, not the

other way around. We must be producers, not mindless consumers in all

things.

Only this will allow us to exercise our autonomy and create the basis of

a free society.

All philosophy requires a material base, and Hess’ work lays out the

path to create it through appropriate, decentralized, sustainable

technology, and to gain more control of our lives through localization

of economic, social, and political organization.

May he rest in peace.

-SEK MCGORA

The Agora Podcast

Chapter 1: The Failure of Large Institutions

There is not a single large institution or organization in the world

today that is satisfactorily performing all of the functions people have

assigned to it. They are creaking, cracking, and even crashing under

their own weight. Everywhere people sense that things are going to hell.

Yet people themselves persist, contrive to survive, even make things

better; and more and more they do all of those things with less and less

direct reference to the major institutions.

People seem to be going one way, institutions another.

The largest of all institutions, the nation-state, maintains itself by

sheer force in much of the world. Even where it is supposed to be

supported popularly, the old enthusiasms wane. In America, fewer than a

third of the eligible voters elected the last President. America’s most

recent war (usually the proudest activity of a nation-state) was a

shambles. What more and more people seem to want most from their

government is for it to go away—after, of course, handing out the

particular favor which is seen as its only redeeming grace!

Churches sag at the institutional level and are revitalizing at the

local level, in new sects, evangelisms, mysteries. The largest of the

tightly organized churches, the Roman Catholic, is fracturing and

sliding like a geological mass, with its adherents going their way, the

papal leadership going another.

Cities, virtually all of them, seem to have reached limits of

satisfaction having to do with size and the cost of that size. New York

remains the largest city—and also the most precarious, the most dubious,

the most perilous. Size has not saved it. Size seems to have damned it.

In cities where there seems to be a rebirth of confidence and

possibility, there also is a rebirth of life in the smallest of civic

units, the neighborhood.

Schools, failing all along the line, have also grown all along the line,

with the one-room schools giving way to the town schools and those, more

recently, giving way to the consolidated schools. The shiny new

buildings and the conglomerated classes produced—what? A crisis in

literacy and a few winning football teams. Now school bond issues have a

tough time passing anywhere.

The police get tanks, helicopters, bullet-proof vests, and a lifetime

subscription to the CIA. The muggers get bolder. The rapes go up. And

nobody ever did bother to get some cops to watch the executives.

Hospitals glisten like the command modules of spacecraft. Rare and

wonderful surgery is performed. Medical miracles keep making the

headlines—and a long siege of an ordinary illness bankrupts people.

Meantime, back at the lab, one group of scientists spends millions to

research a medical cure for cancer while another group spends millions

proving that the major causes of cancer are environmental.

The Surgeon General condemns smoking. The Secretary of Agriculture helps

stimulate tobacco farming.

Everybody condemns the Arabs when they raise oil prices—then say how

shrewd a business deal it is for American companies to own so much of

the world’s largest oil producer, Aramco, in Saudi Arabia.

Ronald Reagan keeps talking about getting Big Government out of our

lives, then drums it up for a military occupation of Our Panama Canal,

higher defense budgets, and more freedom for government security agents

to poke and probe and even shoot wherever they want.

Leftists condemn the government for every wrong from racism to

genocide—and then propose that an even bigger government take over all

productive facilities.

Industry and business, also grabbing for the claimed efficiencies of

scale, have become so concentrated in ownership that just 2000 (1

percent) of the 200,000 American industrial corporations now account for

about 90 percent of annual profits and about the same proportion of

total assets. Yet, products are more and more seen as sleazy, and

advertising depends on the rankest appeals to push products. The people

who design and make them are increasingly bored, silly and dissatisfied

with what they do. Alcoholism, narcotic addiction, suicide, divorce, and

sabotage rise as the production lines go faster.

Television, with its creativity captured by three commercial networks

and one politically controlled public one, shifts back and forth between

mediocrity and ho-hum while entertainers make in a year what poets,

scientists, and farmers make in a lifetime.

Corporate farms replace family farms, crops are grown more and more in

great area-wide clumps or even in separate countries (tomatoes in the

Bahamas, asparagus in Mexico), famine stalks the earth, blights sweep

the giant farms, and machines that have replaced farmers prove incapable

of functioning with care and sense (as witness the corporate-scale

farming of the Soviet Union).

Small business perishes, and with it freedom of enterprise, as

conglomerate managements and agreements replace old-fashioned marketing.

Product differentiation replaces actual innovation and style dominates

over serviceability or need.

Even neighborliness and friendship become gripped by the symptoms of

growth, so that simple affection of people for each other is replaced by

the new industries of introspection, meditation, faddish indulgences,

singles bars, dating companies, and pleasure consultants.

Finally, the places where we live become simply real estate, places

primarily for speculation. The good town is the growing town, even if

the growth displaces the residents, scatters them to other centers, pays

them well for property abandoned, then charges them even more for

property to replace it. And, like a final blow to the old American

Dream, the possibility of even having a house to live in is now said to

be beyond the reach of most of us. Progress. Growth. Moving on. Growing

up, and up, and up.

In pathology, one form of unlimited growth is known as cancer. To many a

Chamber of Commerce unlimited growth is still called “progress.”

Yet, people by themselves, not as parts of the institutions which lead

the cheering for all this concentration and growth, people by themselves

keep going elsewhere.

Some townspeople simply shut the door. No more growth.

Some young people declare that community, not success, is their goal.

Small business is suddenly a countercultural phenomenon. Family farms

are said to be the mark of “the new pioneers.”

All of these matters are discernible in the ordinary course of things.

They do not require scholarly research at least to see the outlines, The

outlines of the discontents are ordinary table talk. So are the outlines

of the simmering hopes and the shimmering dreams and the changes.

At the heart of it all lies what seems to me an inescapable observation;

People feel vague and dissatisfied, troubled, when their work seems to

have no meaning or to be just part of some interchangeable inexplicable

machine; when their life shrinks into the confines of a single house or

apartment; when neighborliness is lost; when all life seems

compartmentalized, packaged, processed; when anonymity seems the name of

the game and one’s name becomes a number.

The equally inescapable alternative would be community, understandable

work, friends, someplace to stand, a reason to stand up, and a certainty

of being counted, of being heard, of being a recognizable and not an

indistinguishable part of the whole.

It does not seem much to ask to be a whole person in a whole world. Yet

the world would have to change to make that possible. Is it possible? I

am convinced it is. Possible. Practical. Not pie in the sky, but

something for here and now.

The two crucial elements are community and technology. A place in which

and a way in which people can live peacefully, socially, cooperatively;

and tools and techniques to provide the necessary material base for that

way of living.

Communities, of course, are human work; they arise from human decisions

and interactions. But what about technology, knowledge, knowing how to

do things and making the things with which to do them?

They are seen so commonly as the results of institutional that viewing

them as community enterprises requires what may seem a shocking

reassessment. This book is for people who want to at least consider such

a reassessment. For any who do, there is an initially comforting

thought. You, we, are not alone. Thinking about community and thinking

about the technologies appropriate to community is something people are

doing in increasing, if not yet overwhelming, numbers everywhere on

earth.

Most are not impelled by ideological furies. They are doing it for a

simple and very decent, very human reason: there really doesn’t seem to

be any other way to go these days. All of the grand theories of central

authority, of pyramids of power, ideological purifications, growth,

bigness, and progress have been tried. Yet here we are, knowing that

things just aren’t working.

Because this is a book about technology which has very personal

dimensions, it requires a personal statement at the beginning.

Unfortunately, it is likely to sound outrageous. If it does, please

understand that it derives from experience and not from ideological

frenzy.

Like most of us, I have worked very hard and very long under the

impression that the bigger anything is the better it is. I have worked

very hard and very long under the impression that success is money, that

time is money, that progress is money, that money is wealth. You know

all of these things. We grow up knowing these things. In fact, when we

know these things we are said to have grown up.

We see technology as a tool to do it all, to make things bigger, to make

more money, to save more time. And we see technology as a way of

accomplishing everything, as an entire way of thinking. With the time we

save we have leisure—and with the leisure we have new technologies of

recreation. When the recreation palls, we have new technologies of

introspection and analysis to discover why it palls and, in effect, to

provide a new recreation to fill all that time that we saved—but which,

come to think of it, we are too rushed to enjoy. Perhaps then we turn to

the technologies of narcotic tranquillity.

Above all, we see technology, most of us, as something remote, another

product, built in another factory—something we can buy. Like food. Like

satisfaction. Like respect.

I am convinced now that there are other possibilities. I have worked

enough at the practical development and deployment of them to see them

as wholly available as alternatives here and now.

It is possible for us—working together in social situations of various

sizes according to our preferences—to spend our time almost exactly as

we want to. The rules and imperatives that conventional wisdom fasten on

us are not binding except to the extent we let them be.

Technologies, ways of working, kinds of tools, can be developed,

deployed, and maintained at the community level.

Communities, founded upon ways of life that reflect the values and

aspirations of the people who compose the community, can take long steps

toward exactly the degree of self-reliance that will best serve the

purposes of the community. Communities can, without complex social

controls, cooperate with other communities to provide things not locally

available, to enlarge cultures, to do anything that will enhance the

community without destroying it.

There are no shortages of anything on the face of the earth that would

prevent any community from surviving healthily and happily. If you say,

Aha, there are shortages of petrochemicals so severe that not everybody

can have them, the obvious answer is that not everyone needs them. There

are other fuels. There are other chemicals. Petrochemicals seem

essential not because of technology so good that everyone must have it

but because of technology so poor that it has become inflexible,

dependent, stultified. The petrochemical industry is a monument to the

folly of putting all our technological eggs in one huge basket. That

huge basket is corporate and state domination of technology. This book

is an argument for community participation, with all of the diversity

and resultant flexibilities that that implies.

Technology, to hear most public descriptions and discussions of it, is

concerned solely with great institutions: National Strength, Corporate

Progress, Gross National Product, National Security, State of Knowledge.

You can practically hear the trumpets blaring and see the thrones of

power glistening at the end of majestic red carpets. Ta-ra, ta-ra.

So long as technology actually seems that remote and that majestic, it

will not serve us. Like a monarch, it will rule us. Rather, those who

manage it will rule us.

The fact is that technology is simply the way we use tools, actual tools

in the material sense, and tools of knowledge in the sense of skills and

craft and technique. It is not majestic. It is quite earthy. It is not

remote. It involves us all. It involves shopkeepers in crowded cities.

It involves farmhands. It involves kids. Everyone. People here. People

around the world. We are all tool users and knowledge users, from the

tribal farmer scratching a seed furrow with a pointed stick to the

high-energy physicist aligning a particle accelerator, from the shaman

to the molecular biologist.

Science is another matter. It is a process: one way of observing the

natural world, conjecturing about relationships in the natural world,

rigorously testing those conjectures, and then making predictions as to

performance and occurrence on the basis of those tested conjectures. It

is also the process by which, over time, virtually every conjecture,

even after acceptance, has been replaced by another. Science is a way of

thinking.

Technology is a way of doing work. Science is when someone, on the basis

of a long-tested theory or conjecture, predicts that it will take so

much energy to drive a certain nail into a certain piece of wood—other

scientific probing having established descriptions for energy and for

the hardness of wood. Technology is when someone attaches a dense

material such as metal, to a hand-suitable material such as wood,

tubular steel, or fiberglass to produce the hammer that will impart the

arm’s energy to the nail (a device that involves another technology,

based on scientific notions of friction, which is a theory, and so on

and on).

Today, both science and technology are part of a public schizophrenia

that is as deranging as the private kind.

On the one hand, virtually all politicians and managers of great

economic power, such as the Rockefellers, the Morgans, the Du Ponts, and

the Fords, seem to regard science and technology as twin goddesses

lighting the sky for the greater glory of capital expansion and the

empire of businesses around the world. Socialist politicians and

businessmen, or ministers of this or that as they prefer to call

themselves, share exactly the same respect for science and technology

and for exactly the same reasons but with different labels affixed.

Socialists and capitalists alike, for instance, feel that National

Strength is simply a function of National Defense, which in turn is just

a derivative of the Nation’s State of Technological Know-How. They also

feel that no matter what the problem— pollution, for instance—there will

someday be a technological cure; so, therefore, there really are no

problems, just political priorities.

Counter to all that are the people who hate science and technology. They

reason that science and technology got us into whatever fix we are in,

can only get us in deeper, and should now give way to other ways of

thinking and working in order to save our souls and our lives. They

ascribe to science a way of thinking which obliterates human

consideration. They ascribe to technology a way of working which

obliterates concern for nature.

To make the point of this book, it is necessary to oppose both those

views, the capitalist-socialist one and the hate-science and-technology

one.

The point is that there is no reason in nature, in organization, or in

science and technology for human beings to lead secondhand lives, under

second-party rules, in second-class communities. Instead, there is every

reason, if they choose to, that human beings can participate fully in

all the decisions that affect their lives, be responsible for their

lives, and with other human beings live in precisely the communities

suited to their capabilities and cares rather than bound to someone

else’s advantage or blueprint.

This hardly means a sort of reckless freedom of choice based only upon

desire. It does not suggest wishful thinking as the basis of society. It

is meant to suggest responsible capability as the basis. Freedom of

choice thus based means that when people choose the shape of community

they must also be prepared and be capable of building that shape. If the

choice is made in freedom and if others enjoy an equivalent freedom, it

means that the responsibility must be borne by those directly involved

and cannot be fulfilled by denying freedom to others. Freedom of choice

that suggests the freedom to deny freedom is, except for debating teams,

an obvious travesty.

Freedom of choice otherwise just might be the death of a free society.

If, as it surely has, freedom of choice has come to mean freedom to

choose between already existing situations in the development of which

you were not directly involved, then it does not reflect a free society

at all but rather an ordered society.

Freedom to create would seem to me a better demand for a free society,

even the necessity to create, the necessity to make choices by actually

making actions rather than just by picking “products,” whether social or

concrete.

America today is a technologically backward nation. It has a lot of

technology. But the technology is largely frivolous, serving corporate

caprices.

Technology has become very much like politics. There is a lot of

it—technology and politics everywhere, in every nook and cranny of our

lives, in every ticking second of our times. But the politics is

frivolous too. It serves the urges of the two major political parties,

the egos of the principal players in them, and the big businessmen who

pay for it all out of profits made from the use of the technology!

The situations really do go together. The kind of technology that is

possible, and which would suit the old yearnings of the American Dream,

is exactly the kind that would undermine the sort of spectator-sport

politics we have come to play. It would be a technology in which

ordinary people participated very actively. It would be a tool to serve

their purposes and make possible the kinds of lives they (and not

Madison Avenue fantasists) want to live. Having a role in the

development, deployment, and maintenance of technology, wouldn’t people

also want more of a role in politics? Wouldn’t they want a politics that

makes possible a democratic life rather than a politics that makes

necessary a life subordinated not to politics but to politicians?

In politics a person is not a citizen if the person’s only function is

to vote. Voters choose people who, in turn, act like citizens. They

argue. They establish the forms within which people live their lives.

They make politics. The people who merely vote for them merely make

politicians.

People who argue for their positions in a town meeting are acting like

citizens. People who simply drop scraps of paper in a box or pull a

lever are not acting like citizens; they are acting like consumers,

picking between prepackaged political items. They had nothing to do with

the items. All they can do is pick what is. They cannot actively

participate in making what should be.

In technology there is the same thing. To be merely a consumer of

technology is always to accept and take what is and never to shape what

could be.

Invention, science, the arts, civil life—all can be enjoyed at smaller

levels of social organization, at the community level. Much of the best

we have ever enjoyed in all those fields comes from small, not large,

arrangements of work, research, education, and society.

Personal security, that great hobgoblin which often scares people into

giving up freedom for some claimed increase in safety, can actually be

provided more satisfyingly and more surely at smaller levels of

arrangements, particularly at the community level. Even the security of

a major geographical area, covering literally thousands of communities

the size of a modern nation-state, could be provided in a military sense

at a level of organization perhaps a tenth as great as the one which

today threatens to engulf us in a regimented society without the enemy

having fired a shot or issued an order.

I make an assumption in all this: Most people would prefer to live in a

social setting where they know their neighbors, enjoy their work, and

have a full voice in discussing the terms under which the work is done

and the living is lived. I have another assumption that attaches to

that: Such arrangements are structurally impossible in some social

organizations. The point at which the scale changes is simply the point

at which the purposes of all the people involved or the purposes of the

institution and its institutional leaders become dominant. Numerical

size is no gauge to this. A Spanish trade union, the CNT, with a

membership of a million, once had only two paid employees. The purposes

of the members dominated. On the other hand, in some very small

communities, a single family or company may totally dominate. Generally

speaking, however, sheer scale does at least tilt things toward command

and away from democracy.

There is an obvious problem in imagining that the purposes of any group

of people, large or small, ever will be so constant as to enable

agreement and community. I for one do not imagine any such constancy.

The individual purposes and predilections of people in a community are

kaleidoscopic. However, if a basic purpose of the community is to be a

community, and if there is shared respect for the neighbors and the

neighborhood, then the multitude of other differences can be and will be

argued and resolved without tearing apart the founding purpose. In

short, it is the purpose of the community that undergirds the

proposition, not any supposition that there won’t be differences. If, of

course, the differences ever become so powerful that they challenge in

order to disengage. But then all you have is two communities, each still

presumably united at bottom by the same purpose as the old one—to have a

community of shared respect!

Another way of putting this is geometrically. If the organization,

regardless of numerical scale, is organized like a pyramid, with power

running down from the top, and obedience as the base, then the

administrative scale is big, a larger number of people controlled by a

smaller number. If the shape is spherical, with power adhering to all of

the particles in it, and with no way to establish an up-and-down order,

then the scale is small, with decision-making involving the smallest of

all social units, the individual, all of the individuals.

After the assumption that people do indeed want to live in a community,

rather than anonymously in some sort of social conglomerate, the

remainder of my arguments are not assumptions but practical

propositions. They are not based upon things that lie in the future, on

tools not yet discovered or used, on principles yet to be spelled out:

They are based on what we have and what we are today.

Still it seems discordant. If possible and practical, why not present

and palpable? If it isn’t just dreaming, then why does present reality

seem so immutable?

No doubt about it. There is, in any discussion of what could be, an

overwhelming sense of things as they are—and powerful variations on the

theme.

I often find myself asking why something isn’t done differently only to

hear the answer that:

if I have to explain it you wouldn’t understand anyway.

want responsibility.Because they aren’t smart enough.Because they’d

rather watch TV.Because “they” won’t let them.

Reality is defined in all of those propositions as “the way things are”

in a purely administrative sense. None of those propositions, not even

the one about human nature, describes any hard-and-fast material

reality.

Rules are made by people. People can change them—and not necessarily the

same people who made them.

The way things are done is often a result of habit, custom, or old

rules. Habits can be broken, custom that is not based upon some material

imperative can be changed.

Cost is a bookkeeping matter, it is the result of social agreements and

is not a part of the natural or material world. Costs are what a

particular value system says they are. Paying as much for a painting as

for the saving of a life is the result of a particular value system,

always susceptible to change, and not the result of something handed to

us by nature, physics, chemistry, biology, botany, physiology, or even

psychology. One person’s priceless psychological security is another

person’s wasteland.

Simplicity is not necessarily a curse. In the natural world simple

rather than complex answers are more the rule than exception. It would

be incredibly complex to ask the human mind consciously to direct the

functioning of all the bodily parts, even though it might be satisfying

to a certain managerial urge. On the contrary, the vital organs and the

cells generally operate pretty much on their own, doing their jobs so

long as they can without hierarchical structuring and coercion.

Photosynthesis (which simply is) is a lot simpler than having the

federal government or General Motors try to create nourishment from

scratch.

Complexity, on the other hand, is by now a familiar managerial defense

against anything in which there is a suggestion that people generally

can understand, operate, or change any process controlled by someone who

wants to keep the controls firmly in hand. (One reasonable response to a

claim of complexity is to ask for clarification.)

The imperious “you can’t” is just that, an exercise of authority and not

of reason. It is a part of reality in about the same way the Inquisition

was a part of religion. Again, it may be a “real” force, but it is a

force that emerges from human purpose—which is changeable—rather than a

material or natural imperative which might not be nearly so flexible.

(It is possible by an exercise of human purpose to stop using

petrochemicals as fuel. It is not possible by an act of human purpose to

extend the availability of such chemicals beyond their actual

availability in the natural world.)

Things that cannot be explained are things that cannot be explained and

need not detain anyone interested in reality unless that interest

focuses entirely on the inability of some people to say what they mean.

The idea that people can’t, won’t, or never have done something because

most people are this way or that sometimes seems at least rooted in

reality, unless you begin to recall that people have, over time, acted

in so many different ways and have, even over short times, changed in so

many ways as to seem to have almost limitless possibilities. Certainly

there is nothing to suggest that their ways of working and living

together are inscribed irrevocably in their DNA. If so, we could

scarcely discuss the matter at all.

The most acute part of my own reality problem lies in the suggestion

that “they” won’t let there be any change. We all define “them”

differently, of course. 1 am prepared to admit, as fervently as you

wish, that there are some people who have mighty interests against

letting anything change and whose very life-styles are founded upon

putting down any upstart suggestions that might set the applecart to

wobbling. Some welfare recipients or pensioners can be understood as not

wanting anything to change because of a cynical conviction that it would

just get worse. The Rockefeller family hardly seems eager for change in

the world, unless it is simply a reinforcing of the vast system of

wealth which is their own welfare system, making it handily unnecessary

to work except as whim dictates.

But, understanding that to be a part of reality is a shallow thing if it

is not accompanied by a deeper appreciation of a reality in which all

the idlers on earth—to continue with that example—do not amount to any

great numerical shakes. The reality is that when most people want

something to change it will change. A few muttering malcontents could

scarcely stop it, particularly if the muttering comes from people who

are clearly not among the most energetic or creative but actually the

least, as is the case of the idle rich or the given-up poor.

Much of the criticism leveled against this book will call it

“unrealistic” dreaming.

Accepted. If the real world is only the world of administrative

decision, then I do have a reality problem and am properly disregarded

as a simple ass braying in a distant boony. If, however, the real world

is based not altogether upon desire but also upon material reality—and

what we know of it, such as physics and chemistry, etcetera, and what we

think of it, such as poetry and philosophy—then administration may be

seen as merely one sort of effective opinion and not a “law of nature”

after all.

If that is the case, and this book will try to make it, then the

criticism of these speculations as unrealistic should be changed to

saying that they are merely unpopular. And that in turn might be

modified by saying, Unpopular right now but maybe not tomorrow.

Chapter 2: Why Community Technology

Local liberty is the heart of community. A community without liberty is

just a bunch of people living in the same area—a sort of arrangement all

too familiar in the suburbs, for instance.

The community without liberty must accept what is given. Its boundaries

are not merely geographic, they are legalistic, even cultural. Some

power outside of the community is in control.

Take one of the slick, sleek new planned communities. They are

prepackaged, processed, and perfected before anyone moves in. The mix of

incomes has been set by the range of prices or rents. The paths, byways,

stores, working places— even the mood produced by architectural styles

and building placement, by wooded areas, water, and recreation—all have

been established. People do not move in to form a community, to be part

of a community of their own contriving; they simply move in. What is

meant to pass for the community is already there, planned and put into

place by people who need not live there.

A community that richly reflects the aspirations, capabilities, and

social agreements of the people living there would, by definition, have

to be one they built, one in which there is the liberty to make the

community and not just move into it.

After the building there must be the liberty to maintain or change it as

the successive generations of the people involved decide. That process

thrives best where the community was founded in liberty. It starts a

good habit. Made-to-a-mold places do not.

The disappearance of community, particularly in city life— where

neighborhoods once were strong communities but where only a few still

survive—involves points which are popularly made against neighborhoods

and against community.

Small-scale social organizations, such as neighborhoods or other

community structures, are said to be inefficient, they are said to be

unable to provide civil rights (or unwilling to), and they are said to

be impractical in purely material terms.

The argument of efficiency has already fallen of its own bureaucratic

weight and is taken seriously only by those desperately hanging on to

traditional power, such as the politicians of New York City or, for that

matter, of all other megacities.

Efficiency arguments once included every phase of civil life. It was

supposed to be cheaper to have a big city than a little one because the

administrators could purchase supplies in such large and economical

batches. But the cost of the purchasing process itself and the cost of

storage and the cost of distribution have begun to wipe out the claimed

savings.

Large police forces were thought to be more efficient and effective than

small ones. Today in most major cities the most innovative and the most

familiar changes in police forces are those which return the individual

patrolmen to neighborhood beats and which try to establish precincts as

parts of neighborhoods. The most highly praised force in the country,

that of Los Angeles, has made neighborhood emphasis the central theme of

crime prevention and detection. An in-depth study of citizen reaction to

police organizations made at Purdue found the clearest evidence that

people prefer police organizations which are close rather than remote,

scaled to fit into the community rather than scaled to stand over it.

And even though the FBI’s justly famed crime laboratory is clearly a

central facility, the bureau’s skill at what it does most usefully,

catching ordinary rather than political criminals, depends to a large

degree upon its widely decentralized system of field offices, its

neighborhood agents, you might say. And those field offices, in turn,

operate most effectively when they do not have to spend long hours

catering to the whims of the central bureaucracy, as they often did in

soothing the political rashes of J. Edgar Hoover.

Large-scale welfare systems, as common sense should have suggested at

the very outset, can never operate as effectively as can a local

charity—where needs are known, where caring is personal and not cool and

remote.

Large-scale health facilities (sickness facilities, really) such as the

great teaching hospitals can render spectacular care if a person is

suffering from something interesting, yet may not have room for the

person with a commonplace affliction. Also, the price of caring for

patients in large facilities is all-of-a kind, no matter the affliction,

and that price is notoriously high. Already, the first rumblings of

demand for a community-scaled localized sort of health care are being

heard. Home care could, in fact, meet the needs of many patients, given

a medical profession that was itself sufficiently decentralized and not

drawn to the convenience of assembly-line hospitals— convenience, and

easier profits.

Paramedics, nurses, the relatively new nurse practitioners with their

advanced and specialized training, and other not quite doctors also

represent a useful and common-sense decentralizing influence in health

care—and a direction toward community-scaled localized services. Such

services, incidentally, need not, without other cause, mean the end of

the large teaching hospitals. But they could indicate an important

movement against the tendency of big hospitals to substitute themselves

for all health facilities in a given area.

Educational efficiency is now farcical in terms of large-scale

operations. The more money that has been spent on big buildings, the

tinier the results in terms of well-rounded, literate children. The fact

of the matter now is that large consolidated schools are often defended

publicly more for their effectiveness in providing hot sports teams than

for any educational reason. Education has moved from performance and

productivity into the style of a spectator sport; what is done in the

school is not as important for some people (particularly those people of

a booster or Chamber of Commerce mind-set) as what is seen. Looks are

more important than brains in such a mind-set with, unfortunately,

considerable justification. The Chamber of Commerce, in short, knows

that other businessmen looking for a town will not be so much concerned

with the true social character or possibilities as with the kinds of

illustrations that can be put in a brochure to lure employees, who also

will be felt to be tuned to style and fashion and surface appearance

rather than to material reality. What business, for instance, would

extol the value of an area’s schools in terms of describing excellent

individual teachers when it can simply choose to show a picture of

excellent buildings? Style is, after all, the basis of much business—so

why not the basis of social attraction as well? And, of course, it is.

It seems to me that the most powerful thing that the argument regarding

the inefficiency of small-scale organization has going for it is the

pervasive mood of consumerism in the country.

New consolidated schools, new towns, and most new prepackaged social

offerings depend on a consumerist mood and mode. In fact, the major

argument overall for favoring big organizations over small ones is that

the big ones do make it easier for people to be passive; that is, they

depend on delivering entire life-styles and not just single products.

People are said to desire this. In this perception, progress is in part

the ability to escape “doing” things (action) so that people can have or

enjoy things (objects).

The new town, in its most flamboyant modern form, does not simply say as

did older subdivisions, Come here to buy a house; it says, Come here to

buy a way of living, a way already defined and extolled in four-color

brilliance. One town may be for the “modern couple,” another for “young

families,” another for “the man on the way up,” still another for “the

leisure years.” The automobile makers do not say, as did the elder Henry

Ford, Here is transportation that you may buy; they say, Here is an

entire self-image to buy, one which, incidentally, provides

transportation when the traffic isn’t too heavy. Buick Skylarks, for

instance, are for “free spirits”; Cadillacs are for those who have

“arrived.”

Television is a notable example and in all probability a notable

contributor. Radio skits and sketches used to provide information and

suggestions, but the listener had to provide the context and the texture

in his or her own mind. Television, as the American philosopher Marcus

Raskin has put it, actually colonizes that inner refuge of the person,

the person’s own dreams, packaging and processing an entire image

structure for people who, if they wish, may simply consume visually an

entire world of action. And they need never move. Or act. They can just

be.

In great cities where neighborhoods have vanished, passivity applies to

most phases of life except moving from one consumed entertainment to

another. Neighborhood life, by contrast, has traditionally been a

structure woven from the participating activities of everyone on the

street, from the hawkers of wares and the conversational clumps, to the

watchers at the windows, to games, art, and celebration.

There is about a small-scale organization with an overall emphasis on

productivity rather than consumption. The nonproductive stand out more

sharply, if nothing else. The person who will not be part of local life

cannot enjoy the easy anonymity of a faceless, larger social setting. It

does not mean that a person may not in a neighborhood be totally

withdrawn. It just means that there is general awareness of the

withdrawal, which certainly seems fair to the neighborhood as a whole

and certainly is not unfair to the person who has withdrawn. It might be

unkind in the minds of some, scarcely unfair. Only a hermit may

reasonably expect anonymity. Curious, active people have no use for it.

Anonymity is one of those “rights” of large-scale social organization

that has a double function. It keeps people compartmentalized, and thus

at the mercy of the social organization rather than as cooperating

actors in it. It makes it possible to evade responsibility, to be an

isolated cipher in a social setting, to have at best a sort of

hit-and-run relationship with the social world around one.

Another virtue of anonymity, so ingenious as to deserve attention, is

that ascribed to it by the liberal journalist Henry Fairlie. In his

moving and justly famed defense of the American supermarket as a

pinnacle of human achievement, Fairlie points out that in a supermarket

the consumer, guaranteed anonymity by the mass traffic, may indulge

whatever food folly he or she may wish without drawing the attention of

a buttinsky neighbor who might laugh, scoff, or scold. Fairlie does not

trouble himself with examining the other side of that coin: that such

anonymous, isolated, impulsive buying of foolish food also permits

manufacturers to sell products that provide no nourishment, often are

injurious, and would probably be laughed at or scorned out of town if

ever discussed openly with friends and neighbors. But, most importantly,

the foolish anonymous buyer is not so much exercising a right as simply

buying a poor product. I don’t question one’s right to buy a foolish or

dangerous product. I question a manufacturer’s decency, ethics, and

claims to be a part of the community in profiting from poor products.

From the anonymity-passivity position, finally, comes the basic canard

against people delivered with smug assurance by the defenders of

large-scale organizations. People, they say, do not want to do things

for themselves, think things through for themselves, go to meetings, be

part of a community, and so forth. People, they say, are sheer appetite.

This does not include the people making the charge, of course. They are

hardworking, responsible, eager for challenge, always wanting to do

more. They are people, the implication is, while we are slugs.

The woman to whom a TV ad says, You are what the shine of your dishes

is, is being told this. The voter who is told that only by electing

better leaders can things be accomplished is being told this.

And always the refrain: You are a consumer, somebody else is a producer.

Production is not a community matter; it is an “expert” matter, best

left to managers and politicians.

Materially and otherwise, that attitude is a deadly mistake. Discussion

of the material side of it will occupy much of this book.

Productivity in community terms is a social activity, not always just a

material one. People talking together are productive of a community of

shared information. The watchers from the windows may be productive also

of information that may be shared. Not to slight material productivity

at all, but a major productive activity in a local setting is the

sharing of information. It is one of the ways that a neighborhood stays

aware of itself and thus stays a neighborhood. This may seem a praise of

gossip. It is. Gossip is the mews and the chronicle of the commonplace,

the everyday, the shared information about what is going on where we

are. It is not necessarily inaccurate, any more than any other type of

information must be inaccurate. It can be, depending on the motives of

the people involved; it can also be accurate and incisive, depending on

those motives. However, to call what Walter Cronkite mouths “The News,”

as though there is no other, and to call the talk in a neighborhood mere

gossip is to prefer life in the clouds to life on the ground. A major

possibility in a free society, it seems to me, would be to reverse

things so that the most important news would be the real news of real

possibilities right where we live. News of other communities could be

informative and helpful, but it would not be, as it is now, the news.

The consumerist aspect of so many large-scale organizations has an

internal reflection as well. Inside of large-scale organizations after a

time there seems an inevitable development in which people begin to

succeed by being consumers instead of producers.

Successful junior executives consume, in effect, the styles of

successful superiors, add to them ideas brought from fashionable

consultants, and then advance on the basis of those consumed activities.

The original executive—the one with an experimental mind and with

experiments in mind, the producer—becomes the target of all the others,

is seen as a great rocker of boats, and his every daring action is

watched not for success but for failure. There is another way in which

the large industrial and business corporations have themselves become

consumerist in nature. They grow, characteristically, by acquiring, by

consuming other successful and innovative organizations—smaller

organizations. They do not grow by producing. They grow by consuming.

They do not add new knowledge so much as they just add new mass.

The essence of consumerism is that those caught in its grasp behave as

though the ability to purchase is in fact an ability, a manifestation of

merit, of expertise, and, further, they behave as though what they

purchase actually confers upon them real characteristics, actually

defines them as human beings. We are, the consumerist credo goes, what

we buy.

The official, or Nader, version of consumerism simply feeds the fire.

The Nader approach, no matter its decent motives, also sees people as

defined by what they buy; it sees buying as the most significant

activity of most people and thus feels that to protect their purchases

is a major good.

The alternative, which is emphasized by a participatory community and by

the sort of technology appropriate to it, is to see the human role of

production as crucial and to regard the work people do as far more

significant than the things they buy. In short, consumerism regards

people as appetite; community regards people as creativity.

The argument against community in terms of efficiency, therefore,

finally boils down to the components of efficiency itself. If efficiency

is seen wholly in terms of satisfying the consumerist mode of human

life, then the anonymous city (where a person may consume anything

without appearing foolish or profligate to nosy neighbors) is a splendid

milieu, the production-line factory a splendid workshop, and

gadgetglitter technology a titillating glory. If, on the other hand,

efficiency is seen as the way in which a situation reflects the creative

mode, the community mode, the human being as active and not passive,

then smaller-scale ways of living together and working together may be

viewed as serviceable.

All of this reflects the difference between an overall concept of rights

and of responsibilities. Rights are administrative; they are legal or

even legalistic statements deriving from an institution of power.

Responsibilities are perceived, necessary ways of behaving.

In nature there are no rights. No creature has a right to anything, no

blade of grass, no anything. That is, all life in a material sense

involves not the rights of creatures or cells but the nature of

creatures, plants, cells. Cells behave in certain ways.

They do not proclaim a right to do this or that; it is just what they

do.

Human beings, no matter how complex an agglomeration of cells they may

be, also have certain natural functions which cannot be modified by

statements but are inherent and natural.

There is, in the natural order, no absolute right to life, to

sustenance, to shelter, to anything. Human beings do not provide or

produce any of those things by right. They produce them by action. They

come from concrete conditions and actions, Part of the process, of

course, may (and usually does) involve abstraction, analysis, and

theory; but only the active application of those interior actions in the

exterior world produces anything—poems, philosophy, gears, wheels, or

transistors.

Take a person in the wilderness, or alone in a room. The person has no

rights at all, it may be said that he or she has a right to live. But

that right cannot be exercised except by action. The person, or some

person, or some something has to do something. Otherwise, if the person

in the wilderness will not pluck a berry, the person will starve. If the

person in the room will not call out, will not move, that person will

starve. And the room, incidentally, could not have been built by a

proclamation of right, it had to be built by an application to materials

of energy and knowledge.

Yet we know that there are rights. Everybody talks about them.

Precisely. Rights derive from talk, from human talk, from human

agreement. All rights are social in nature. There can be purely

theoretical rights, of course. They exist in a person’s head. They

cannot exist outside of that head except by talk and by agreement—or by

force.

Happily, there are ancient agreements about rights. The common law

represents such an ancient agreement regarding such things as the right

to protect oneself against murder and theft and the right to punish

those who violate that right. Constitutions like that of the United

States represent, if not ancient agreements, at least respectable

elderly ones. Yet, in every constitution that provides for judicial

interpretation (actually it can also be reinterpretation) of the

constitutional agreements, there is copious demonstration of the fact

that those rights are not only what people generally say they are but

they are most forcefully exactly what some people say they are. In this,

the most palpably free nation-state on the face of the earth, that is

nevertheless an obvious fact of civil life. Rights today are what the

state says they are. If or when rights are seen as what people other

than the leaders say they are, the occasion is known as a revolution.

Revolution, as most familiarly defined by today’s right and left, is the

substitution of bosses, one for another. Their revolutions seek to

maintain the system of top-down leadership, of elite control of the

masses, citizens, or whatever you call them. They seek only to change

the personnel at the top.

Some, of course, are benevolent, even kindly. Candidates for the

American presidency speak of leading the people, through hard times for

instance, to a brighter tomorrow, Commissars just lead; they don’t have

to explain.

Benevolent or malevolent, the top commands; the rest follow or at least

are expected to.

Could it be otherwise? Doesn’t someone always have to lead? Don’t most

people want to follow? Isn’t it more efficient that way? Isn’t it, in

fact, the way things have always been, part of human nature?

The answers, I think, are yes, no, no, no, and no.

In arriving at the answers, the question of scale becomes, to me,

crucial. The scale at which people can participate in making the

decisions that affect them is a scale acceptable to and nourishing of a

free society. Scales beyond that just naturally are conducive to, at

best, representative forms, in which the most one can hope for is a

chance to pick someone to make the decisions. At worst, of course, even

that choice is denied. But in either case decisions are made remote to

the discussion of all the people affected.

The difference lies in whether or not we wish to live by coercing or

exploiting others. To live by leeching off others requires some very

strict social controls and arrangements. We have such arrangements and

controls today. Under them, most people have to conform strictly to

conventional wisdom and to conventional standards in order that a

few—the ones who make the rules—can live pretty much as they wish. Yet

even the people who make the rules are to an extent constrained by them.

The masters and the slaves always have been chained one to another in

some way.

A different way of living is to live in freedom by cooperating with

others so that the rules of your lives together are set by yourselves.

If those are the terms under which you want to live, there is no

material reason for you not to do so.

The rules and imperatives that conventional wisdom has imposed on us so

far are not binding except to the extent we permit them to be. We

acquiesce to the rules, literally. Nature does not force us. We

volunteer.

The scale at which goods that are needed for a healthy, pleasant life

may be produced can be reduced to a community level.

If production can be reduced to a community level, so can social

arrangement. Community, not nation or corporation, could be the basis of

social life, permitting all those affected by decisions to be

participants in those decisions. Democracy, which is often sacrificed

for imagined efficiency, can be efficient as a way for people to live

together, even if it is cumbersome.

It is possible for people in their communities to develop, to deploy,

and to maintain the sort of technology, tools, aids, and techniques that

will permit them to live as they wish—so long, of course, as they don’t

wish to live in a way that requires the coercion of others. Today’s

technology, in fact, works the other way. It permits a relative few to

live the way they wish by fastening rules and regulations on everybody

else. The executives of General Motors do not have to punch a time clock

precisely because all of the people who design and make the products do.

The Du Pont families can live pretty much as they please so long as all

the people who could make a particular synthetic fiber behave as though

the Du Pont family owns that particular combination of chemicals and

that no one else is entitled to it without permission and so long as the

people who buy the fiber believe that it is essential to their lives and

that the only way to get it is to buy it.

Ways of living should and can reflect the culture of communities and not

be established for communities by others. Again, the Morgans and the

Mellons and the Rockefellers can establish precisely the ways of living

they wish to enjoy in large part because they can also heavily influence

the ways of living in other communities. The Rockefeller children can

all go to private schools; the Rockefeller Foundation will spend

millions making sure that the other children on the continent, if not

the entire world, go to schools owned and operated by the nation state

and dedicated to the proposition that most children (excepting those of

the rich and powerful) must fit into the way things are.

Communities, however, cannot exist apart from nature. They are part of

nature, even though their location in the midst of cities sometimes

obscures the fact. A major way in which humans relate to the natural

world is through technology—the development and use of tools to utilize

natural resources for human purposes. A neighborhood needs technology

exactly appropriate to its scale of social organization and to its human

purpose. If a neighborhood is totally dependent on outside institutions

for technology it will be shaped in large part by the purposes of those

institutions rather than by the purposes of the neighborhood’s citizens.

The need for neighborhood people to become involved in technology is

similar to the need of neighborhood people to become involved in social

and political action. The first step is to demystify the subject. In

politics this means demystifying the idea that “they” always must do

things. In fact, “we must do them. In technology this means demystifying

the idea that all technology is beyond ordinary understanding and that

neighborhood people must simply accept what “they” give us. Again, we

must begin to produce our own. This includes even science itself, the

discovery of the principles upon which technology is based, as in such

American ideas as the colonial associations in which craftsmen supported

and engaged in scientific research. The prestigious Franklin Institute,

whose members once supported Franklin’s pioneering work on electricity,

is an example. Today at the Institute for Local Self-Reliance basic

research is being done by people in the neighborhood.

There is great difficulty, however, in convincing people that they can

get involved with subjects that have for so long been deliberately

obscured and made to appear too complex for local action.

A special point should be made about education. Young people in a

neighborhood would be better served by apprentice training in

neighborhood enterprises than by most present day schools, where,

instead of common-sense natural ways of thinking, they are afflicted by

highly obfuscated and regimenting instruction.

The most powerful point to be made for community technology efforts is

that when people take any part of their lives back into their own hands

for their own purposes, the cause of local liberty is advanced; and such

liberty, in turn, seems the strongest base on which to found a decent

culture of mutual aid and humane purpose. In such a revolutionary change

toward a free society of volitional social arrangements, liberty would

have to be defined, agreed to, and made real locally, in communities.

For that is where people live.

Chapter 3: Politics Versus Community

Local liberty has been attacked most specifically in political terms.

Local interests are said to be too narrow for national goals. Local

life-styles are said to be too disparate for national homogeneity. Local

resources are said to be too uneven for national “fairness.” People

where they live are assumed to be untrustworthy. Thus politics becomes,

and indeed is, the politics of the world where people do not live: the

politics of international business and expansionism and the politics of

abstract national goals.

Since this derives from political judgment, stemming from prevailing

national political power, it is a judgment that can be reversed,

altered, or simply forgotten. Local liberty, which was once an

attractive opinion, could become an attractive opinion again—so long as

it is considered, as with other politics, just a matter of opinion.

But are there areas of the concern that are not matters of opinion? Are

there aspects of local liberty which are rooted in the natural and

physical rather than social and political worlds?

Yes. Local liberty cannot be considered apart from the natural world. If

local liberty has no material base, then it ultimately has no base at

all. National political liberty—the freedom of national political

leaders to act—has such a material base.

For the generals it is the material base of nationally sponsored weapons

production, which, in material fact, gives them the physical power to

protect and extend political decisions. For the multinational

corporations it involves continued access to raw materials upon which

production may be based and flexibly moved hither and yon.

Unless localities could have an equivalent base in the material world, a

base that can literally support the freedom of local people to make

political decisions which affect their lives, then local liberty must

remain a mere administrative proposal, gauged roughly by the amount of

elbow room the local people are given by those who do have a base in the

material world from which to exercise power.

At first glance, the prospects of a material base for local liberty seem

so slim that it is understandable that arguments about it are usually

political arguments, involving the convenience of higher power in

“letting” some power rest at a local level.

As a matter of fact, so powerful has been the assumption that there is

no base in the material world for local liberty that the development of

political institutions has moved away from local liberty toward ever

more centralized and remote power, despite the failures of centralized

and remote political institutions.

The remedy for the collapse of big institutions has been seen as simply

the building of even bigger institutions. One important reason for this,

I suggest, is that it is assumed that local liberty is simply

impractical as well as being politically undesirable. In short, why try

it when it is totally unrealistic? How could a neighborhood do what a

city cannot?

The assumption is rash and uninformed. And, as are so many decisions in

politics, the assumption is contrary to and even hostile to scientific

knowledge and technological developments.

One seemingly sound base for the assumption, however, is the matter of

food. A city neighborhood, seen as a concrete bound ghetto, scarcely

seems worth considering agriculturally. True enough. Agriculture and

city spaces are apparently incompatible. Gardening and city spaces are

not.

Can gardening produce ample food for a neighborhood?

Hydroponic gardens in small greenhouse enclosures produce vegetables at

a rate many times greater than ordinary agriculture. In one notable

example, ten acres of greenhouses produced two million pounds of

vegetables annually at a cost of twenty cents per pound, including the

amortization of the structures, the desalting of water (it’s a seaside

operation at Abu Dhabi on the Persian Gulf), administration, etc. The

most interesting point about such projects is that they can easily be

subdivided, with the greenhouse becoming roof-sized and still yielding

high growth in proportion to space allocated. City rooftop spaces, plus

vacant lots or even the centers of streets, could be used to grow ample

vegetables for a local population. The Institute for Local

Self-Reliance, in Washington, D.C., maintains a good example. This is

not to say that any neighborhood would not want to supplement local

vegetables with those grown by other, distant communities. They surely

might. And that in turn just means that neighborhoods also have an

inherent capacity to engage in “foreign trade.”

Herd animals such as beef cattle are clearly inappropriate to city

neighborhoods. Chickens and fish are just as clearly appropriate.

Aquaculture—growing fish in artificial settings— can produce high yields

of high-quality protein in basement spaces. In one experiment undertaken

by the author and associates, an inner-city basement space, roughly

thirty by fifty feet, was sufficient to house plywood tanks in which

rainbow trout were produced at a cost of less than a dollar per pound.

In a regular production run the total number of fish that can be raised

in such a basement area was projected to be five tons per year.

In these discussions of material aspects of local liberty, it is freely

given that simply realizing a technological possibility does not

inevitably make an inevitable social decision to adopt it. That remains

a political and a cultural discussion.

But—the decision to oppose local liberty or to adopt it is a decision.

It is not a part of nature. The material base for local liberty does

exist.

Problems of waste disposal also have undoubtedly contributed to the

assumption that there is no material possibility for local liberty. A

city waste sewerage system, indeed, would seem to defy any ability of a

single neighborhood.

At the very least it can be assumed—and, I feel, justifiably—that a

neighborhood would have to join with all contiguous neighborhoods to

duplicate or even maintain the usual city sewerage system. And having

done that, it might be argued, why not let “nature” take its course and

just stay together for all other purposes as well?

Why bother about liberty? (That, of course, requires an answer in

ethics. 1 will continue with emphasis on the material.)

City waste sewerage systems are wasteful, unnecessary, often dangerous,

and certainly technologically backward. Neighborhoods are hooked into

them because of history, not because of any current necessity. First of

all, waste is not a problem, it is a resource. City waste systems simply

ignore this. They waste the waste. In-house waste-digestion systems, now

commercially available at costs as low as a thousand dollars, will

convert all human and kitchen wastes into an odorless fertilizer. Some

provide modest amounts of heating gas as they do it. (The average family

could do all its cooking on the gas produced by its own waste.)

Variations of waste-digestion systems for single dwellings could include

processing plants to serve an entire neighborhood housed in an abandoned

dwelling or the basement of an apartment house. The money used now to

maintain, replace, and expand existing systems could be directly

converted to the permanent solution offered by digestion systems. (Storm

water, now carried through huge pipes to nearby streams, could instead

be stored under a neighborhood or in a neighborhood “lake.”)

Manufacturing today is thought of as a massive large-scale system by

advocates of massive large-scale ownership.

It is assumed that it is appropriate to our needs mainly because of

assumptions about those needs: quickly obsolescent products,

package-emphasizing products, and proliferating fad products.

In point of material fact, manufacturing has undergone the sort of

technological change that has characterized all science-based activities

in this century—a distinct tendency toward decentralization and

small-scale units. A truly modern cybernated plant, turning out a vast

array of machine parts, for instance, can be housed easily in a city

neighborhood, in conventional office space. It uses computers to direct

its tools, and can be handily operated by workers trained in the

neighborhood. Transistors, the heart of electronics, are extremely

demanding of material quality and specialized tooling-up but are also

quite adaptable to small-scale local production. Plastics, which have

got such a bad name because of their use in disposable containers,

actually include some of the finest building materials known, permanent

materials far stronger than steel, and they can be fabricated in

small-batch operations. Even steel production has undergone a distinct

shift toward smaller-scale facilities, such as continuous slab casting.

Raw materials, of course, are not usually appropriate to neighborhood

production—city neighborhoods, that is. Most raw materials, however, are

produced in such highly localized situations (a mine, for instance, or a

group of oil wells) that it could be said they represent

neighborhood-scale activities at a far distance.

If the raw materials are forever consigned to central buyers or to

central governments, then their use as neighborhood resources will

remain also at a far remove. There is no technically compelling reason,

however, that the neighborhoods that produce raw materials could not

trade those raw materials more directly with neighborhood refining

facilities or with facilities maintained by groups of neighborhoods.

Energy production is strikingly adaptable to neighborhood scale. Solar

energy, economically collectable as heat, could provide at least half of

the cooling and heating requirements of any inner-city neighborhood.

Photovoltaic cells that directly convert solar to electrical energy are

on the verge of manufacturing breakthroughs that could make them the

cheapest, most decentralizing power source yet.

Transportation within neighborhoods generally is seen as merely an

extension of the transportation demands not of citizens but of

corporations. Yet the two demands are different. Corporate

transportation need not occupy the total travel space of a neighborhood.

Most citizen travel is of short duration and is ideally suited to

electric vehicles. These vehicles in turn are simply built and also

quite adaptable to the most localized production facilities. General

Motors boasts that its Basic Transportation Vehicle can be built in a

space the size of a barn and for a total capital investment of $50,000.

Run by an electric rather than internal combustion engine, the BTV, or

something like it, could serve most of the transportation needs of any

American neighborhood. It could also be built there.

The most vital of city services, police and fire protection, have always

been thought of as highly localized in nature. Firefighting facilities

are not concentrated in some super firehouses. They are spread as widely

as possible, and the wisdom of this policy is rarely questioned. Police

protection, when centralized and withdrawn from a neighborhood setting,

as has now been widely recognized, results in disadvantages rather than

economies of scale. A desire to return to neighborhood-based protection

is evident in most cities. Central laboratory facilities for the police

might not be economically duplicated in every neighborhood; but the

matter has been given little study, and with an increase in local

manufacturing skills there might not be as much difficulty in providing

each neighborhood with its own microscope, computer-held files, and so

forth, as might be imagined.

Health care, on the other hand, seems far more complicated, and the

current tendency to destroy small facilities in favor of huge

teaching-hospital empires might appear an argument against any

consideration of locally based health care. At the same time, however,

the common-sense emphasis on paramedical personnel to handle perhaps a

majority of everyday health problems and the equally common-sense

emphasis on citizen health awareness show a movement as strikingly

toward local centers. Although it is true that exotic ailments might not

be treated in good style in a local medical facility, it is also true

that most people do not require such service and that to distort an

entire technology for the least rather than for the greatest needs seems

a questionable practice.

Simply reinstituting the practice of house calls by physicians would,

probably, eliminate the need for a majority of today’s centralized

medical facilities.

Communications and information systems are already involved in

technologies which are adaptable without any question to the most

localized uses. Virtually every neighborhood in America has within it

amateur communications technicians of reasonably high skill: ham radio

operators. Citizen-band radios further democratize the use of radio

communications. Further, the very scale of the neighborhood makes it

adaptable to communications of the most traditional kind—bulletin

boards, wall posters, signs, even town criers or sound trucks.

Newspapers on a community scale can be produced in small spaces and with

wise recycling of materials or even substitutions of materials (for

instance, material that can be quickly erased and re-used) or they can

be in electronic forms. Even the raw materials for print media could be

held fairly close to the possibilities of neighborhood self-sufficiency

and responsibility. The point is not that a neighborhood would thus

close itself off from all other communications. The point is simply that

the neighborhood can have internal communications sufficient to a fully

developed politics of internal freedom and could thereafter enjoy any

extended communications with a world of other communities that might be

desired.

Computers, of course, have made the storage and retrieval of information

a matter of the most drastically reduced scale. They are adaptable also

to local manufacture. They are perfectly suited to neighborhood use.

Used in neighborhoods, with local familiarity and control, the computer

might be seen as more of a tool than a weapon.

Even the problem of traditional information, exemplified in the library,

is solvable in a way most compatible with neighborhood scale. Microfiche

readers of great sophistication, but happily of reasonably

straightforward and small-scale manufacturing technique, mean that the

entire contents of the Library of Congress can be stored in a small

office space, taking up no more room than the pet food section of a

supermarket.

Since the material base of local liberty, and particularly the local

liberty of city neighborhoods, requires attention to the material world,

it necessarily involves science and technology. The potential for local

liberty of rural neighborhoods is scarcely arguable or, as a matter of

fact, often disputed.

Fortunately, most neighborhoods already have many citizens within them

who represent a scientific turn of mind and who are familiar with

various technologies. Again, it is from the realm of opinion, and not

the realm of material good sense, that we have derived the notion that

neighborhood “skills” must be administrative skills rather than material

skills. Material skills have for so long been accepted as merely the

purchased property of corporations and the state that seeing them as the

ordinary skills of ordinary people in ordinary settings may seem novel

or even unsettling.

But the fact is that there are craftspeople, technicians, and people

with general scientific training in most neighborhoods. A tool and skill

inventory of an urban neighborhood would be revealing and encouraging.

Local schools, of course, have science and shop teachers. The entire

life of the neighborhood is riddled with skills—putting things back

together, plugging them in, and so forth.

Also, it would scarcely seem reasonable to say that pursuit of actual

scientific knowledge (which at root involves what Albert Einstein called

“common sense carried to an extreme’) should be beyond neighborhood

people. If science is beyond them, or us, what can be in our grasp? Only

opinion? Only singing and dancing? At any rate, in discussing the

material base of local liberty, it would seem foolish to assume that

scientific knowledge is impossible to people simply because of where

they live! When a neighborhood is a university, nobody is surprised that

there are people in the neighborhood who understand plasma physics. Ten

blocks away there need be no more surprise if anyone wants to understand

plasma physics there. The problem is not that brains change when they go

across town but only that opportunities change. And, in a neighborhood

aware that much of its liberty depends upon prudential relationships to

the material and natural world, and understanding also that this

relationship is mediated through scientific knowledge as well as

political decision, it should be no great trick for people to acquire

the knowledge necessary to their civic needs.

In summary: The material base for local liberty exists. The decision to

have or not have local liberty is just that, a decision, a decision

derived from human will. Nature does not abhor liberty. It is rather

neutral on the subject, chaining most life forms to a totalitarianism of

instinct and reflex that makes liberty extraneous. Humans, however, have

choices. Humans speculate and analyze and deliberately change

environments. Humans make choices between those changes. And one choice

in nature is local liberty.

Chapter 4: Experiences in Adams-Morgan

Adams-Morgan is a small country afloat in a great city. It is a

neighborhood of some seventy blocks in the center—almost the exact

center—of Washington, D.C. The population is 58 percent black, 22

percent Latin American, 18 percent white, with the remainder mostly

Middle Eastern. It is a neighborhood in transition; as a small country,

it’s in decline.

For a while, during a rash and wonderful tilt at making itself a truly

participatory community, Adams-Morgan was a fascinating culture in which

to live. More recently it has become a prime target for speculative

selling and buying, a bullish market well beyond the means of the people

who first made it a good neighborhood. Its nature is slowly changing to

chic—from workshops to boutiques, from bars to cocktail lounges, from a

heady whirl with community government to the island life of townhouses

with barred windows and residents whose concerns are global, where, for

a time, they were local. If all goes as it now is going, soon it will

not even be a neighborhood, much less a small country. Adams-Morgan will

be just another place in Washington. An address. A fancy one.

For almost five years, Therese Machotka and I lived together and worked

with hundreds of people in the neighborhood striving for an entirely

different future. Some are still at it. We quit several years ago and

moved to West Virginia. What happened—and continues to happen—goes

something like this.

I spent my childhood in the neighborhood, got my first haircut in a

barber shop there that is now a locksmith’s shop, kissed my first girl

in the part of Rock Creek Park that borders Adams-Morgan. I had my first

fistfight under the bridge that carries fashionable Connecticut Avenue

safely past the northwest edge of the neighborhood and went to one of

the two schools from which Adams-Morgan derives its name.

After forty years or so I came back. What had been comfortably middle

class had become very lower class, a shambles about to become a slum.

But it was cheap—and it tolerated hippies both socially and

economically. This was the mid-1960s. The hippies who moved in were

mostly stoned, mostly exiles, mostly useless; and the neighborhood

slipped down another notch. Venereal disease went up. Panhandling became

the local growth industry, and welfare blacks and zonked-out whites

began to drink Ripple together and curse the dark night of colonialism,

oppression, and shortages of good hash and sturdy H.

By the late 1960s something began to stir in the debris. In the fashion

of the opening scene in 2001, some stoned-out hippie got sick of the

faucet dripping or the VW van not running—some minor calamity—and,

wonder of wonders, got straight long enough to fix it. Perhaps the

change began more subtly, perhaps it was more complex, or, at least,

perhaps some social jargonist could describe it that way. My own

experience was that it was fairly simple and direct. Somebody had to do

something. Someone did. It worked. And the world changed a little. Odd

jobs became a substitute for panhandling, and proved more productive.

How-to books began sliding self-consciously onto shelves alongside the

great mystics and the red-hot revolutionaries. And something very

important indeed began to happen to the residential warrens in which the

stoned citizens had compartmented themselves. They turned into working

communes, group residences with shared chores, aspirations, shared

values, and, very often, shared work.

By the end of the 1960s there were probably sixty to seventy-five

functioning communes in the neighborhood, and a burst of productive

energy emanated from them. A worker managed grocery store opened and

became an immediate success, a place to shop with good prices and a

good-natured persistence in nutritional education. Then a second one

opened. A newspaper popped up in the neighborhood, about the

neighborhood. Then a second one. A record store. Several bookstores.

Craftspeople, from potters to auto mechanics, began hawking their wares

from community billboards, tree posters, street corners. Musicians

rented a storefront and began nightly improvisational sessions—jazz,

rock, country, classical. Several graphic arts shops opened. A community

credit union was started. And, perhaps most important, a community

government proclaimed itself, called a meeting, and actually got off the

ground.

The community government rose, like everything else, from the rubble of

failures immediately past. Heretofore Adams-Morgan, neighborhood

organizations, and civic associations had simply sought to present

resolutions to the city government. None had dared the idea of being a

government.

At the first meeting to discuss something new, it was young white

products of the counterculture and the New Left (but mainly the

counterculture) who made the breakthrough. Rather than simply have

another neighborhood organization, why not go a step further? The step

was toward a town meeting. The idea was remarkably non-ideological,

considering that some of the proponents were burning inside with visions

of storming the Winter Palace, of looking like Lenin, of smashing the

oppressors, of this and of that. A town meeting, it was argued in

practical terms and, fortunately, in purely homely language, would

provide a forum in which people in the neighborhood could get together,

discuss their problems, discuss solutions, and then actually decide what

they themselves could do. This instead of just complaining to a

massively sluggish city bureaucracy.

The thing wasn’t even called a town meeting, It was called the

“Adams-Morgan Organization,” AMO. At its first meeting someone said that

the streets were dirty. Someone else suggested that we all get together

and have a clean-up day. The meeting agreed. Signs were mimeographed on

a church duplicator, paper donated by a neighborhood resident with a job

in a print shop. The neighborhood was saturated with the information

that AMO members (then only about 300) were going to sweep down the

neighborhood’s main street over the weekend.

About 200 people actually got out and swept. Probably almost all of the

neighborhood’s 40,000 total population at least heard about it. AMO’s

membership, based on a growing belief that it would be a doing and not

just a talking organization, began to grow. By the time we left, it had

passed 3000.

The town meetings, or “AMO Assemblies” as they were actually called,

were the most exciting political experiences I have ever had. After

tasting a participatory democracy, I would never want to trade it for a

merely representative one.

A small problem: Most of the participants in the assembly never thought

they had left a representative democracy. The idea of participation

versus representation did not jell for everyone.

There was an obvious cultural dimension to the problem. The

counterculture people were actually looking for a new way to make social

decisions and, specifically, a way to do it without social exploitation

of one group by another. The idea of a town meeting—with people who make

decisions being responsible also for carrying them out, and not merely

for getting someone else to do it—was understandable and inspiring to

them. One consequence was the counterculture types made up at least half

of every meeting.

Blacks in the neighborhood had a clearly different view. The rhetoric of

participation was accepted and so was the form. But the reality behind

it was not participation at all. It was power. Blacks, at least in that

neighborhood and at that time, were not interested in changing the way

social decisions were made. What they wanted was to have the power to

make those decisions—to have power in, not power to change, the system.

Whites who do not understand this can make fearsome mistakes in

assessing the meaning of black-white alliances for social change.

There was just as deep a cultural bias to the work that was of prime

interest to Therese and to me. We were among the most active

participants in the town meeting, to be sure, but the work that actually

preoccupied us had to do with science and technology. Not science and

technology in the abstract or globally or grandly. Science and

technology to fit Adams-Morgan precisely.

The interest derived from a scholarly project at the Institute for

Policy Studies, with whose work Therese and I had been associated. One

IPS project was to study and catalogue ways of life and social

agreements in which citizens were full participants and not just voters

at best and colonized subjects at worst.

Because the politics which Therese and I share emphasizes

decentralization, our work at IPS was directed toward seeing the extent

to which science, as a thinking process, and technology, as techniques

and tools, could be made part of and directly support everyday life.

Our unifying proposition was this: If there was to be a free society,

one in which people could be responsible for their actions, be

cooperative individuals rather than coerced corporate parts, there would

have to be a supporting material base. Freedom cannot float in the air

as mere theory. It must rest on solid earthy ground. The material base,

we felt, would have to be one in which people generally could develop,

deploy, and maintain the tools of everyday life and production,

directing them democratically rather than being directed by them. Such a

relationship to science and technology would have to have relevance to a

neighborhood. Our neighborhood was Adams-Morgan.

Our first step was just to meet and talk on a regular basis with others

who shared some part of our notion. We did it weekly, at first with a

half dozen people, a couple of engineers we had met through the peace

movement, some craft friends, and students. Others soon joined and soon

tired of talking. Therese and I were able to coax a neighborhood clinic

operated by Children’s Hospital into letting us have unused space in the

warehouse building they rented. Therese agreed to put most of her salary

as an editor into buying equipment and paying stipends for work. Our

talk group became a project that we called “Community Technology.”

Our weekly meetings continued, sometimes crowded with forty or fifty

visitors, as an information-sharing process. A young physicist with

superb general mechanical skills came on full-time for a subsistence

share of the money Therese made available. (I just covered our living

expenses by writing, welding, selling metal sculpture, and occasionally

lecturing.) Our experiments began.

Food, it seemed to us, was the place to start. What could be more basic?

Also, the idea of developing, deploying, and maintaining a technology of

food production in the middle of a city, and in a ghetto neighborhood at

that, seemed as stern a test of our general propositions as could be

imagined. The whole idea flew right in the face of conventional wisdom.

First there was the land problem. There’s no land for growing food in a

city. If there is any open space, it’s too much trouble. If you want to

be a farmer, go to the country. The arguments that outside critics

launched against our project were certainly varied. Neighbors on the

other hand often took the attitude that the idea was sort of crazy but

what the hell. One of our first mistakes probably took hold right there.

We began to confuse toleration of our work with actual support for it.

The land problem was easily solved. Food grows not in an abstraction

called “land” but in a reality called ‘someplace nutritious to put down

roots.” Space for this reality need be only that—space. We located a lot

of it. First the rooftops. The neighborhood is one of houses, typically

three-story row houses. The roofs are almost all flat. So are the roofs

of the apartment houses. On very strong roofs, organic soil can be

spread, or boxed, for growing vegetables. Therese and I grew such a

garden. Less sturdy roofs could accommodate the lighter demands of

hydroponic growing—cultivating plants in tanks of liquid nutrients or in

light sand, the nutrients seeping through it. Friends who began a

companion enterprise, the Institute for Local Self-Reliance, a still

growing and prospering activity, operated a hydroponic garden with

storybook success and wildly bountiful crops. They also managed to fill

virtually the entire neighborhood’s demand for bean sprouts from a

single basement facility.

More traditionally, we worked with kids in the neighborhood to establish

regular gardens in vacant lots and in any back-yard space that people

wanted to make available. The entire back lot of our warehouse was

covered with dirt that we begged from local excavators, and it became a

community garden. Also, using the vegetable wastes from several local

grocery stores, leaves from suburban lawns, and horse manure from a park

police stable, we maintained about ninety feet of compost pits behind

the warehouse.

To supplement the vegetable crop we looked around for a suitable meat

animal. Cows were out. Too big. Rabbits didn’t make it. Too cuddly.

Chickens wouldn’t do. Too noisy. How about fish?

One of our group, an organic chemist, was experienced in trout farming

and suggested that we work up some high-density indoor tanks for raising

that fancy fish.

Jeffrey Woodside, our resident physicist and jack-of-all-trades; his

immensely energetic friend Esther Siegal; our chemist, Fern Wood

Mitchell; and Therese built tanks of fiberglass-covered plywood,

arranged water recirculation with pumps from discarded washing machines,

and contrived filters for the fish waste made of boxes filled with

calcite chips (the standard marble chips sold in garden supply stores)

into which a few cups of ordinary vacant-lot soil had been poured to

provide a bumptious strain of nitrifying bacteria to feed on the ammonia

in the fish waste.

The bacteria kept the water clean, the pumps and some well-placed

baffles kept the tank water moving in a strong current, the fish (which

we first reared from eggs in ordinary aquarium tanks) swam strongly, ate

heartily of the commercial feed that we first used as a convenience, and

grew as fast as fish in streams. Surprisingly to us, the rate at which

they converted their feed to flesh was better than one ounce of fish for

each two ounces of food, about 500 percent more efficient than beef

cattle, and as good as that champion barnyard converter, the chicken.

Our installation, neatly tailored to urban basements, produced five

pounds of fish per cubic foot of water. A typical basement in the

neighborhood could produce about three tons annually at costs

substantially below grocery store prices.

A young stonemason in the group began experimenting with small

completely self-contained bacteriological toilets and had fair success

suggesting that any neighborhood could unhook itself from conventional

sewer systems and their inefficiency and pollution.

A marine engineer in the group, lately turned solar experimenter, built

a very effective solar cooker that tracked the sun automatically, cost

under $300 to build, and provided up to 400 degrees F. of cooking heat

on an indoor hotplate from energy collected by an outside mirror in the

shape of a three foot-long trough.

An elementary school science teacher built a solar collector out of cat

food cans that heated household air to about 120 degrees F.

The group generally began discussing the design of a shopping cart that

could be built in the neighborhood; a self-powered platform that would

handle most of the neighborhood’s heavy moving chores; a neighborhood

chemical factory to make household cleaners, disinfectants,

insecticides, and aspirin; and a neighborhood methanol plant to take

local garbage and turn it into a portable fuel with properties roughly

similar to gasoline.

We sought a grant from the National Science Foundation to start a

neighborhood science center in which people of the neighborhood could

work toward understanding the natural science of the neighborhood

itself, of the tool and technique possibilities, and of the appropriate

role of science and technology in the community. The NSF sent a

sociologist out to look us over and turned our application down cold. We

did not meet the government-approved definition of a neighborhood

self-help program. Even at NSF such programs are aimed at enhancing the

ability of neighborhood people not to produce their own wealth and

future but to better obtain welfare assistance.

Government programs aim at getting money for poor people. Our hope was

that knowledge would in the long run be more useful, provide more money,

and eventually strike at the system-causes of poverty. Government

believes that poverty is just a lack of money. We felt, and continue to

feel, that poverty is actually a lack of skill, and a lack of the

self-esteem that comes with being able to take some part of one’s life

into one’s own hands and work with others toward shared—call them

social—goals.

It will not be denied that ours was and remains a middle class attitude,

quite classical and thoroughly Western. It stands opposed to the elitist

notion of mandarins caring for benighted peasantry, an attitude that

prevails today in various modern trappings, among them enlightened

capitalism, state socialism, and welfare statism.

But so much for the big notions and nations.

It seems these same lines get drawn in the participatory neighborhood.

At assembly meetings, reports of our work were always greeted with

applause and great enthusiasm. We were a showcase bunch of wizards doing

wonderful far-out things. Our appeals for neighbors to join us in the

work—to help build, expand, improve the fish farm; to move the gardens

along; to experiment with new ways of growing; to start stores and even

factories based on our skills and tools—got choruses of “right ons” —and

no participants.

Instead, the heavy work of the assembly began to emphasize direct

appeals to government agencies and foundations for grants; there were

complaints about landlord abuses instead of plans to buy them out.

Meeting after meeting, for instance, the idea of pooling money was

brought up, pooling money to establish neighborhood ownership of key

properties, to provide homes for the evicted, to set new patterns of

ownership for a new kind of neighborhood. Plenty of “right ons.” No

cash. Was there any cash? Of course. Even people on welfare have

disposable incomes. The pool of money needed to buy our neighborhood

would have been relatively modest, the weekly equivalent of a carton of

cigarettes or a bottle of whiskey from each member of the assembly. Of

course, it would have meant sacrifice. Some of us have little enough

pleasure, and a smoke or a drink is to be treasured beyond all the

promises of paradise.

There were, in fact, jobs aplenty in the neighborhood. The District

government, sternly charged by federal authorities with making the

streets safe for visiting dignitaries, including congressmen and

bureaucrats, had decided that bribery was the best tool available for

getting young people off the streets. The District funded programs

through which teenagers could draw a minimum of $1.75 an hour for the

exertion of signing in in the morning and signing out in the afternoon.

There is no convincing evidence that this did anything to halt incipient

criminality. It seemed to me that it accomplished a great deal more in

terms of separating young people from the possibilities of

self-reliance. It anchored them more firmly to habitual dependence on

unearned incomes and thus on the people who dispense them—be they the

wielders of welfare programs or those less-willing providers, the

victims of larceny.

A question began nagging during a lot of our work and discussion: Was

our vision of neighborhood self-help crumbling along racial lines?

Are blacks particularly disabled when it comes to seeking alternatives

to welfare programs?

The Adams-Morgan neighborhood, like Washington overall, is certainly

black. The people who seemed to talk most about and do the least in

support of our group’s proposals were black. Young whites seemed to

respond more to skill- and production-centered activities. Those are

solidly middle-class values out of a primarily European culture. Blacks

have been the victims, rather than the beneficiaries, of both the values

and the culture.

Blacks think black, as they continually say. So black has come to mean

poor and oppressed. Black demands have come to mean black reparations:

to be given something rather than seeking the chance to do something.

Everyone in our largely white group deeply sympathized with the fact of

oppression. Some went further and supported the implicit strategy for

social redress through reparation rather than community renewal.

My problems and doubts began with my conclusion (shared in large measure

by Therese) that such a strategy was not only useless, it was unjust,

crippling, and ethically debilitating.

While nursing such doubts, the Community Technology work began to seem

quite different to me than it had at the beginning. First, it did not

seem to have any real relevance to what was happening in the

neighborhood. The hope that people would want to fashion new lives based

upon new knowledge and new skills seemed now very romantic and very

wrong. Desirable still, but at present hopeless.

There was another problem: crime. It too fell along racial lines.

At one AMO meeting a young white man reported a particularly vicious

hold-up, beating, and rape that had occurred at a communal house. Before

any discussion could get under way, he was asked the color of the

victims. White. He was asked the color of the attackers. Black. With

blacks in the majority, that particular meeting simply moved on to

another topic. Not another word of discussion was possible.

This typified a particularly destructive, if fashionable, impulse among

both blacks and whites to dismiss all discussion of crime as

oppressively racist, despite the fact that blacks are the principal

victims of black crime.

Another major victim of unchecked, because unmentionable, crime was the

AMO group itself. Keeping a typewriter available in the office was

always a rigorous exercise in security, and none too successful at that.

Money needed for a variety of things was eaten up simply replacing

ordinary equipment rather than attacking the roots of the problem with

the same energy so effectively mustered for battles with landlords and

sanitation and welfare services.

An inevitable result of an undiscussed rising crime situation was the

deterioration of the neighborhood and the easing of entry for the next

wave of residents, the ones who could afford better security and who did

not mind living in a small fortress so long as the address was

fashionable. It happened in Adams-Morgan.

But could neighborhood people have coped with crime? I certainly think

so. It would mean first coping with their own children, facing them

down, creating families that would absorb their energies and deserve

their loyalties. Not easy. Not likely.

And particularly not likely when parents are opiated by a welfare

existence, and where schools are simply disciplinarian baby sitters,

offering young people no creative alternative to violence as the way to

get out, to get up, to get even.

It was the growing crime and violence that finally ended our residence

in the neighborhood. After being robbed on the average of once every

sixty days or so, Therese, for one, felt terror at night in the

neighborhood. We both resented the continuing loss of things,

particularly since our income was roughly at the poverty level; but,

being larger and a male, I had not felt the terror. After a time,

Therese felt it sharply enough to leave. We moved to West Virginia.

Having been raised in rural Wisconsin, Therese found these hills

immediately hospitable in ways the city’s streets had never been. I

still love the city neighborhood but have also experienced a sort of

homecoming in these hills richer than I ever could have anticipated.

The neighborhood is still there, of course. So also are every — one of

the problems that we should have addressed more squarely during our time

with Community Technology. Or perhaps, from this new distance, I only

see them differently.

I do believe from my experience in the small workings of Community

Technology that even science can live in a neighborhood. Ordinary people

can get together to discuss physical principles just as well as they can

get together to discuss abstruse political principles in the fashion of

young radicals and young conservatives.

But the entire relationship of our work to the neighborhood suggests

something else in the short run: that the culture of poverty is not

easily diverted beyond itself. In that culture, immediate relief in

terms of program handouts is the “cure” too commonly prescribed. It

cannot easily be changed. It was not changed in Adams-Morgan over a

period of years despite some most adventurous experiments by highly

charged people. The culture of poverty will run its course. How long

that course is, I have no idea. I am convinced, however, that if the

culture of poverty is to be broken in any black neighborhood it will be

broken by black people, not by starry-eyed whites talking soul patter.

Coming from his Chicago base, Jesse Jackson lectured black Washington

teenagers on the need to learn skills rather than gripe endlessly about

feeling oppressed. He was virtually run out of town for his effort.

Still powerfully at large in the city is the attitude of a former

superintendent of schools, Barbara Sizemore, a vigorous opponent of

Jackson. To her, the entire problem is power, black versus white. She is

less interested in a freer or better world than in a black one. I recall

her once being quoted as advocating that black children should not even

study white subjects. And what are white subjects? Mathematics and

science. What should black children study? Those things that come

naturally—singing and dancing, perhaps. It sounds to me like an old and

foul joke.

The assembly, meantime, shows signs of attrition as the old idea of

representation begins to recover the ground lost to the experiment in

community participation. The assembly has become more a bandstand for

aspiring politicians than a forum for people. To still dream of

something entirely different requires the understanding that this kind

of subversion is likely to happen time and time again.

While the assembly was occupied mainly with local problem solving, and

before conventional constituency politics overcame it, it was greatly

effective. People who had been shy spoke out. People who had seemed

without hope sparked to new life.

Meantime, a similar and sad malady has affected some of the

worker-managed enterprises that brought the neighborhood to life in the

first place. The malady is ideology. For several years the workers in

the enterprises toiled hard and long at being useful to the neighborhood

and good friends to each other. Now several of the key groups have begun

to work equally hard at becoming friends not of people but of history.

They spend hours behind closed doors thrashing out the correct line on

this or that remote political issue or revolutionary posture.

Previously, in open meetings, they drew in—and on—the neighborhood. They

have forfeited once-real social power in Adams-Morgan to become no more

than images of history floating in the clouds of rhetoric and pure

theory.

Blacks by and large have moved wholly into the rat race of conventional

politics and foundation grantsmanship. And upper-middle-class

arrivistes, both black and white, share no concern for the neighborhood

beyond the recent trendiness of its address.

Some of the original spirit persists, however. The people at the

Institute for Local Self-Reliance continue to do what they can, but more

frequently this entails reaching into other communities. With Therese

gone and rent no longer provided, our Community Technology warehouse has

been turned very usefully into a soap factory, operated by Jeff and

Esther, stalwarts of our group from the start. They make a living at it

and they try to teach a few kids in the neighborhood how to read. They

grin and bear the annual vandalism of the gardens by kids who think that

vegetables are underclass food—TV snacks, beer, and dope being the fare

of real operators.

The weekly meetings have ended. Information is swapped by phone and mail

these days. But almost everyone who was involved in the effort retains

faith that it was a right thing to do and that someday the memory of it

will be an inspiration to the neighborhood that finally does decide to

take its culture, its lives, and its productive possibilities wholly

into its own hands. Such a neighborhood will not change the world

overnight as in the fervid dreams of the young revolutionaries. But it

will change part of the world, possibly the part of the world that you

live in.

Chapter 5: A Vision

A vision of what it could be like.

Exactly ten years after the District’s first home-rule primary election,

it will be 1984, the date famed for predictions of the ultimate rule of

Big Brother.

In a Washington and an America following a path of centralized power

over an expanded bureaucracy, the 1984 elections here could be merely a

ritual support of a puppet city government—a little brother for the Big

Brother ruler.

But the signs are not all pointing that way. Indeed, heady new whifts of

freedom seem to be sensed everywhere. By 1984, Washington, free and

bountiful, could be a dream, not a nightmare, come true. If so, a

chronicler of the time might reflect on the decade in this way:

It came as no particular surprise to anyone that the first of the great

changes came in the Adams-Morgan section, that mixed seventy-block bag

of artists, craftspeople, businesspeople, anti-businesspeople,

bureaucrats, cooperators, radicals, conservatives, welfare families,

workers of all kinds, loafers, hucksters, hypsters, and hipsters.

Shortly after the first mayoral election, as a matter of fact, during a

neighborhood street fair, the fairgoers by obvious conspiratorial

arrangement simply tore up the entire street, blocked it at both ends,

and began preparing the ground for planting. In the spring the first

flowers appeared. By the end of the summer the entire neighborhood was

not only using the street as a park but was supplying a significant part

of its nutrition from the gardens which checkerboarded the street.

Automobiles, in the meantime, parked very handily in angle-in lines at

each end of the street.

The city, of course, had virtual fits about the citizen action in

converting the street to a park. But, in the jockeying for power and

politicking that marked the transition to home rule there were more

situations in which the citizens could, literally, stand off the

government while experimenting with their new-found freedom. And, in

cases like the spontaneous park, the effects were so practical and

popular that the forces of status quo looked silly anyway.

There was also the very important development in Anacostia, where the

people, totally neglected for so long by so many politicians, decided to

make a new kind of politics just for their own benefit. Moving from the

base of their neighborhood advisory council, they instituted a town

meeting of the entire neighborhood. When that appeared too cumbersome

for such a large area, they sensibly divided into six parts and

instituted six separate town meetings that met monthly and one federated

meeting that met twice a year to discuss problems relative to all the

neighborhoods.

One important effect was that people got a hold on their own civic

lives. Those who had cynically stayed away from any civic activities for

years found that airing their gripes and making their suggestions at

town meetings, and seeing actions get under way through citizen

participation rather than downtown red tape, made their entire lives

take on new meaning, new excitement, and a new sense of dignified

purpose. Unlike any other form of political activity they had ever seen,

the town meeting was democracy in action. Things got done because they

did it.

It was the matter of work, as a matter of fact, that moved the Anacostia

town meeting toward one of the most significant of all the changes in

the burst of freedom and creativity that eventually turned Washington

into what some people called “New Athens” and others called “that crazy

place.”

The question of neighborhood use of an abandoned garage-repair space

came up for discussion. First suggestions followed old familiar

patterns. The space would be good for teenage dances. It might be used

for a community office. Someone suggested it might be used as a soup

kitchen for the unemployed. That seemed to spark it. Why not use it to

attack the problem of unemployment itself? Someone asked. Why couldn’t

the community acquire the space, which was tax delinquent, for a

business of its own? After a few hours of discussion there seemed to be

agreement that, rather than an ordinary business, the space should be

used for some sort of labor-intensive light manufacturing process.

Anacostia’s booming community bicycle factory, whose products are now

seen all over town, was the result. It was the first of the many actual

production facilities, managed by the workers and owned by the

community, that helped turn Washington from a federal dependent, with

red tape as its most important product, into a self-reliant and vigorous

place with an economy of its own.

The Georgetown Furniture and Cabinet Guild, of course, followed very

quickly, using a warehouse space which had previously been seen only as

useful in housing fashionable peddlers of bric-a-brac to the rich. By

working as a cooperative venture, and by trying to be part of the city’s

new economic life at a community level rather than standing apart and

just chasing profits, the guild introduced furniture designs that were

not only of incredibly good quality but available at prices that

eventually drove most of the junk furniture out of stores where working

people had for years been sadly exploited and overcharged.

The basement transistor “factories” near Howard University and a

warehouse-sized fabric mill in the same area made a nationally

significant point about the utility of small-scale production which had

been slighted for so long simply because people viewed production as

only an economic activity, not a social one. Everyone associated with

the new burst of activity agreed that the effect on the neighborhoods

and on the people was every bit as significant as the sheer dollars

generated.

By the fifth Year of Freedom, as the years quickly came to be known and

numbered, the relationship of these production centers to the entire

life of the city was clear. That year the first Columbia Electric Car

rolled out of a neighborhood factory instituted in space formerly used

for city government storage in the Northeast section beyond Catholic

University. By then the number of town meetings—which had become the

characteristic form of local organization, reducing the power of the

central government to that of virtual storekeeping and ceremony—had

risen to more than 200, giving forms of direct participation unequaled

in any city. The Columbia Car has proven, as is now well known, a fine

service vehicle throughout the city, more than making up for the banning

of conventional vehicles on all but a few through arterial streets.

This year, of course, with the introduction of the so-called Gallaudet

Gasser, the hydrogen-fueled car designed by a communal house of

engineers living in the Gallaudet College area, the entire subject will

come in for new debate and decision as the neighborhoods have a new

technology to consider.

Perhaps nowhere more than in the Well Body Health Center at what once

was St. Elizabeths Hospital, is the effect of town meetings more clear.

The facilities at St. Elizabeths, used for so-called mental cases for so

many years, became available for other purposes after another of the

town meeting decisions. Considering the amount of money allocated under

traditional systems for mental hospitals, and also considering the

dubious nature of treatment in them, the neighborhoods decided on an

experimental scattering of the patients throughout the neighborhoods, in

what amounted to therapeutic foster homes, with the money formerly used

for the centralized treatment now allocated for special and specific

needs, such as the special cases involving live-in attendants to stay

with the supposedly violent.

Absorbed into neighborhoods where they could slowly become a part of

everyday life rather than constant clinical subjects, the former

patients in almost every case improved and became able to live peaceful

lives, with self-respect and in many cases with opportunities to use

skills and talents that their clinical experiences had ignored and

suppressed.

St. Elizabeths, emptied by the successful experiment, became available

for another one, every bit as striking. It became an intercommunity

health learning center. (The name Well Body Health Center was the

contribution of a ten-year-old girl who wandered in one day and casually

suggested that half the kids in her school class would be willing to

spend a summer working at the center if they could use the swimming pool

every day.)

The idea was to have a health (not sickness) facility in which people

with health problems, or the desire to avoid them, plus medically

skilled people, plus people regarded in the past as “only” maintenance

people, could work together in a learning and doing center.

By that time also, virtually every neighborhood had made some sort of

local health advance as well. The Chevy Chase Community Clinic, in the

neighborhood’s long-standing community center, was one of the first. It

began, as old-timers there now recall, as pretty much a substitute for

the old fashioned community drugstore where the pharmacist on duty was a

sort of one-man medical band, extracting a splinter one minute, getting

a cinder out of the eye next, advising on a cough medicine, talking

about diet, and so forth—a sort of paramedic way before the term became

fashionable. At any rate, at the Chevy Chase facility, a few young

people trained in paramedic skills got together to form an after-work

facility that would attempt to deal with the many health problems that,

while not requiring a fully trained doctor, seemed to make up a

substantial part of the pressure that had made obtaining health care in

Washington as difficult as in any other city.

A significant extension of the idea followed in at least three other

neighborhoods almost immediately, when people there decided to have

their own drugstores, combining the paramedic services of the earlier

facility with actual prescription and other services. Such facilities,

the town meetings in those areas argued, are far more than just

commercial enterprises, so closely do they affect the lives of the

citizens, and therefore should be operated with the fullest citizen

participation.

Even before the end of colonial status, several of the city’s

neighborhoods had developed a commercial life that was quite appropriate

to the turn things took during the early Liberty years. Worker-managed

stores such as Fields of Plenty, Stone Soup, and Bread and Roses were

both a joy for shoppers and proof that worker management worked

internally, while community involvement in general commercial decision

making worked socially. Second-generation efforts such as the South

Capitol Street Hardware, Science, and Tool Store broadened the concept

into areas that supported very appropriately the wave of do-it-yourself

parks, street benches, kiosks, playgrounds, and housing renovations that

became as familiar in Washington as step scrubbing had been in Baltimore

a couple of generations earlier.

The development of the idea of community apprenticeships for

schoolchildren by several of the neighborhood schools also enriched the

movement.

Of all the ideas of community cooperation on projects that had formerly

been the exclusive province of well-heeled outsiders, there probably was

none that aroused more immediate and citywide interest than the Columbia

Eagles, the city’s community-owned, player-managed big-league baseball

club. When the club won the pennant in Freedom Year Eight, the result

was a civic celebration which lasted a full week. There were festivals,

carnivals, and an epic round-the-clock concert that alternated the

Columbia Symphony, the community follow-on from the old National

Symphony, with Morales, the great Mount Pleasant Latin rock band. The by

now carless downtown area was made to order for the occasion.

At the very outset of the Washington renaissance, a group of students

and faculty at Washington Technical Institute turned Washington’s waste

(once the full-time odorous chore of Blue Plains) from a problem into a

resource.

The first phase was the complete reorientation of the trash collection

system. Several neighborhoods, despairing of the cumbersome, careless

manner in which trash had been collected or neglected under the city

government proper, had already demanded and received the right to handle

it in their own way, retaining an appropriate share of tax revenue for

the purpose.

One neighborhood had actually turned the collection system into an asset

from which certain social services were financed. by getting the

community to agree to stashing trash in “category” containers (garbage

in one, solid materials in another), which made possible a profitable

salvage operation. Another neighborhood set up its collection operation

as a cooperative, with neighborhood people taking turns, as a sort of

social “tax,” doing work which, they agree, is better shared than dumped

on one or two people full time.

Several other neighborhoods, pooling resources, found that a collection

system using pedal carts that ferried the trash quickly and quietly to

regular trucks on the edge of the neighborhood worked well economically.

It was with the change of the human-waste system, however, that the WTI

students became involved. Their proposition was to try to close up, in

effect, the entire sewage-waste system, using it as a neighborhood

resource rather than letting it grow wildly as a citywide problem. A

six-block area near Fort Slocum Park was the first full-scale

experiment. In it, the entire sanitary sewage system was diverted at a

convenient main to a waste-use facility set up in a remodeled one-family

house. In the house, waste entered large digesting chambers where,

odorless and without any atmospheric or other pollution, the wastes were

broken down into usable methane gas and very nutritive organic

fertilizer, wholesale also helped finance community services, while the

methane was recycled into the neighborhood as an almost complete

substitute for commercial cooking gas. (In one neighborhood using a

version of the same system, it has been reported that all of the local

cooking energy is supplied from waste-generated gas.)

In Spring Valley, a variation on the same theme—but more appropriate to

the large, rather isolated housing there—was arrived at during the same

period. Individual houses, it was discovered, could disconnect from the

sanitary sewage system altogether by installing small-scale versions of

the waste digesters, providing a substantial supplement to cooking gas

and enough organic fertilizers to make the local lawns bloom greener

than ever before.

Within three years it was apparent that the entire citywide sanitary

system could be abandoned. The final step was a larger but still local

digester plant, which was installed in the first six floors of a

downtown office building.

The fact that this year both the Anacostia and the Potomac were open for

swimming attests to the plant’s success.

But it was at the other end of the problem, the eating end, that some of

the most innovative work was done in the earliest years. Glover Park led

the way in one of the two most important developments. First, there was

the W Street Fish Factory. Thanks to innovative work done by local

technologists and scientists, who took the idea of neighborhood

self-sufficiency as requiring a material as well as a socio-political

base, a way was discovered to raise high quality fish (mainly rainbow

trout and the delicious Asian Tilapia) in extremely concentrated but

absolutely healthy conditions. The earliest experiment, on Fulton

Street, grew five tons of fish in the basemeént of an ordinary

single-family dwelling. By the time the W Street neighborhood set up its

cooperative factory in a surplus geodesic dome on the edge of

Glover-Archbold Park (the familiar multicolored landmark that children

nowadays are fond of calling the “flying saucer’), the technique was

developed so that the entire fish-protein needs of a neighborhood could

be filled from a space such as the basement of a school building, or a

dozen separate houses, or a separate structure as in Glover Park.

Perhaps the most ingenious variation of the fish-farming technique was a

small fish-farming operation on 17^(th) Street N.W., which used as feed

for its fish a “ranch” of cockroaches obtained from “brood stock”

rousted out in a clean-up campaign and fed exclusively from kitchen

wastes made available through the local trash separation service.

Efforts of a well known local lawyer to close down the operation were

outwitted during the now legendary Cockroach Conflict in which the

17^(th) Street fish farmers threatened, if stopped, to liberate their

entire ranch of roaches in the neighborhood of the famed, and futilely

fuming, lawyer. (Lawyers generally seemed to have a mixed time of it

during the early days of citydom. The rush to local autonomy and

experimentation kept plenty of them busy scrapping with the city

officials. But the tendency of neighborhoods, once well established with

town meetings, to discuss their affairs, to work out most of their own

problems in ad hoe and neighborly ways, took away a lot of other legal

work.) With the advent in many neighborhoods of regular neighborhood

courts, with open hearings where grievances could be aired and, almost

inevitably, where common-sense solutions could be found, it seemed that

the idea of local self-reliance had effectively shattered another myth,

the myth that law is a field so complicated and separated from everyday

life that ordinary people cannot understand it. The attitude of the

neighborhood courts seemed to be that if law is that esoteric, it had

better be brought down to earth, And they did that.

Down to earth also was the next stage of the food production process

that had begun with the fish farms. Versions of the old Victory Gardens

flourished all over the city during the first, and every subsequent,

summer of Washington’s liberation.

The next stage wasn’t down to earth at all, however. It was quite up in

the air! Now, of course, the sight of greenhouses on rooftops is

familiar and has even become, to people portraying the Washington

skyline, roughly what the skyline at the Battery used to be for New

York.

Hydroponic gardening on rooftops yielded some astonishing results. To

cite just one, the elderly residents of the Roosevelt Hotel harvested

ten tons of tomatoes from their roof the very first time they tried

it—raising the plants with liquid nutrients poured through sand beds

supporting the roots, and controlling the temperature and humidity so

that year-round growing was possible.

People familiar with the greenhouse skyline are familiar also with those

other symbols of an alternative technology that have become

characteristic of the city and, increasingly, of the world: the solar

collector and the wind generator.

The famed Willard Generator, with its brightly painted designs, has

dominated the corner of 14^(th) and F Streets since it was erected atop

the Community Research Center in the old Willard Hotel. It is now one of

the most copied civic art forms in the world. When it was first erected,

however, the Potomac Electric Power Company waged a full-scale attack

against it, partly on the basis of defacing the downtown visual

character! Shortly after PEPCO was “municipalized” by the federated

neighborhoods, a full-scale duplicate of the Willard Generator was

lovingly erected atop PEPCO headquarters.

The solar collectors, which are also now a commonplace of everyone’s

life, and which supply fully half of the city’s heating requirements

during the winter and considerable amounts of energy for cooling during

the summer, started springing up like black caps on many older houses

and almost all new ones in the early years and particularly after the

entire commercial block of 18^(th) Street below Columbia Road in stalled

collectors in staggered rows to prevent shielding one another. Among

other things, the bursting brilliance of the sun glistening onto and off

of the collectors turned the street into a daytime display that made the

old-fashioned use of spotlights to get attention seem feeble indeed.

For a time there seemed a possibility that the smaller, house-scaled

collectors would be abandoned when the vast experimental “sun farm”

collector was installed at Soldiers’ Home. Its eventual use to supply

almost the entire federal power requirements in the Northwest and

Northeast areas, however, caused most neighborhoods to stick with plans

to keep their alternative energy sources on as local a basis as

possible. By now, of course, solar collectors and wind generators are

simply a commonplace, although by no means the only alternative sources

in the amazingly productive ferment that has grown out of the

neighborhoods and out of the city’s creative freedom.

When the city achieved its freedom, the Rock Creek Methanol Association

was just beginning as the seemingly idiosyncratic effort of a group of

businessmen who had become angered by the actions of the petroleum

companies during one of the perennial shortages. They began a

small-scale methanol plant to see if some measure of self-sufficiency

could be achieved right in the middle of the city, knowing that methanol

had a long and satisfactory history as a fuel and could be produced,

even from some forms of garbage, in small batches and with middling

economic feasibility. Although it and some other methanol plants still

exist in about seven neighborhoods, the new hydrogen-producing

cooperatives—several of them electrolyzing water to produce hydrogen

from power generated by wind—are probably more familiar.

It is almost a political cliche now to say that every time a Washington

neighborhood came up with one of its screwy ideas a thousand bureaucrats

contemplated jumping out their windows—the trend to local self-reliance

being the hardest blow ever dealt to the federal bureaucracy. That

today’s federal establishment, concerned mainly with such international

technical conventions as the radiation detection service, the Globe

Weather Service, and the Maritime Ecology Treaty, is housed largely in

the relatively low-lying Pentagon (with the military now pretty much

confined to the Polaris System Command at New Britain, Connecticut) is

not a tribute to the need to keep bureaucrats out of high-rise buildings

so much as it is to the remarkably unanimous action in which the newly

liberated city put an absolute ban on future high-rise buildings. Such

structures, it will be recalled, gobbled up energy in such indefensible

amounts that virtually no one could be found to defend them.

Kennedy Center’s conversion soon after that also marked the end of an

era. Now familiar and well used as the central facility of the

Washington Waterside Park, the center was once a grand ballroom, in

effect, for major musical and dramatic events. But, with the emphasis on

self-reliance and neighborhood life that followed the decolonization of

the city, there was an obvious movement toward decolonizing its artistic

life as well. Instead of wanting to be mere spectators at events staged

by visiting celebrities, more and more Washingtonians wanted to create

and perform themselves. The model of the old Arena Stage and Kreeger

Theater became much more appealing than the regal scale of the Kennedy

Center and, beginning with the Georgia Avenue Playhouse and the Navy

Yard Art Arsenal, neighborhood performing centers sprang up throughout

the city to dominate, as they do today, a cultural life which has

become, in fact, fully democratized and part of every life rather than a

special and separate reflection or mockery of it.

Nowhere is the spreading impact of citywide visual arts sides, tops,

fronts, and backs of the city’s electric U-Drive cabs, pedicabs, and

electric jitney buses. Back when Washington depended upon a fixed

state-run surface transportation system of large buses, the most

colorful thing about them was their exhaust fumes. Today the average

pedicure or electric cab looks like an escapee from an art gallery,

thanks in large part to the early Art Co-op artists who traded their

designs and decorations in the community for subsistence items.

Looking back on the developments since home rule first became a reality

in Washington ten years ago, the only amusing part of the transition is

that no one had seemed to be willing to make all these sensible changes

way back in 1974, when they had all the technology they needed. Now, it

seems so simple.

Chapter 6: The Need For Action

Utopias are not unattainable; they are simply undesirable. They are

undesirable because they mean change and change is the thing most people

resist with more determination than any other social action. Any

familiar situation is preferred by most of us to any unfamiliar one.

Our very folk language is full of tributes to this fact. The devil you

know is better than the devil you don’t. I’ll stick with what I have. He

may be a bastard but he’s our bastard. Don’t change horses midstream. A

bird in the hand is worth two in the bush. Take the cash and let the

credit go, nor heed the rumbling of a distant drum. You go ahead and do

it; if it works, I’ll join you.

Our own Declaration of Independence gave the notion historic

credibility, and also tried to explain why the colonists had waited so

long before confronting the Crown: “... all Experience hath shewn, that

Mankind are more disposed to suffer, while Evils are sufferable, than to

right themselves by abolishing the Forms to which they are accustomed.”

Utopias are fun to think about, but only the more seriously disaffected

or the most idiosyncratic will seriously pursue them, risking or even

desiring the changes involved. Christians are particularly strong on

this point, making the premature entry into Paradise a serious sin.

Suffering what is, rendering Caesar what is his, and so forth are

serious Christian virtues. Change is radical. Change is dangerous.

One only has to think about the notorious Utah nerve-gas spill to

understand how deeply rooted is this resistance to change. There, after

the spill of deadly gas from a training flight, people who were employed

by the Army’s Chemical Warfare Service, and whose own lives had been

endangered by the spill, explained why they did not intend to raise hell

about it. In the memorable words of one citizen, who spoke to a friend

of mine covering the incident, “We understand it’s dangerous, but we

need the work.” Die-hard (literally) cigarette smokers often say

something similar: “I know it’ll kill me, but I just can’t think about

changing now.”

You can’t teach an old dog new tricks. Right.

Change in the past has seemed to be mostly violent or if not violent so

subtle that it hasn’t seemed like change at all.

Subtle changes, I believe, have succeeded because they seemed sensible

developments rather than changes at all and because they could be

accomplished by small groups of people, volitionally, almost as

experiments and probably as additions to rather than violent shifts from

everyday ways of doing things. The shift from nomadic to agriculture

must have been like that, a crop planted experimentally, a success, a

season of staying put, then another. And the world changed.

The city, as it developed, did not destroy the towns or villages but

simply added a new place to which people could go if they wished.

Trade must have developed sensibly like that too. Some ancient surplus

swapped for something else when a visitor chanced by, a sensible

hospitality at first, a way to widen possibility afterwards.

Or take that most epochal of inventions, the yoke, dimming even the

wheel as the first great technological advance and permitting for the

first time the substitution of some other energy for human energy in

performing human-directed tasks. Someone did it, others saw it, others

did it. It worked. And the world changed again. It was, obviously, not a

scary thing.

It is administrative inventions that seem to require violence for

success. Priestly and monarchical power have always been pressed on

people and borne forward by violence or the threats of it (swords or

damnation). Feudalism, capitalism, then state capitalism and state

socialism—all have been ridden by violence. The nation-state itself has

been aptly described as the institution claiming a monopoly on violence

in a given geographical area.

Sometimes, however, it may seem as though what should have been a subtle

change becomes a nightmarishly violent one. The spinning machines that

ushered in the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain saw not only the

Luddite violence of resistance but the broader violence of empire as

cotton plantations in distant lands were kept in line by England’s

immense naval power. But the key there is not the technology, it seems

to me. Rather, it is the organizational imperatives of imperial markets

and imperial supplies. Had the spinning machines been fed by an emphasis

on local British fibers, had they been deployed in village arrays rather

than in the administrative fiefdoms of the great families, banks, and

politicians—the industrial cities—then the development of the technology

would probably have been pacific.

The most notable attribute of any technology has come to be the way in

which it is organized and owned, rather than exactly what it does.

Gandhi could look at modern machines and see their use in villages.

Andrew Carnegie couldn’t. Gandhi saw the machines as ways to make

things. Carnegie saw them as ways to make fortunes. (Interestingly

enough, the American steel industry was quite innovative, quite

skillful, and very productive prior to Carnegie and his invention of the

heavy industrial trust or monopoly. It wasn’t the Bessemer converter

that forced the industry into a pattern of big companies that over the

years have become scandalously stagnated. It was the administrative

invention of industrial growth through merger and acquisition. Steel can

be produced by little companies and it can be produced by big

companies—both using the same technology. If there is a difference, it

would be simply that the smaller companies would be more likely to be

inventive, innovative, and vigorously competitive.)

In our time, violent change has seemed the only sort of change.

Revolution has been the route of change. Even at this very moment,

violence is seen as the great change agent, with terrorism its most

contemporary embodiment.

Yet, little has changed except leaders. Standards of living generally

have gone up, to be sure, But the general distribution of wealth remains

pretty much the same, clumped on the side of the hereditary rich, the

predatory politicians, or the violent revolutionary leaders. Generally,

in both the capitalist and the socialist world the same modes of

production prevail—concentrated ownership, mass markets, mass labor,

universalized management. The scale of violence varies, of course.

Commissars are more murderous than junior executives. The firing squad

is more dramatically lethal than the breadline. Imprisonment is harsher

than unemployment. But the modes have been static for so long. Rule is

the rule. And even in the United States, the admittedly and happily most

free society, the most extolled choices remain the choices among

products. And that, alas, is choice trivialized. And it is choice

grotesquely trivialized when even politics becomes a matter of choosing

among packaged personalities instead of substantive issues.

All is far from lost, however. Because there have been real changes off

on the side, almost behind the scenes, changes that make changes

possible. Changes that need not be trivial, There have been great

changes in knowledge, quantum leaps.

The most revolutionary possibilities in our species’ history are the

possibilities, here and now, that flow from new knowledge.

Much of the new knowledge is about things, structures, processes,

Electronics alone is a revolution of possibilities.

As fond as I am of gadgets, and as crucial as the gadgets are in

describing possibility, it is other knowledge that is even more powerful

and persuasive. The other knowledge is of life and of ourselves.

There is knowledge enough now to do a much better job, not of conquering

nature but of being a decent part of it, of using without ruining it.

And there is more knowledge of ourselves, enough to conquer old fears

that human beings in the very longest run simply could not be expected

to live in peace with themselves, much less the natural world generally.

The fear that human beings are somehow inherently flawed, capable in the

long run of little better than armed restraint of a violent, competitive

nature, is under illuminating attack all along the fronts of research.

From the painstaking archaeological studies by people like the Leakeys

comes the warming news that the history of humans is not one of unbroken

rampages but rather shows a general disposition to be, wonder of

wonders, civil, to be attentive to the community of interests

represented by those with whom we live as well as to our own ambitions

and lusts.

Peter Kropotkin’s turn-of-the-century study Mutual Aid had turned up

similar evidence from the available data on many peoples and places. But

Kropotkin, as the most famed anarchist of his time, was felt to be

pleading the special case of all libertarians who have seen in the human

condition infinite possibility and not only unspeakable peril. The

matter-of-fact, reassuringly “‘scientific’’ evidence that now supports

him is getting a more respectful hearing.

Even in such chilling experiments as the famous one in which people were

asked to inflict pain on others (supposedly as part of a very proper

clinical test) there is encouraging evidence. Alarmists have made much

of the fact that a few people involved in the experiment went so far as

to follow orders to inflict the pain even when they believed it would be

fatally injurious. Others might take heart from the fact that most of

the people involved could not be so cruel and so blindly obedient. They

stopped.

And, against the pop-science scare stories of the ethologists who

compare human behavior with that of fierce animals in the forest, there

are the counterbalancing arguments of scholars such as Ashley Montagu

who argue that humans have a distinct personality, are not merely

brutes, and as often ascend to the heights as descend to the depths.

There is even that champion scare story of recent years, the discovery

of the Ik, an African tribal group so depraved and deprived that they

actually make cruelty to one another their most creative activity. First

reports of this cruddy bunch darkly suggested that we were peering into

the open abyss of our own universal nature—all of us. Since the Ik have

not become a continuing obsession, I assume that this dismal first thud

of publicity wisely mellowed into realization that what was so

astonishing about the Uk has not their universality but their

particularity. They are the one and only bunch like that!

And so it goes. So here we are with interesting new knowledge. We can

see that human beings are not appallingly bad but are rather a mixed

bag, and, most importantly, they are not afflicted with any inescapable

tendency to be brutal. For every monstrous psychopath, a bevy of good

neighbors. In the personal inventory of most people, the villains may

stand out, but the ordinary and decent people outnumber them. And that,

of course, is ancient knowledge, newly appreciated.

On top of this we have new knowledge about gadgets. First that knowledge

tells us that human ingenuity is widely distributed, so widely that it

even defies the constraints of formal education and licensing. Edison

was an untutored maverick, Einstein a tutored one. One of the finest

physicists I know, Ted Taylor, had to be virtually dragged kicking and

screaming to get an advanced degree that would permit the

“authenticating” of work he had already done! The incredibly promising

amorphous semiconductors, which may bring conversion of sunlight to

electricity into low-cost availability, have been the scientific

specialty of Stanford Ovshinsky, a technological innovator without a

college degree.

Our new knowledge of things also tells us that organizational scale is

not so important as inspirational and informational intensity.

Most significant new inventions of our time have come from either lone

experimenters or small labs, not from corporate giants or even

government research centers.

Miniaturization has been the most interesting hallmark of the technology

most of us think of as the most advanced— electronics. In the technology

that may be even more advanced, that of genetic research, there are

constant discoveries of the decentralized autonomy of the myriad small

organizations that, federated, form ourselves. Miniaturization and

decentralization abound in the real world. In the administrative world:

concentrations of power, consolidation of information, jealous

prerogatives; everything is just the reverse of the material world

unfolded in technology, and in the humane world unfolded in scholarship.

Item: Acknowledged in the field as the most powerful computer in the

entire world, the Cray I is made in a barn on the farm of the designer

in Chippewa Falls, Wisconsin. Of course, this is possible because of the

relationships and availability of parts from many other places—but those

places also represent small-scale operations in comparison with the

gigantism of the dominating corporations such as General Motors. The

largest manufacturer of the silicon chips that have made computers so

tiny (and the decentralization of their information processes so

possible) has only 8000 employees.

Item: With the cost of photovoltaic cells, used for the direct

conversion of sunlight to electricity, falling faster than that of any

other power source, there is sense to the notion of individually

powering houses, apartments, workplaces, farmsteads, labs, and so forth.

The source of the energy will be free. Commercial cost of the

photovoltaic cells already has dropped to $6000 a peak kilowatt

installed, and even though that is a dozen times the cost of

conventional power installations, there are at least lab-scale

demonstrations which already suggest that the cost in the immediate

future will drop to $1000 and not too long after to $500 a peak

kilowatt. If the pace of the relative costs of photovoltaic cells and

conventional power continues (the cells down, the others up), it should

not be many years at all before the direct conversion of sunlight to

electrical energy—at the point of use!—will be the cheapest form of

nonhuman energy available to human beings anywhere on this planet.

It is not Utopian thinking that should make us gasp at this point, it is

anti-Utopian thinking. How in the world could anyone in his or her right

mind have available information on such a transforming power source as

photovoltaic cells and not engage in Utopian thinking.

Utopias, given good tools and good neighbors, are in fact the very least

we should settle for.

Against Utopia, of course, stands a towering argument that we have heard

many times and may hear many times more. The argument, in several parts,

runs like this:

People do not want responsibility for their own lives and would rather

pass it along to experts who would relieve them of the arduous tasks of

making decisions and being socially or politically active when after a

hard day’s work they just want to relax. Besides, this argument

continues, some people are good at one thing, some at another. Leaders

are good at leading and should do it. Why should others bother?

The argument has run itself into the ground. The choice is no longer

pertinent. The leaders lead on only to new chaos, the experts make

grander mistakes. And people generally, coming to realize this,

eventually may realize that Utopia is, after all, just a sensible

choice.

Which or whose Utopia? The Utopia of those involved, of course. Many

different kinds.

That is where the role of the tools may be seen as crucial and where

science and technology, operating consciously at the level of the proper

locus of Utopia, the locality where people can live together in shared

respect and on the basis of shared values, can become essential in an

everyday sense.

To be able to live at peace, the way people in a community might want

to, requires that the material base for that way of living be available.

The material base includes tools—even for a community that desires, as

some religious ones might, a life of absolute simplicity. The knowledge

tools for growing food would at least be a necessity. Additional tools

such as greenhousing and hydroponics, depending upon the area, are

possibly helpful. The point is that the community to have its freedom

must have knowledge of its choices and chances, otherwise it could not

be free but would forever be constrained by ignorance of real

possibility.

These constraints through ignorance today are far and away the greatest

constraints, replacing in their harsh bondages the older constraints of

natural resources.

Actually, natural resources never were too harsh a constraint until a

growing cosmopolitanism in the world made it appear that those without

the resources of the cosmopolitan centers were grievously deprived or,

as the phrase became, underdeveloped. Previously, lack of raw materials

of one sort had led merely to the development of materials of other

sorts. Builders without the bricks of Paris, but with an abundance of

bamboo, developed architecture perfectly appropriate to the resource, a

truly appropriate technology. And, as a matter of fact, to the extent

that a growing and less self-sufficient Paris became dependent for brick

on remote suppliers, it became a shackled city, diminished in some

freedoms because of outside dependence and yet unable because of

commercial imperatives to develop any new, more appropriate technology.

Today’s great opportunity is that any community — any community — can,

with access to knowledge, develop a technology perfectly appropriate to

its needs and, moreover, perfectly appropriate to its resources. Of

course, this means bamboo architecture for some, adobe for others, steel

for others—or it means arrangements in free trade to swap back and

forth. But, even for swappers a good and solid base seems a sensible

first step.

Any community, emphatically, means any community. Communities of the

Western world, of course, should be able to see the possibilities as a

matter of course. Communities of the so-called Third World, dragooned

into so many inappropriate technologies by the cultural forces of their

former colonial masters, would also be well served by the concept. In

the concept, the communities of a poor nation would first attend to

first things: to food, to shelter, and to securing a firm base in basic

production before venturing into foreign trade or to more specialized

modes. As things stand, the communities of the Third World are spiraling

toward disaster at an unstoppable velocity, facing fearful famines even

while former colonial powers erect cheap-labor factories and extractive

industries that create rich upper classes, virtually no middle class

except for a largely unemployed bunch of liberal arts university

graduates, and a tragic lower class. (Recall the 1968–1972 drought and

famine in the southwest Sahara area of Africa, where people starved to

death even while locally grown food, from irrigated, absentee-owned

farms, was being exported to Western Europe by the new entrepreneurs of

commercial colonialism.)

Of all communities, however, the ones most likely to be able to take the

quickest advantage of making new technologies for their specific

purposes would be the very poor inner-city neighborhoods—as previously

described but with the addition of the will to work at solutions rather

than simply ask for them—and medium-sized or small towns nervous about

their future, perhaps over-dependent on a single or several absentee

employers, or on tourism or other “outside” factors for survival.

The small town, for instance, might be tempted to put up a substantial

amount of money to create an industrial park to lure industry in.

Experience with this technique is mixed. It is costly and it still

leaves the town in a dependent position, its future unsecured.

Such a town might well take the next and certainly logical step of

owning a small productive industry itself. The experience with the

municipal ownership, say, of electrical power generating facilities is

so successful that it hardly seems far-fetched that municipal industries

would do well. Social ownership is, after all, a familiar activity at

the local levels of American life. People who very wisely reject as

state socialism the federal ownership of productive facilities have long

accepted local social ownership of such things as hospitals (a very

complex productive or service unit), road repair facilities,

agricultural units as in farms associated with county homes, schools,

libraries, firefighting companies, even swimming pools and golf courses.

To extend that sort of familiar social ownership just a bit to include a

productive facility that could help secure the economic future of the

entire town seems scarcely romantic but altogether hard-headed and

practical.

In taking such a step, a town could draw upon the talents, ad hoc, of

craftsmen, technicians, engineers, and others already at work in the

town. A most prudent step, well in advance, would be the formation of a

town group, committee, or what-have you to bring such people together

regularly to think ahead about the kinds of “tools” for a better

community and a more secure future that the town could devise and

deploy.

If such a group needed tools to tinker with as they sought out these

options, they probably would find them already in place in most towns.

Schools have shops and tools. Vocational schools, in particular, have

not only equipment but skilled people. Town garages have heavy

equipment. Even unused school buses might be an asset in this

enterprise, to bring people together for meetings, to take tours of

areas that might provide information. Town printing equipment could

produce a newsletter to other towns to share information and to inform

townspeople of a process in which the participation of all should be

welcome.

As a matter of fact, a complete inventory of just how much potentially

productive equipment already is owned by any town might be a good first

step for citizens concerned with taking their technological future into

their own hands.

A group of this sort to which I belong in West Virginia has undertaken

mundane projects such as advising the mayor on possible applications of

solar energy for town buildings and imaginative ones such as studying

the use of a nearby abandoned quarry as a heat storage pond to provide

warmth for town buildings. It has also been able to point out to the

mayor of another town that rather than waiting for a multimillion dollar

federal grant to solve a waste-disposal problem, the town could for a

fraction of the cost begin switching new construction to the use of

composting toilets and even subsidizing the retrofitting of older homes

to the same technology.

There is in every town, talent and imagination. Coupled with conscious

and uninhibited desire to brainstorm possibilities, that talent and

imagination can be a useful part of a public policy which itself could

become aware of the technological choices underlying political choices.

If those technological choices are not known, the political choices will

be restricted, perhaps dangerously and counterproductively, to

conventional and even failed paths.

There are no legal, moral, or technical reasons why a town or a

neighborhood should not add technological awareness, research, and

innovation to its public spaces and discussions. All that is lacking is

the decision to do it and the will to work at it.

In times such as these it would certainly seem prudent to make the

decision and exercise the will. Certainly, conventional attitudes have

gone about as far as they can go.

Chapter 7: Activities of a Local Group

The goals of a community technology group and its projects should

include the demystification of technology so that instead of seeming a

mysterious force it can become part of everyday life, including public

life and policy. If not demystified it can easily become the master of

and not the servant of those policies.

Another goal should be to challenge all of the claimed economies of

scale that find many communities despairing of being self-reliant or

being able to control their own destinies to any extent at all.

Overall, the goal should be to demonstrate the possibilities of

technology in direct service to human needs in local settings, either in

urban neighborhoods or in a town or county.

The group should, beyond demonstrations, gather useful information

relating to technology which is both usable by and useful for

communities of people—technology which, although possibly sophisticated

in concept, is low in impact on the environment, and low also in demands

upon the fixed or nonrenewable resources of the communities.

The uncomfortable feeling about technology that has ‘kept so many of us

afraid of it, aloof from it, or just plain frustrated by it derives from

a situation that was brilliantly and succinctly described by Paul and

Percival Goodman in their book Communitas:

Technology is a sacred cow left strictly to [unknown] experts, as if the

form of the industrial machine did not profoundly affect every person;

and people are remarkably superstitious about it. They think it is more

efficient to centralize, whereas it is usually more inefficient… They

imagine as an article of faith that big factories must be more efficient

than smaller ones; it does not occur to them, for instance, that it is

cheaper to haul machines and parts than to transport workmen.

Indeed, they are outraged by good-humored demonstrations of [Ralph]

Borsodi that, in hours and minutes of labor, it is probably cheaper to

grow and can your own tomatoes than to buy them at the supermarket, not

to speak of the quality. Here once again we have the inevitable irony of

history; industry, invention, scientific method, have opened new

opportunities, but just at the moment of opportunity, people have become

ignorant of specialization and superstitious of science and technology,

so that they no longer know what they want, nor do they dare to command

it. The facts are exactly like the world of Kafka: a person has every

kind of electrical appliance in his home, but he is balked, cold-fed,

and even plunged into darkness because he no longer knows how to fix a

faulty connection.

The curative, as described by Dr. John Blair, is a “new industrial

revolution.” It is a revolution of new techniques, new tools, and new

materials that allow for decentralized technology that is relatively

simple to use and inexpensive to operate and accessible to understanding

by all of us and, therefore, to development, deployment, and maintenance

by all of us. Dr. Blair says of the materials involved that they “are

neither labor intensive, nor capital intensive. They are knowledge

intensive.”

Yet, as the Goodmans pointed out twenty-five years ago, people have

become more uneasy, insecure, and even superstitious about technology.

Today’s headlined debates about energy shortages, food prices, and

housing problems are phrased in terms of national and international

reference. The problems are not considered, as I certainly feel they

should be, in terms of reference to our own local resources and to the

possibilities of local solutions. Instead, even as the major

institutions continue to display their inability to solve problems, we

continue to turn to them. Only, however, when people turn away from them

does there seem any real hope. And more and more people are turning and

seeing that hope.

There is a growing realization that community technology (or what others

call “alternative,” “low impact,” “centrifugal,” or “liberatory”

technology) can revive our communities, raise—not lower!—our standard of

living, and give people a new sense and reality of regaining control

over factors which we know crucially affect our lives and well-being but

which we have in the recent past been content to leave to the control of

others—the experts. In virtually every city today, in many towns, and

even in many of those fortresses of conventional wisdom, the colleges,

there are projects centering on some sort of alternative technology and

often on some sort of alternative social organization at the same time.

If there is an element lacking to turn this disposition into a movement

of genuine social impact, it is simply the element of consciously

linking the work of alternative technologists to the problems of

specific and existing communities rather than seeing the work as

appropriate mostly to experimental communities, homesteads, and the

like.

A way to do this is to imbed the work in the community and not confine

it to exotic areas or atmospheres; to keep the work centered upon

practical, immediate, and material possibilities rather than “futurist”

musings; to assure that work relies upon interaction with the community,

upon being part of the community rather than being an exterior force

telling the community what it should do from a position of elite

knowledge and superior taste.

It is not enough to search for new possibilities in community

technology. Information and working models must also be provided so that

community people and groups, or entire communities, may themselves adopt

and adapt the technology best suited to their purposes.

Two major goals, therefore, emerge for a community technology group, as

I see it: the accumulation of and the assurance of easy access to

information concerning technological options and impacts, and the

construction of demonstration models of technologies that solve as many

problems as possible while causing as few as possible.

It is a major attribute of what has come to be called alternative

technology that it is concerned at the outset with the problems that a

technological fix can cause as well as the ones it can solve. It is a

mark of commercial or state technology that is concentrated on neither

as strongly as it does on the matter of the extent to which the

technology can strengthen the institution’s position. And even when it

does have to take into account problem solving of a more general nature,

it virtually never seems inclined to consider subsidiary effects (the

connection between the fumes of combustion engines and cigarettes, and

emphysema, for instance).

The specific projects that can emerge from thinking about community

technology could begin with either the software of the information

function or the hardware of the demonstration function. Circumstances

will suggest which way to go.

If there is in the community a problem that sticks out like a sore

thumb, then the demonstration approach might seem most attractive as a

start. Suppose that in a small town or an urban neighborhood the problem

that bothers many people is the sanitary sewer system. It may be

overloaded, obsolete, or leaking. A group interested in alternative

technology might have the information available to see composting

toilets as a cheap, sensible, hygienic solution—and propose a

demonstration. The demonstration should keep the group together, giving

it plenty of shared activity, should give it familiarity in the

community, should tempt others to join in, and, if the final

demonstration is successful, make it apparent that an ongoing activity

would be good for the community and feasible in the community.

Need to heat a public building and high costs might combine in another

instance to suggest a demonstration of solar energy as a first activity.

On the other hand, if the formation of the community technology group

derives internally, in response to the individual interests of a few

people in the community, then it might be best to emphasize the

information function at the outset. Our own group in a small town in

West Virginia began that way. Its meetings were for a year simply

show-and-tell, info swapping sessions. Demonstration projects came

later—with the design of a heat-storage system for a local vocational

school greenhouse and then with the building of exhibit models of

alternative energy systems for a public display in connection with the

first observance of national Sun Day.

The functions of information for a community technology group might well

be patterned after the very ones some of us outlined when establishing

our first group in Washington, D.C.

—To gather, catalogue, and aid in the interpretation of existing

information relevant to the continuing projects of the group. In

addition, this activity would prepare a base for the community’s use of

technology and for the evaluation of future projects.

—To survey original research aimed at adaptations of scientific and

engineering knowledge and techniques to the sort of community-oriented

technology which is the special concern of the group. (The group itself

should make a special effort to keep up with “outside” technological

developments which might be scaled for community use. Despite the

blueprinted scale of a particular advance, there is always the chance

that it contains some effective principle or design which is easily

translated to a community rather than institutional scale.)

—To disseminate the information that is developed or discovered, not

only to the local community of which the group is part, but also to

other groups working along similar lines elsewhere, thus opening and

maintaining a flow of information and a steady stimulation of fresh

thought.

The group, either on its own or in association with the local public

library, a school, or some other familiar and dependable (and

open-minded) existing facility, would probably be well advised to

establish a library of material relevant to community technology. The

emphasis might vary according to whether the group is in a big-city

neighborhood or in a small town, close to a university or remote, or in

a rural area, where separately, Future Farmers of America, the Grange,

Ruritan, 4-H, or other similar groups might want to cooperate in

establishing the library.

The library should include books, articles, and reports from several

areas of science, engineering, and the practical arts. A temptation

might be to emphasize the journals and reports of other like-minded

groups. Their work, of course, is important and appropriate. But

conventional journals should not be overlooked or undervalued.

Technology Review, for instance, which is the regular journal of the

Massachusetts Institute of Technology, has an actual and often-stated

bias against decentralized technology and yet its superb reportage of a

wide variety of technical innovations is constant grist for the mills of

innovative alternative experimenters. Just because MIT thinks of every

development in terms of corporate activity is no reason why you should.

There is a similar comment to be made about such standard basic journals

as Scientific American and Science, the journal of the American

Association for the Advancement of Science. Scientific American often

carries the first generally understandable news of important

technological advances which have obvious implications for community

technology: no-till farming and trickle irrigation would be recent

examples. Science, on the other hand, not only covers the upper reaches

but also has reported favorably on alternative and decentralized

technology experiments, including our own in Washington, D.C.

Of very particular interest should be pop magazines such as Popular

Science, Popular Mechanics, and Mechanix Illustrated. The fact of the

matter is that Popular Science over the past few years has had probably

the most complete coverage of such alternative technologies as solar

energy of any publication in the land, barring only such specialized

ones as Solar Energy Digest and Alternative Sources of Energy. The

craftsman-like approach and do-it-yourself emphasis of the pop magazines

make them especially attractive to community technology experimenters.

The most natural publications for the library will be the ones that have

actually identified themselves with appropriate or low-impact

technology. (It is simply because they are so natural that I would

personally urge the community technologist to attend to a search of

other “straight” publications before loading up with tried and true

familiars.)

Mother Earth News, Organic Gardening and Farming, CoEvolution Quarterly,

and that British masterpiece Undercurrents are the kinds of publications

that probably have turned more people to thinking of alternative

technologies than any others. They remain important and standard in

their field. Regional publications, such as Portland, Oregon’s,

wide-ranging and, to my mind, outstanding, publication, Rain, should

also have an important place in the library. Another such publication

would be North Country Anvil, from Millville, Minnesota.

Of special interest and significance is Self-Reliance, the newsletter of

the Institute for Local Self-Reliance, 1919 18^(th) Street N.W.,

Washington, D.C. 20009. Not only is the institute’s publication a fine

one, the institute itself is a good active example of community

technology information gathering and demonstration.

Although the institute itself does not identify with just a single

community, its work is usually with community groups, such as a

composting project it is conducting with people in the South Bronx, or

various gardening and energy projects in the Washington area.

Community activities of a general nature that can grow out of the

technology group’s information gathering could also include the showing

of films. During the celebration of Sun Day, our group in West Virginia

was able to collect three hours’ worth of films on solar energy, for

free, to be shown in the town. Films are often a good way of opening the

door to any discussion. They are not, however, in any way a substitute

for regular public meetings in which neighbor-to-neighbor talking builds

ideas and a community of interest that cannot be provided by simply

being a spectator at a film showing.

Somewhere, one community technology group with just the right

combination of skill and energy might take on an information function

which has always seemed to me to have considerable potential value. That

would be a regular review of patents to spot those which might have

application to community-scale technological interests.

A similar, perhaps even more ambitious and therefore usefully shared and

decentralized, sort of information activity would be to keep in close

touch with college engineering, architecture, science, and agriculture

departments to spot activities with community applications. Few such

departments are interested in such applications, but the work they do

may have precisely such applications whether they care for them or not.

Community technologists should not overlook this possibly rich lode of

informational ore. Cooperating community technology groups could parcel

out such survey work, tackling a set of schools in each of their areas.

For any community technology group near a college or university there is

a special challenge in keeping in touch with technical faculties and

students. First, there is always the chance that a school, particularly

a land grant school, might be talked into actively sharing information

and skills—and even tools—with a nearby community. The resistance will,

of course, be strong, since most schools see themselves as serving not

communities but corporations. Nevertheless, colleges and universities do

exist in or near communities, some f. members have paid at least lip

service to the fact, and the thing could be gently pushed by a community

technology group. Nothing to lose. Certainly, for a community college or

a vocational school the link-up should be natural and practical. That it

would be in every case desirable is a point community technologists

might want to keep making.

A tie-in that falls somewhere between the informational and the

demonstrational would be with small businesses in the area, specifically

shops and garages and with such professionals as civil engineers,

architects, and builders. The small business description is emphasized

because of the regrettable but nonetheless real difficulty experienced

with virtually any big business with a plant in the area. First, the

community is only of “tactical” interest, a sort of necessary nuisance,

more to be held at bay than to be treated as an actual friend and

neighbor. Also, few decisions of any value can be made at the local

level in such plants, so that even a request to make available for

community use discarded materials or tools becomes a long, tortured

process with the head office. This shouldn’t rule out cooperation, it

should simply put it into perspective. It should be kept in mind that

the interests of a community and of any absentee-owned business are

unlikely to be the same. The number of big business “good neighbors” who

pack up and leave a community at the rise or drop of a profit point

should remind everyone of the very limited possibilities of similar

interests between a community of people and a big corporation. Its

community, after all, lives in the boardroom and the posh suburbs and

simply is not and never will be just folks in the neighborhood.

With truly local plants and craft firms, however, there can be

identities of interest and, perhaps, sharings of skill, information, and

even tools. Turning over depreciated tools for community use is one area

that might be fruitfully explored, just as might the acquisition of

government surpluses, through a town’s offices.

Although it might seem that there would be an inevitable clash of

interests between the public service emphasis of a community technology

group and the profit necessity of the small business, there is nothing

that actually demands such a conflict. If a community can in its public

spaces and decisions use the best and most suitable technology, the

savings and advantages accrue to all. It should ease, not exacerbate,

relations with small businesses and with property owners in general by

easing off the upward spiral of taxation which is often associated with

using high-cost, brute-force conventional technological answers to local

problems rather than seeking native local-resource solutions.

Where there are conflicts between a public service and a profit

approach, there is also a good opportunity for adding a new dimension to

community awareness and discussions. Certainly the community should

discuss and in the long run decide which areas of activity are best

served by which of the approaches. There is certainly nothing sacred

about either approach, the competitive profitable one or the cooperative

public service one.

A good case can be made for the fact that any community service could be

carried on by either means. Some towns do have private profit-making

fire departments; they work well. On the other hand, most communities

have volunteer fire departments, and they work well. Larger towns, of

course, have professional departments, paid out of taxes. They work well

too. The decision should be prudential, not theological.

A very important underlying strength of the community technology group

could be to bring into the social forum the sort of common-sense or even

engineering approach to public problems that would show that reasonable

people can make reasonable choices about how to get things done, without

having to be constricted to either ritual acceptance of what has been or

fantasized fear of what could be.

After all, in deciding whether the town wants to operate, say, a golf

course or a factory or a power station, the arguments should involve how

the people involved want to live. If you think that Way A serves your

purposes best then that’s the way. If Way B does it for another bunch,

then that’s their way. Some communities, for example, have turned down

the almost inevitably lower rates of a municipal power station because

they simply do not want to have to bother about adding power management

to the roster of civic interests. They’d rather pay a higher rate and

let someone else do all the worrying. Fair enough, and certainly more

sensible than turning down such a proposition simply because it is

public rather than private. The opposite is also true, of course. To

pick a way only because it is public, whether it ends up making your

life better or not, would be stupid.

Questions such as those, however, keep coming up in any community

technology effort and serve as a very useful reminder of something that

should never be forgotten. There are two parts to the phrase “community

technology.” It is not all gadgets. The gadgets—the technology—are

simply there as the support for the first part—the community. The

purpose of any human activity, I have come to feel, should be the

enhancement of the lives of the people involved. That sort of betterment

may have many definitions. To some it will mean securing a bedrock

foundation for a deeply loved and unchanging way of living. The Amish

are such a community. To others it may mean a place of kaleidoscopic

possibility, and many an artistic community is like that. To most it

probably will mean trade-offs and combinations of such things, a

community in which there is the security of shared values and ways of

living, some excitement, probably through cultural expressions, or maybe

sports, and so forth. No matter how people want to live, they still must

devise means to do it. Even a decision to live stark naked in a grove of

trees would require some attention to climate, to bark scrapes and the

alleviation thereof, to silviculture, and to some sort of agreement with

surrounding communities to whom your decision might seem vile or

laughable, or both. In short, a decision to live a certain way has a

practical dimension no matter how airy.

It is in approaching this practical side that the gadgets are important

and that a community technology group will make exciting and noteworthy

contributions—but those contributions will be made only in light of that

most basic of all considerations, the social notion of how people want

to live together. And again, just because some of the technology that a

community technologist might come up with is highly imaginative or even

astonishing, sight should not be lost of the fact that the underlying

social decision may be nowhere near so dramatic. For most people it may

simply be to continue living roughly the way they do in the existing

neighborhood or town. Community technology is undertaken, in all cases

of which I am aware, in the knowledge that even to do that in these days

of social and resource crunches may well require some very fast

technological footwork, that the technologies of massive size and

institutional centralism are no longer reassuring of real possibilities

today, no more than are the social institutions of great scale and

centralism which have presided over most of the upheavals which we now

see as undesirable. In other words, the big-scale central authorities

have created more problems than solutions. The community technologist

must hope to do the reverse and must depend on being a part of the

community for a good deal of the common sense which can help prevent

massive mistakes, repetition of past error, and bureaucratic insistence

on form versus substance.

Perhaps just a good beginning, eschewing internal hierarchy and starting

in a neighborly rather than institutional spirit, helps. Our group in

West Virginia began simply on the basis of a half dozen posted notices

and a brief item in the local paper suggesting that people get together

at the public library on a particular night to discuss such things as

solar energy, water power, new ways of organizing work, gardening, wood

energy, and so forth. About thirty people showed up the first night and

that has become a fairly average monthly attendance with more than a

hundred people seeming to feel themselves to be members. All of the

meetings are announced in the paper, results are also publicized, such

as indicating who is starting to build a windmill, who wants advice on

steam engines, and so forth. The local Chamber of Commerce directs

people interested in such things to the meetings. The group has no

officers. Its newsletter is done on an ad hoc basis by volunteers,

although Therese Hess sort of coordinates it because she usually types

it. Dues are not asked but a hat is passed from time to time to defray

newsletter mailing and paper. This has been going on now since early

1977. One result has been that the group and its meetings are now fairly

well accepted in the area as dependable sources of information on

alternative technologies. And even now the group is negotiating with the

area’s splendid Vo-Tech center to use its facilities for a more formal

information system and to open room for some courses in solar energy and

perhaps later in the whole range of things that could be associated with

community technology.

Continuing then with things we are either doing, want to do, or can see

some use in someone else doing, there are two offshoots of the

information function of a community technology group that might be

useful and revealing.

One, which we earnestly hope to begin in our own area soon, is to make a

good and full inventory of the productive facilities which already exist

in the public space of both the towns and the county.

To understand the possibilities of sharing of things which are of a

technological nature, you might be well advised to know whether you are

actually doing some of it already. Among other things it brings a

familiar touch to something which otherwise might seem unfamiliar and

thus threatening.

There is a town surveyor, for instance. His office, you could say,

already is a publicly shared and financed center for the application of

trigonometric and geometric functions. Also, there is likely to be some

first-class equipment in such an office. Applications? The office and

the equipment might be helpful in siting wind generation experiments, in

studying stream configurations and water power sites.

Road repair and building equipment represents a powerhouse of tools. The

community technology group anxious to study shared or community

heat-storage facilities or to build a demonstration earth-insulated

house could find vital tools in the town garage.

In urban neighborhoods there are also possibilities with city equipment,

using some, for instance, to bulldoze lots for community gardens, or

borrowing help from the fire department to mount a rooftop collector.

The inventory can bring to light the crucial community technology points

that tools are important and that they may be shared on a community

basis without in any way ideologically or morally fencing off the

possibility of other types of sharing, using, or owning!

To continue, printing equipment is another item of interest, of course,

to any group hoping to disseminate information. Sometimes there are lab

facilities maintained to test water supplies. Then, of course, there are

maintenance shops in general. Who really knows the tools of a town until

he or she looks carefully? And who knows the possibilities of sharing

and extending their use until a serious question along those lines is

asked?

It is possible that the school systems and libraries will have

concentrations of tools to make the community technologist leap with

joy. School labs do have equipment that, if the community technology

group can share in paying for, might be used on a community basis after

school hours. On the other hand, there may be instances where a

community technology proposal and its exploration might itself be a

superb way of teaching skills to school classes. The public library’s

main resource is a trained ability to help in working out information

retrieval systems and perhaps even providing space for information

storage.

County extension agents should be considered prime potential resources

of a community technology effort, and lest the fact be overlooked, these

agents with their access to information and often with available

mechanical equipment are also present in big cities. In Washington D.C.,

where most people never even suspected that a county agent would exist,

one certainly did and very helpfully provided a tiller for some of our

original community gardening efforts.

There is no limit to where a community technology group should go for

help. Recently our group received informational assistance of a

first-class sort from people at NASA’s high technology Goddard Space

Flight Center. Some folks there, working on a new heat concentrator for

a solar heating system, actually came to visit us with a model and with

helpful advice. Even a police laboratory could offer a possibility for a

community technologist. If the lab has a spectrometer, you might talk

your way into some time on the machine to analyze soil samples suspected

of heavy metal concentrations which can occur in areas near highways or

in smogged city lots.

Whenever the community technology Group reaches out for help, it should

remind itself that the emphasis is as much on community as technology

and that fascination with the gadgets should never overpower fealty to

the neighborhood.

Variations of the sort of surveying of tools suggested in the town

inventory would involve finding out everything possible about the same

things in other sectors.

A community skill-resource inventory should be useful. It would involve

a systematic door-to-door canvassing of the entire community (the way a

dedicated church goes about it, for instance) to discover what social

and tutorial skills are held by people in the community. At the same

time you could raise the question of the extent to which the people are

willing to commit those skills to community projects.

Churches, by the way, can always be important allies in any community

venture, just as they can be overpowering foes. In rural areas today,

many ministers are more willing than ever to experiment with new social

and technical forms. Shared activities have always been an important

part of rural and small-town churches, with cooperative helping-hand

projects being constant and familiar. Perhaps today it would not seem

bizarre at all for a church intent on helping a family in the

congregation to think about a solar hot water heater where they might

have thought of an electric one a few years ago. There is, of course,

one obvious attribute of the solar device that might appeal to some of

the congregation. They could build it, thus carrying a step further the

notion of the Lord helping those who help themselves.

In making the community skill inventory, it should be possible also to

survey tools and resources—from hobby-centered basement shops, to

heavy-duty farm repair sheds, from special libraries to the person who

just likes to store old papers or magazines, to basements or garages or

sheds full of scrap wood or metal that someone is keeping “just in

case.” Maybe the community technology group and the experiments could be

“the case.”

Too often the resources of a community are viewed only in money terms or

in some statistical way. A community technology survey of the sort

outlined above would certainly expand the narrowness of that older

concept and point to what in the long run might be the richest of all

community resources and the only sure gauge of its self-reliance: the

shared knowledge and skills and tools of its residents.

Another sort of survey that would look at present resources but also

concentrate more than any of the other activities so far suggested on

future possibilities would be a community productivity study.

The community technology group for a study of this importance and depth

probably would want to involve as many other groups in the community as

possible.

Such a study would keep in mind two points in particular, points which

could be seen as the pivots or hinges for the study. First, existing

decentralized technologies—including cybernated machine tools,

minicomputers, biological production of complex chemical substances

through DNA research, high-grade plastics molding, electronics

generally, on-site alternative energy production, intensive

gardening—beg to be studied carefully by communities of human beings no

matter the mass production, central authority direction of big business

and big government. Communities of people obviously need to begin to

think of their own well-being in their own terms rather than being

carried along by the momentum of big institutional plans.

Second, in studying the future and the tools available to shape it with,

the community needs to think seriously and democratically about just how

it wants to live in the near and the long term and how it might best get

on with doing it. And just as the study of available technologies should

be undertaken with an open mind and without the restrictions of

conventional wisdom (which at the moment keeps saying that you should

let the experts and the big boys do it), so should the study of how a

community wants to live. The study should not begin with a pessimistic

notion of not being able to change anything. There is nothing to lose at

all if the discussion begins instead with the idea that we can do

anything. It is better to discover restrictions as you go along than to

never explore at all and thus risk never discovering even the smallest

hopeful possibility.

Many a civic group or, business group or, service group in many a town

has found it useful to plan for the future. How can it hurt? Many also

find that a lot of the planning is just an exercise in futility because

somehow “practical” matters always grind it down. The suggestion in the

approaches mentioned is that by studying tools and possibilities and

dreams at the same time and always keeping them linked as tightly as you

can, there is a better chance of emerging with something that is

practical. The dream would have a material base as well as a social

base. It is founded on productive reality even though it rises to

heights of speculative Utopianism.

Imagine, to consider just one detail of what such a study might

encompass, what it would mean for a town, through some sort of community

garden space, to provide all the food to alleviate the hunger of welfare

clients in the area, rather than using cash resources to buy the food

from distant suppliers. A social dimension: What is the effect of

alleviating some welfare needs, such as food, through the work efforts

of those welfare clients able to assist in the gardens? Would prisoners

be better served and the community better guarded if they worked in a

community garden project? What about gardens and education? Year round?

What about putting some garden space into greenhouse areas? How do you

plan such greenhouses? Hmmmm. Maybe the community technology group

should be working on that in conjunction with some local plumbers and

florists. But mightn’t all that community effort divert money from local

merchants or craftsmen? For one thing, most money for welfare food is

spent at stores that buy from remote areas and whose profits are

siphoned off to other communities. Any threat to local incomes needs

seriously to be considered, of course. Perhaps if new ways of doing

things permitted a lowering of taxes, the first benefits should go to

any neighbor adversely affected by the activity. It is an important

point and one which the community itself should discuss and decide.

Suggestions such as I am making should never be considered more than

suggestions and never should be considered substitutes for the

neighborhood, community discussions, which alone make a community

technology worthwhile in the long run.

Chapter 8: Finding Your Own Way

Specific demonstration projects and activities that might interest a

community technology group should focus on the heart of the matter,

which is community, as well as the hands of the matter—tools. The idea

is not to tinker just for the love of tinkering, but to tinker for the

love of being a good neighbor and wanting to live a good life in a good

place on a healthy earth.

Community technology, information sharing, and demonstration are

responses to facts. The way we live must be based upon material reality,

upon the way we work in part, upon the way we use land and resources in

part, upon the way we make decisions in part. What we do and the tools

with which we do it are part of a process, not separate things. off,

isolated, and compartmentalized. Finally, the way we live need not be

dependent upon uncontrollable forces either of history, economics,

politics, institutional pressure, or even conventional wisdom. It need

not be if we want to, and will take those actions which will enable us

to define our desires, see our situation clearly, envision ways to

accomplish what we want, and clearly and in practical terms base our

desires upon available resources and either potential or available tools

and techniques.

With that in mind, and with the community technologist defined basically

as a person who 1) agrees and 2) is willing to work at it, using or

acquiring skills to make something possible, projects can abound. Here

are a few:

A shared machine shop might be a useful demonstration since it aims at

both areas of the community technology concern: ways of working together

and tools. It doesn’t say that all work and all tools must be shared; it

simply says that some tools and some work (community research work in

this case) may usefully be shared.

The machine shop should have enough basic tools, both hand and power, to

make the building of demonstration models or test facilities a practical

and everyday activity. The shared shop might just be part of some other

public facility, used in its off-hours. Or the shop might be separate

and stocked with cast-off industrial tools, with tools bought from

government surplus through the local school system. Or a community

technology group might just go ahead and do it themselves. Work can, of

course, be done as well in home shops or in commercial shops of people

who like the community technology approach. Results should be fine, but

the participants would miss the creative challenge of the shared shop.

Although it might not be immediately evident, such a machine shop

probably has more significance in an inner-city neighborhood than in a

small town or rural area. For one thing, shop and even laboratory

equipment is commonplace in small towns and rural areas. People already

have habits and practices of self-reliance that make this likely.

In the inner city, generations of dependence upon politicians to solve

problems and on welfare to end poverty have dulled a good deal of skill

and sharing and any other sort of emphasis on material, as opposed to

administrative, activity.

For inner-city residents, the shared machine shop might be a sensible

and practical doorway to the neglected world of productivity, as well as

being a base for community experimentation and demonstration.

Thinking of such a shared workshop in an inner city, you can think of

its use also for the maintenance of appliances and other household goods

whose replacement might represent a real economic burden in the

neighborhood and whose mysteries might be an important part in the

feeling of helplessness that many inner-city people develop.

Such a function in a small town or rural area might not be nearly so

appropriate since there are fix-it shops aplenty and they probably

represent an honest and useful part of the community’s existing economy.

Rural people are usually handy.

In either case there might be similar projects that the machine shop

could undertake beyond the building of demonstration models and other

regular community technology tasks. The machine shop could regularly

redesign cast-off items into useful ones. Discarded refrigerators, for

instance, suggest an infinity of new uses, from fish tanks, after

removing doors, to numerous small parts as each discarded one is

stripped for its components, which include small compressors, copper

tubing, heat transfer arrays, and so on. The same goes for washing

machines. In small towns a nice bonus of recycling such things is that

the local landfill or other disposal project doesn’t have the problem of

disposing of these relatively large hunks of junk; and that’s all they

are unless given a new life by the community technologists!

Similar in spirit to the shared machine shop could be a shared

warehouse. Everyone knows the agony of having to throw something away

even though instinct says that someday it will be needed. But space does

us all in—apartment dwellers immediately, homesteaders finally.

A community decision to share a space in which discarded materials can

be stored, categorized, and made easily available is a decision to use

an otherwise wasted resource, to be ingenious, and to take back into the

hands of the community an active role in making decisions about

industrial processes. In this case, of course, the decisions are made at

the end of the process, where usually the trash collector and the dump

operator are the only players. But, it has been my observation that when

people begin to take a new active part in any segment of their lives, it

becomes a self-feeding passion, urging a person on for more and more

responsibility, more and more self-reliance, more and more action as a

whole person and not merely as a spectator.

The shared warehouse—which might also have some impact on the

community’s welfare problems, if wanted—should collect a trove of bits

and pieces of building materials, no matter whether in the inner city or

in a rural area or small town. There always seems to be a bundle of wood

at the end of any project that is too good to burn, too junky to sell,

and too insignificant to store. Put a lot of those bundles together and

the picture changes to more and more practical possibilities of building

materials for the public space.

Spare parts are fair game for the community warehouse. Thus it can serve

as a parts cabinet for the community technology experimenters. Where

might the warehouse be located? Unused public space is always a good

place to start the search—basements, unused equipment sheds, or

abandoned buildings, which could present a dual challenge of community

rehabilitation work plus providing community technology space.

Fantasy, perhaps, but a local vocational school might even want to

operate a community junkyard as a way to train people in the imaginative

and creative skills of operating a good junkyard.

A problem common to many communities is the plight of more resources

leaving than coming back in. This is particularly true with national

marketing systems that draw resources toward a few centers rather than

encouraging a scattering among many communities. The shared work space

and the shared warehouse space involve a community in taking a first

look at this problem at a homely and non-ideological level. It could be

hoped that after the process is begun it will continue until the

community is prepared to discuss every aspect of its resource base and

its shared interests in regard to it.

For many communities these days the first and most obvious place to

start any community technology demonstration or experiment is in the

area of energy. My own prejudice is that food comes first, as indicated

throughout these comments. A good look at a community’s food base, it

seems to me, would be more enlightening in many ways than a look at the

energy base. Nevertheless, energy is obviously on more minds today than

food. Experiments and demonstrations in alternative sources of energy

are a quick entryway to the interests of most communities. The most

obviously intriguing part of it is solar energy. Fortunately, it is the

part most susceptible to community technology demonstration, even in

northern climes.

Of solar energy projects, one of the most immediately productive and

economically feasible is hot water heating. Even in southern climates,

where solar space-heating devices might lie idle most of the year, hot

water heaters would perk away full-time. Furthermore, the use of hot

water heating, particularly in schools, might be an item of substantial

community interest from a purely economic point of view.

Community technology groups, cooperating with local officials, should be

able easily to make convincing demonstrations of the feasibility of

solar hot water heating, starting perhaps with out-of-the-way

installations such as in road or building maintenance shops, then moving

on to more prominent places. Whereas the community technology group

might be biting off a bit too much to offer to install solar

space-heating collectors on a local school building, they might be able

quickly and easily to do it for a sheriff’s substation or a

road-maintenance office—or a dog pound. Inner-city opportunities are as

numerous as the buildings in the neighborhood.

My own feeling is that the what or the where of the solar experiment is

not as important as the process of doing it wherever and however. It

begins that process crucial to a community technology outlook in which

you feel that new answers can be found for old problems and that you and

your neighbors can find them and apply them.

In most community technology ventures it is quite probable, my

experience has shown, that individual experimenters themselves will have

taken the lead in designing and installing innovative systems of some

sort, so when an opportunity for public demonstrations comes along,

there will be some practical experience on hand as well as plenty of

theoretical knowledge. Also, in looking at answers such as solar

heating, the community technology group will be an important agency for

convincing tradespeople and craftspeople in the area that they are, as

they definitely are, already engaged in matters with direct

possibilities of conversion to solar energy. Sheet metal workers have

most of the skills needed to install good solar hot air systems. A

little brush-up on physics—helped by the community technology group

meetings!—and the sheet metal worker is a solar worker. It is the same

with plumbers and liquid transfer solar systems. Everyone involved in

building supplies or construction has skills that are directly

applicable. And bankers have skills required for financing! Money also

is a tool.

Storage of solar heat is a prime area of experimentation for any

community technology group. In our area, large unused and abandoned

quarries represent a resource we will be investigating to see if the

caverns or ponds of the quarries could be used for community-wide heat

storage or, sequentially, for “cold storage” (air conditioning).

In regard to solar energy, however, the community technology group has

another responsibility and opportunity. It should keep very close tabs

on the development both of chemical and mechanical energy storage

systems and also on the development of devices for direct conversion of

solar energy to electrical energy. The speed with which photovoltaic

cells for direct conversion are dropping in cost makes me strongly

suspect that we are on the edge of an energy revolution more

far-reaching than any we have ever known. Should that revolution have a

moving effect only at the most centralized and remote levels of social

authority, we may be in for real trouble if an energy source that could

be dramatically liberating is instead bureaucratically or economically

shackled to the purposes of either big business or big government.

Community technology groups working at the local level would do well to

keep their friends, their town officials, and their inner-city groups

closely advised on the possibilities of using photovoltaic energy before

it becomes chained to one or another corporate interest, either

government or private.

Wind energy is the next most feasible demonstration area for a community

technology group. Whether in the city or in the country, wind is

everywhere.

In the original outline of the community technology group that we

established in Washington, D.C., there is a still interesting and

succinct wind energy proposal:

The wind power project will investigate a number of different aspects of

wind-generated energy: high and low speed mills for electrical

generation and pumping; speed-up effect of shrouded mills and natural

urban wind tunnels; effects of placement of units; effects of wind

generator “fields” (what is the environmental effect of having a large

number of units in a relatively small area?) We will work with

propeller, turbine, and Savonius systems, with both professional and

“funk” (recycled junk) technologies. The units will be developed around

the neighborhood with cooperating groups, in order to get a wider range

of feedback.

The initial phase of this project will be data gathering. We will deploy

a series of recording anemometers around the neighborhood, at a variety

of altitudes, in order to develop a suitable picture of the local

microclimate, to guide us in mill site selection. We will then build a

series of small (under 12-foot diameter), relatively low powered (under

one kilowatt) mills, to investigate several questions simultaneously:

blade shrouding systems; control feathering and braking systems;

battery, hydrogen, gravity, and compressed air power storage; and

turbines and Savonius rotors for low wind speed applications.

We will later apply what we learn from the small mill experiments to the

construction of a larger (two kilowatt) plant. Barring unforeseen

setbacks, within a year we hope to have a refined design for, and

proceed with, the construction of a series of one and two kilowatt

units. The capital cost of such units will be about $250-$300 per

kilowatt installed capacity. This figure may seem high in comparison

with the $125-$130 figure offered for conventional steam generating

plants, but consider: (1) that the steam plant figure does not include

environmental costs of thermal and atmospheric pollution; (2) that

proponents of nuclear generating plants (which, we are told, are the

wave of the future) are at present projecting a cost of about $300 per

kilowatt installed capacity, and that estimate climbs every year; and

(3) that operating expenses, although initially higher than conventional

costs, are less likely to increase than conventional costs, deplete no

resources, and show every indication of decreasing as experience

increases—a factor no longer claimable for conventional power sources.

For many small towns and rural areas there is a special and growing

interest in the use of wood as a fuel. Vermont has made it a state

priority.

Community technology groups can certainly help out with this. First of

all, they can make sure that they and their neighbors are really up to

date on what’s available commercially in the way of good wood-burning

equipment. Evaluations of such equipment are important but so far hard

to come by. But assuming that people scattered through a lot of towns

are indeed buying a lot of brand-new wood stoves, and hoping that an

interest in community technology springs up around the country,

community technology groups could test whatever stove they might have

available in a friend’s home, then swap the information with other

groups that might be testing some other design.

Community technology groups should also consider original designs and in

keeping with the overall spirit should keep in mind the possibility that

a good original design could be the basis for a community business or

co-op, or even a town industry.

The stove is just part of the wood-burning process, however. Any

community technology group has its work cut out for it in discussing and

envisioning and then demonstrating novel ways of growing wood, perhaps

on a community basis, cutting it, splitting it, drying it (a solar

task?), and then dividing it for use. Also, they might want to consider

the fact that heat from wood is a next-door neighbor to heat from, say,

agricultural wastes and even certain industrial wastes. Could

utilization of the wastes be useful in the community? Would it also

provide a base not only for a new energy source but for a new productive

outlet for the town’s manpower?

Community technologists should never stop with just one question if they

can help it. Or settle for just one answer!

Specialized vehicles are the sort of problem that particularly interests

me, and they show the wide range of community technology possibilities

in any community. Considerable public money is spent annually on cars

and trucks. Often the money is spent buying specialized equipment which,

although it will only seldom be used, is felt to be worth it. Some of

that, surely, could be built locally.

In our neighborhood in Washington it was clear from a couple of weeks’

study that one of the most important moving devices for the neighborhood

would be a sort of self-propelled platform that could move heavy items

of furniture for a few blocks, to take care of ordinary household moving

needs or for community activities in which chairs, musical instruments,

platforms, or such gear had to be moved a few blocks. An expensive

pick-up truck would have been a waste of money. Our solution was to take

the cheapest car we could get that was still operable, cut it down,

mount a platform across its rear, leaving just a cockpit for the driver,

and, lo and behold, we would have a very low cost moving platform.

Small towns might have similar problems. They also might have junk cars

to dispose of—a happy juxtaposition of resource and possibility. Rural

areas already are models of innovative vehicle design. Few farmers can

resist designing new machines. We should all have this itch.

Also in cities there is a need for community technology groups to design

really good shopping carts capable of mounting curbs and steps, so that

the elderly could do their shopping more easily. Of course there is just

as much reason for the community technology group to think of ways for

the elderly to organize their own gardens, for instance. Or to devise

ways in which a neighborhood can simply stop itself from segregating the

elderly into special ghetto conditions. Community technology is not just

gadgets. Basically it’s people—and about people.

And certainly food is a crucial “people issue.” Again, from our original

outline of community technology work in Washington, D.C., here are two

specific proposals for food projects:

In the United States the quality of food is declining steadily, with

highly processed foods accounting for an increasingly large segment of

the American diet. As the USDA reports, the number of people eating

“good” diets in this country has fallen to around 50 percent, with

vitamin deficiency becoming commonplace, and the general health of the

nation declining.

We will explore an approach that could go a long way toward alleviating

both of these problems—decentralized food production. By taking

advantage of unused basement and roof-top space, we hope to demonstrate

that an urban community can provide itself with a steady supply of high

quality fish protein and vitamin rich fresh vegetables, year-round, at

low cost.

The initial projects in this area are hydroponic greenhouses and

high-density trout culture. Coincident with these food raising projects,

alternative community institutions for the equitable distribution of the

food will be studied. Local food co-ops have already expressed an

interest in being involved. The neighborhood organization also has begun

discussions of the distribution question as well as pledging support to

the food projects generally.

Hydroponics involves the growing of crops in a carefully controlled

environment: soil (and thus the possibility of soil infestation and the

need for fungicides) is eliminated and replaced with gravel,

vermiculite, or similar substrate. Nutrients are supplied in a precisely

formulated solution at specific intervals. Greenhouses are maintained at

a temperature level, carbon dioxide concentration, and humidity suitable

to encourage optimum growth. Yields produced by these techniques are

dramatically higher than those from conventional agriculture, and

year-round production is possible.

The feasibility of hydroponics is already well-established. Preliminary

calculations (based on data from NASA and commercial and noncommercial

growers) indicate that greenhouses covering 10percent of the area of a

city (or a fraction of its unused roof-top space) should provide the

food needs of 18,200 people per square mile. (The density of Washington

is about 13,000 per square mile.)

In the first year, we will construct and operate five greenhouses of 240

square feet each. About three-fourths of this space will be used to grow

crops, including soybeans, tomatoes, squash, carrots, beets, greens,

legumes, and possibly grains. The other 20 to 25 percent of the space

will be devoted to research. We want to investigate, for a start, the

economies of scale involved in choosing between family size and block-

or community-size facilities; the different varieties of nutrient

solutions, including solutions prepared from composted “wastes”:

comparison of the relative nutritional value of crops produced;

companion planting; simplified testing and control procedures so that

units can be operated by individuals with little technical experience;

and the possible problems entailed in dealing with a complex,

interactive ecosystem in a reductionist setting. In addition, data

gathered in these efforts will be used in the development of a

longer-term project—integrated food, energy, and sewage systems for

urban dwellings.

It is widely predicted that over the next three to five years there will

be a dramatic decrease in supply and an increase in the price of seafood

in the United States. This is expected to be a result of the dollar

devaluation as well as the collapse of the domestic fishing industry and

a decrease of the total world catch due to overfishing by the modern,

efficient European and Japanese fleets. This development would lead one

to expect an increase in emphasis on domestic fish culture and, indeed,

one is slowly taking place. The amount of fish produced by the industry,

however, is minute in relation to the total seafood supply—something

less than two percent of it. Most aquaculture operations are limited in

their productive capacity by the amount of water available. A technology

which is just now coming to fruition is water purification, which makes

possible the use of large-scale water reuse systems.

The requirement, up until now, of large quantities of pure water for

rearing fish has dictated that almost all commercial aquaculture sites

be located at considerable distances from their most concentrated

markets, the urban centers. Recent technological developments in water

purification, however, suggest that it is possible to make such

efficient use of the culture water that the situation can be reversed

and that useful quantities of fish can be grown within the urban center

itself, using water from the metropolitan domestic water supply but

without adding any important strain on either the water supply or the

sewerage system.

This movement of a food production facility into the city would

immensely simplify the distribution of the perishable fresh fish to the

concentrated market, would provide a new kind of industry in the city,

and would provide some degree of control by the urban center over a

component of its food supply.

As a first development and demonstration project, we propose to raise

rainbow trout. Although this species has stringent water temperature

requirements, there are many reasons for working with it. First, the

starting materials—rainbow trout eggs or rainbow trout allowing a nearly

continuous year-round production of fish of marketable size. Second,

efficient feed is commercially available. Third, more is known of the

physiology and cultural requirements of the species than of any other

fish. And fourth, the product has a nearly universal high acceptance.

The growth from “eyed” (fertilized) egg to table-size fish, generally an

average of three-fourths of a pound, requires 12 months and about 1.2

pounds of feed. During this period the production is carried out in

perhaps four different configurations of tanks of increasing sizes. In

actual commercial production, the latter stages of growth would take

place in a multiplicity of identical tanks. For the development and

demonstration project, though, we will limit the throughput in the

latter stages by using a maximum of four of the largest size

experimental vessels (10 x 4 x 3 feet). This will give a continuous

production at the rate of about 400 pounds of fish per month after the

first cycle has been completed (12 months).

A facility of this size would permit a demonstration of the process in

large enough equipment to remove all important questions of scale-up and

would provide early-stage facilities for the production of, perhaps, 30

times the 400 pounds per month of the proposed demonstration unit if

adequate later-stage facilities could be added.

For the demonstration units, we will use silo-type incubators and

construct tanks of plywood and fiberglass with perhaps some of the

larger vessels being made of ferro-cement. Each fish tank will have a

biological ammonia converter for water purification and temperature will

be controlled by insulating the tank room and using standard window-type

air conditioners. Temperature will be maintained at 55to 60 degrees F.

and water usage, except under unusual circumstances, will be kept below

200 gallons per day.

Both of those experiments proved successful.

There is an inexhaustible array of demonstration possibilities for any

community technology group; and even at your first meeting, should you

and some friends decide to become such a group, you’ll probably be able

to fill a notebook with them.

Later, as the group enlarges its meetings and either goes to new people

or draws them in, the possibilities should be endless and the trick will

be in prudential priorities or in just seeing how much can be done

before you collapse!

I would not even want to suggest how your community technology group

might operate, internally or externally. I have suggested possibilities

of purpose here and have emphasized several, but I would not want the

suggestions or the emphasis to substitute in any way for your own

inescapable responsibility, along with your friends, to make the basic

decisions on your own, for your own purposes and in the light of your

own knowledge of your own community.

If you want to organize such a group in the hope that you will become

the newest business in town, making a good buck from advising on new

technology—more power to you. Your work has got to be closer to the

community and more responsible to its resources and needs than an

outsider from a big business to whom your town is just another dot on an

international map.

If you want to organize the group to look toward social ownership of

basic productive needs, then more power to you also. Your work has got

to be less regimenting than the plans of state socialists or even

liberal traditional politicians.

If you want to organize the group to truly explore all sorts of human

possibilities and do not even know now which you might prefer—more power

to you also. Your work has got to be more libertarian than that of those

who see the future as a game that can be played and predicted right now,

to be fastened on us all tomorrow by elite decision.

My own interest is the responsibility of people to be responsible for

their own lives and, with their neighbors, for their public space and

actions. To sing their own songs. To make their own inventions. To be on

stage and out of the audience. To love and not just yearn.

To build and not just envy. To light that candle which is so much better

than cursing the darkness. To be as much as the human condition can

sustain, rather than being only what a system can allow.

To be. To do. That is community technology.