đŸ Archived View for library.inu.red âș file âș solidarity-federation-fighting-for-ourselves.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 13:59:31. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
âĄïž Next capture (2024-07-09)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Fighting for ourselves Author: Solidarity Federation Date: October 27, 2012 Language: en Topics: anarcho-syndicalism, class struggle, class struggle anarchism, history, anarchist history Source: Retrieved on 2020-03-18 from http://www.solfed.org.uk/read/ffo
âAgainst the offensive of capital and politicians of all hues, all the
revolutionary workers of the world must build a real International
Association of Workers, in which, each member will know that the
emancipation of the working class will only be possible when the workers
themselves, in their capacities as producers, manage to prepare
themselves in their economic organisations to take possession of the
land and the factories and enable themselves to administer them jointly,
in such a way that they will be able to continue production and social
life.â
â Statutes of the International Workers Association (IWA-AIT)[1]
âOne must try to increase as much as possible the theoretical content of
all our activities, but without the âdry and shrivelled doctrinalismâ
which could destroy in part the great constructive action which our
comrades are carrying forward in the relentless fight between the haves
and the have nots. Our people stand for action on the march. It is while
going forward that we overtake. Donât hold them back, even to teach them
âthe most beautiful theoriesâ...â
â Francisco Ascaso[2]
âThe spirit of anarcho-syndicalism (...) is characterised by
independence of action around a basic set of core principles; centred on
freedom and solidarity. Anarcho-syndicalism has grown and developed
through people taking action, having experiences, and learning from them
(...) the idea is to contribute to new and more effective action, from
which we can collectively bring about a better society more quickly.
That is the spirit of anarcho-syndicalism.â
â Self Education Collective[3]
As we write this in 2012, capitalism is experiencing one of its periodic
crises. In Britain, the depression is now longer than the so called
Great Depression of the 1930s. The state is seizing the opportunity to
tear up past working class gains across the board, from healthcare
provision and reproductive rights, to unemployment, disability welfare
and access to higher education, from job security to wages. This has
provoked brief moments of intense, defensive struggles. In the winter of
2010 students took to the streets across the country against a tripling
of tuition fees to ÂŁ9,000 per year. The movement erupted in November
with the trashing of the ruling Conservative Party HQ at Millbank, as
thousands broke away from the official National Union of Students march.
That spirit continued throughout the following few months, with rowdy
demonstrations across the country. The state response was brutal, with
riot police suppressing the protests and âkettlingâ thousands for hours
in freezing conditions. The rioting in central London was, at the time,
the worst in a generation. But more was to come.
Meanwhile, the public sector unions slowly moved into action, calling a
series of one day strikes. Unity lasted for just two days of action
before unions started dropping out and signing deals with the
government, and the tangible feeling of power and possibility has been
steadily demobilised into one of inevitable defeat as workers are
divided by those supposed to represent their interests.
In August 2011, riots once again broke out across the country. This
time, they followed the police shooting, and subsequent cover up, of an
unarmed man in Tottenham, north London. Hatred of the police proved a
common bond. Rival gangs declared truces and over four days rioting and
looting spread first across the capital, and then across the country.
Rioters voiced anger at police brutality and harassment, political
corruption and the rich, only for the government, media and much of the
left to dismiss them as apolitical. The riots died down, but much of the
underlying tension remains.
So then, we are living in times of unprecedented attacks on our living
conditions on all fronts, of rising social tension and sometimes violent
eruptions of class conflict. And yet if anything, the surprise is not
that there have been riots and the odd strike, but that there have been
so few. How are we to make sense of this? How are we to fight back, to
take the initiative? Against this society, what do we want to put in its
place? The 20^(th) century discredited state socialism, and rightly so.
But with it, a whole history of international class struggle, of
revolutions and counter revolutions, victories and defeats, spontaneous
uprisings and vast workersâ organisations has been eclipsed too. This
pamphlet aims to recover some of that lost history, in order to set out
a revolutionary strategy for the present conditions. We focus on the
forgotten side of the historic workersâ movement, not in search of
blueprints but inspiration. We draw that inspiration from those
tendencies which focussed not on capturing state power through elections
or insurrection in order to impose âsocialismâ from above, but which
took seriously the idea that âthe emancipation of the working class is
the task of the workers themselvesâ, posing working class direct action
against the double yoke of capital and the state.
We focus on anarcho-syndicalism, the tradition we come from, but touch
on numerous other lesser known radical currents along the way. We
certainly donât think we have all the answers, but we do think weâre at
least asking the right kind of questions. How can we organise ourselves
to both defend and advance our conditions? How can we oppose the attacks
of both capital and the state, when dominant liberal and leftist
approaches see the state as the protector of our ârightsâ and push for
participation in the parliamentary process? What kind of society are we
fighting for, if not one ruled by the impersonal forces of capital and
the violence and hierarchy of the state?
We see revolutionary theory as an aid to organising workers struggle and
not, as is so often the case, as a means of dominating and controlling
it, or of producing dense and enigmatic tomes to establish oneâs
credentials as a âthinkerâ. As capitalism is dynamic so must be the
methods we use as workers to fight it. It is only through our collective
immersion in day-to-day struggles that we can adapt and change tactics
to meet changing conditions. And as our tactics change and develop so
must our ideas. Doing and thinking are but moments of the same process
of organisation. It is through our involvement in our daily struggles
that, as an anarcho-syndicalist union initiative, we are able to ensure
that revolutionary theory keeps pace with practical realities and
remains relevant to the workersâ movement and to our everyday lives.
âAnarcho-syndicalismâ is a term which trips awkwardly off the English
speaking tongue, and tends to elicit either bafflement, or images of
burly working men in some 19^(th) century factory. In French, the term
syndicat, in Spanish, sindicato, in Italian, sindacato, simply means
âunionâ, an association of workers without any further connotations,
which can be modified by adjectives, such as âanarchoâ, much as we use
adjectives to modify the word union in English â trade union, craft
union, industrial union and so on. Perhaps a better translation would be
âanarcho-unionismâ. But again, in the context of the United Kingdom,
âunionistâ has British nationalist connotations completely at odds with
the working class internationalism of the anarcho-syndicalist tradition.
So we stick with the term, and unless otherwise specified we will use it
interchangeably with ârevolutionary unionismâ throughout this pamphlet
(there are other advocates of revolutionary unions which we will also
encounter along the way).
This pamphlet aims to shed light on both the forms and content of
anarcho-syndicalist theory and practice, and in the process to dispel
some of the more common myths and misapprehensions. It will explore how
anarcho-syndicalist ideas have differed and adapted to meet changing
conditions; outline the relationship with other traditions and
anarcho-syndicalist criticisms of them. We will then bring things up to
date with analysis of the post-WWII world and the conditions for
organising today. We will set out our view as an organisation of what a
new revolutionary unionism would look like, and outline practical steps
and strategies to make it a reality. With the continued defeats workers
are experiencing through the trade unions, a revolutionary alternative
is needed more than ever. Indeed, we should not be asking the question
âhow can a union be anti-capitalist and anti-state?â, but rather, how
can any union that is not so advance our class interests?, when those
interests are inimical to those of capital and state.
The structure of the pamphlet is as follows: Chapter 1 introduces the
mainstream workersâ movement, specifically trade unions and workersâ
parties, in both their Marxist/Leninist and Labour Party forms. While
these have their origins in the 19^(th) century, they continue to
dominate the workersâ movement (such as it is) today. Therefore the
analysis is not purely historical, but continues up to the present day.
Chapter 2 then explores the radical currents in the 20^(th) century
workersâ movement, long forgotten to most but still a point of reference
for many discontented with the limits of the mainstream. This section
explores council communism, a dissident Marxist tradition that still
forms an important point of reference for many of those critical of the
existing trade unions, as well as Marxists breaking with party politics.
It also looks at both anarchist and syndicalist traditions, providing
the context for Chapter 3.
With the scene then set, Chapter 3 will introduce anarcho-syndicalism as
a fusion of the anarchist and syndicalist currents. We will see how this
fusion took different forms in different places in response to different
conditions, and explore some of the internal debates within the movement
which remain relevant to our time. We will also look at the Spanish
Revolution of 1936, which was both a high and low point for
anarcho-syndicalism, and reflect on what went wrong and the implications
for anarcho-syndicalist theory and practice. Finally, this chapter will
draw on the historical discussion so far to set out the theoretical and
practical basis of anarcho-syndicalism and its relation to other
traditions. We will see that anarcho-syndicalism is a practice of trial
and error around a political-economic core, combining the ideas and
goals of anarchism with the organised labour strategy of syndicalism.
Given that the anarcho-syndicalist movement was all but wiped out by the
combination of fascism, repression and total war from 1939 onwards,
Chapter 4 will explore the changes in post-WWII capitalism and assess
their implications for anarcho-syndicalist organising. Specifically, we
will look at the post-War social democratic settlement, which sought to
counter the threat of revolution and marginalise radical currents by
integrating the working class (via the trade unions) into capitalist
society through a series of reforms. We will then look at how this
settlement went into crisis from the end of the 1960s through the 1970s
with a wave of workersâ struggles against capitalism, the state and the
trade unions. But we will see how these struggles were ultimately
defeated, and gave way to the neoliberal counter revolution from the
late 1970s, which has dominated global capitalism ever since.
Finally, Chapter 5 will draw on this analysis of contemporary conditions
to assess the relevance of anarcho-syndicalism today. We will look at
how to move from small political propaganda groups towards functioning
revolutionary unions, explore the role of the revolutionary union, and
its means of organising class conflicts within the wider working class.
We will also look at how the everyday activities of the revolutionary
union relate to the revolutionary struggle for social transformation,
and explore the significance of the insurrectionary general strike in
the overthrow of capital and state and their replacement by worldwide
libertarian communism: a stateless society based on the principle âfrom
each according to their abilities, to each according to their needsâ.
Against the fashionable and market driven disdain for anything âold
fashionedâ, we will show how anarcho-syndicalism represents a simple yet
sophisticated and adaptable weapon for the working class today, and thus
why we are proud to nail our colours, red and black, to the mast of the
anarcho-syndicalist International Workersâ Association (IWA).
This chapter will introduce the mainstream currents in the workersâ
movement, from their origins until today. This is done in three parts.
First, we look at how trade unions began as a response by workers to the
conditions of early capitalism. By forming associations, workers could
get the strength in numbers to change the balance of power versus
employers. But we will see how, alongside this, a representative
function arose, where unions developed a life independent of their
membership and began to operate over their heads, mediating and
ultimately diminishing their power within the limits set down by capital
and the state. We will also see how this led trade unions to see
themselves as purely economic organisations, leaving âpoliticsâ to
separate party organisations. We will then look at the notionally
ârevolutionary workersâ partiesâ originating in Marxism and Leninism,
and set out a critique of their inherent statism. Finally, we will
retrace the history of the British Labour Party, dispelling some of the
rose tinted nostalgia for this âworkersâ partyâ, which was always a
party of the trade union bureaucrats and never of the workers
themselves.
Britain was the first industrialised country, and so it was here that
the first working class developed. The Enclosure Acts from 1750 onwards
evicted the peasantry from traditional common land and turned them into
rural wage labourers or landless vagabonds. Meanwhile, the need for
large numbers of workers to staff the burgeoning manufacturing
industries created an intense wave of urbanisation. Rural migrants were
joined by former craft workers thrown into unemployment by the
competition of industry. The labouring population of town and country
were completely dispossessed, having nothing to sell but their labour
power. They were the first members of a class which today accounts for
the majority of humanity â the proletariat.
At first, industrialisation was seen as the death knell for the power
that producers, organised in craft guilds, had over production. The
system of apprenticeships and monopolisation of specialist skills had
given craft workers a degree of control over their work that automation
was set to wipe out in the new deskilled, mechanised division of labour.
However, the fear that workers would never again exercise collective
power over the production process would prove to be premature. After a
few decades, new forms of collective organisation began to emerge. As
early as 1799 and 1825 Combination Acts were passed as capital sought to
curtail emerging working class organisation.
These early unions were small and transient. Typically they tended to
form for the purpose of organising a conflict with the bosses,
dissolving some time later following the conclusion of the conflict in
victory or defeat. This posed several problems for the union movement.
Firstly, the division of workers at each firm into small and transient
unions meant a strike at one firm could simply mean ruin and subsequent
unemployment as rival firms took advantage. Secondly, the impermanence
of these early unions meant they were largely reactive rather than
proactive, being formed to counter specific conditions rather than fight
for the general improvement of working class living standards, let alone
holding aspirations of revolutionary social transformation. These
pitfalls led to the growth of a burgeoning amalgamation movement.
The amalgamation movement saw smaller unions combining into larger, more
permanent ones. Their increased resources meant paid organisers could be
employed to further swell the membership, which was stabilised by the
introduction of services such as unemployment and sickness benefits,
which at that time were not provided by the state. But amalgamation also
had unintended consequences. Unions went from being a means to organise
class conflicts to becoming an end in themselves, as permanent
representatives of workers, acting on their behalves and supposedly in
their interests. It is this latter role which came to dominate the union
movement and with which we are mostly familiar today in the shape of the
Trades Union Congress (TUC) unions.
It is therefore possible to identify two distinct meanings bound up in
the term âunionâ. The first is simply that of an association of workers,
joining together for some common purpose (whatever that may be). In
other words, the union is the means by which workers relate to one
another. That relationship may be horizontal or hierarchical, usually
voluntary but, as in the case of âclosed shopsâ where workers have to
join the union, sometimes compulsory. Their association may be
long-lasting as in todayâs trade unionism, or more transient as in the
early, pre-amalgamation unions. The purpose of their association may be
simply economic â âbread and butter issuesâ â or encompass wider social
or political goals. We can call this the associational function. This
function is a product of the reality of life under capitalism.
Individually, workers are powerless. Collectively we have power. Workers
needed to defend themselves against the opposing interests of the bosses
and have historically organised themselves into combinations such as
trade unions in order to do this, realising that workersâ strength lay
in their association.
The second function, perhaps most familiar in the age of the âservice
providerâ union model, is that of the representation of workers
vis-Ă -vis capital. This usually means management, but sometimes includes
politicians and the state, should they decide to intervene in a dispute.
We can call this function the representative function. The
representative function carries with it certain assumptions. Firstly, it
is premised on the legitimacy of the existence of social classes,
between which it seeks to mediate. Secondly, in order to gain the right
to negotiate on workersâ behalves, representative unions tend to
jettison any explicit politics which could put off potential members,
since size becomes the all important factor in determining their place
in the TUC pecking order (in the UK, this has normally meant outsourcing
âpoliticsâ to the Labour Party).
Both of these functions have become closely intertwined in the course of
the historical development of the trade union movement. It is worth
quoting a substantial passage on one such example of this process,
because it raises a number of issues which will come up again and again
in this pamphlet:
âMuch can be explained by John Turnerâs experiences. From the time of
the Harrow Road âriotsâ in 1891 until its amalgamation with another
small union in 1898 Turner had been (unpaid) president of the United
Shop Assistants Union. On amalgamation the total membership of the union
was approximately 700. Turner became paid national organiser and threw
himself into a recruiting drive around the country. The membership grew
rapidly as a result of prodigious efforts on his part. But his
experiences in the âUnitedâ Union had brought about a change of
approach. Branches then had come into being as different work places had
come into conflict with their employers and then faded away as victory
or defeat seemed to make union membership less important or more
dangerous. Now Turner, to ensure a stable membership, had introduced
unemployment and sickness benefits and as a result had members âof a
good type, paying what was, for those days, a fairly high contributionâ.
His policy worked, but he was now primarily organising a union whereas
previously he had primarily been organising conflicts with employers.
âBy 1907 the pressure had relaxed somewhat and Turner was a fairly
comfortably off trades union official of some importance. By 1910 the
Shop Assistants Union had a membership of 13,000 in the London area,
making it the largest union in the district. In 1912 John Turner became
president of the union. Although he called himself an anarchist until he
died it did not show itself in his union activities. Heartbreaking
experience as it might have been, the small union before 1898 had been
anarchistic, that after 1898 was no different to the other ânewâ unions
either in power distribution or policy. There were straws in the wind by
1906. The executive of the union was being seen in some quarters as a
bureaucratic interference with local militancy and initiative. And
complaints were to grow. By 1909 Turner was accused from one quarter of
playing the ârole of one of the most blatant reactionaries with which
the Trades Union movement was ever cursedâ.â[4]
Here we see precisely how the associational function of these small
unions were supplemented by the representative function, and at what
cost. The representative function is not as innocent as it first
appears, as it has implications for the union as a whole. First, in
order to represent workers vis-Ă -vis management, a union needs to
maximise its membership in order to show to bosses it really is
representative when it claims to speak for the workforce. The easiest,
but not the only, way to achieve this is to employ full time officials
out of the dues of the membership, as happened in John Turnerâs case.
Second, such unions need to be able to deliver industrial peace in
return for the satisfaction of demands, otherwise they would not be able
to secure a seat at the negotiating table. This in turn tends to develop
the union as a purely economic organisation, pushing politics out
(typically to political parties), and leads to the creation of a
bureaucracy with interests separate from the rank and file membership.
That bureaucracy then becomes structurally dependent on their position
as mediators between workers and capital and thus prone to reformism and
class collaboration, regardless of the professed ideology of the
bureaucrats.[5] In other words, a consequence of representing workers to
capital is that you also must represent capital to workers, becoming a
barrier to militant rank and file initiative.
The desire for economic representation makes perfect sense in the
absence of a revolutionary perspective, just as the desire for political
representation â i.e. suffrage â makes sense in the absence of an
anti-parliamentary perspective. If you are not opposed to the capitalist
system, representation within it is the most you can ask for. In this
respect, the unions originally developed in this direction because this
is what many of their members, who were not for the most part
revolutionaries, wanted. But once a bureaucracy develops, what the
members want becomes far less consequential, as they are no longer in
control. Thus the unions in this country long ago accepted the
legitimacy of the existence of social classes, between which they sought
to mediate. They do not want to put an end to an exploitative social
system but to get the best for workers within it, which in practice
means collaborating with the bosses and the capitalist system. The class
collaboration of the unions has led them to become more and more a part
of the system. It means that they now not only fail to defend workersâ
interests but often go firmly against them. Their priority is not
fighting the class struggle but getting ârecognitionâ at any price
(recognition from the bosses, of course, not the workers, i.e.
recognition of their representative function to speak on workersâ
behalves).
Once associational and representative functions become intertwined,
unpicking them becomes increasingly difficult. The union becomes backed
by a powerful bureaucracy with vested interests in the status quo, and
often the ability to expel unruly troublemakers. We have recently
experienced opposition from branch union officials to even holding a
membersâ meeting in the course of a dispute![6] The energy it would take
to reform or dislodge such bureaucracies, not just the elected officials
but the structures themselves, is many times that required to simply
bypass the bureaucracy and take action outside it. In 1969 the Donovan
Report, which came out of the Royal Commission into the unions and was
set up by a Labour government, found that 95% of post-war strikes were
unofficial. This changed after the anti-strike legislation of the 1980s
which forced unions to police their rank and file more thoroughly on
pain of asset seizure, but it is a simple illustration of the ease with
which action can be taken. Many, if not most, of these unofficial
strikes would have been organised in the workplace by rank and file
union members and lay officials like shop stewards.
And this raises another problem. Militant workers, including those with
socialist or anarchist leanings, find there is usually a shortage of
willing shop stewards. And what better way to participate in the class
struggle? Soon enough you get trained up in ârep workâ, learning how to
file grievances, do casework and navigate the complex industrial
relations legislation. This is the terrain of representative functions,
a million miles away from direct action.[7] Opportunities might open up
for facility time â paid time off work to carry out union
responsibilities. Such an escape from the day job is welcome. Maybe a
role opens up higher up the ladder, a regional convenor or a branch
official. As another potential shop floor militant climbs the ladder
into the bureaucracy, militancy and revolutionary aims and methods tend
to get left behind, or are neutered by the bureaucratâs role.
This is not, of course, the inevitable consequence of taking a shop
steward position, and there are pros as well as cons. Taking on
positions as stewards can give us greater access to the workplace making
it easier to organise. It also puts us in touch with other militants who
may share our aim in wanting to organise in the workplace. But without a
clear alternative to the representative approach, itâs easy to become
sucked in. The strategy of many state socialist groups is precisely for
their members to climb this ladder. Anarcho-syndicalists need a clear
strategy to avoid these pitfalls.
In the past the unions paid lip service to the emancipation of the
working class and to âsocialismâ (meaning the Labour Party). They donât
even pay lip service now. Todayâs TUC unions are the product of over a
century of bureaucratisation. Associational and representative functions
are now so blurred as to be indistinguishable. Indeed, you join a union
in order to be represented. They have become vast corporations in their
own right, complete with head offices, highly paid executive boards,
legal departments and hundreds of wage labourers in their employ. The
TUC for the most part still backs the Labour Party, despite it
abandoning any pretence of being a workersâ party. Some Socialists have
repeatedly tried to form a new one to replace it. Either way, politics
is pushed out of the unions and into the parliamentary arena, a clear
separation of the economic and the political. All the time we hear
workers and leftists accusing the trade union leaders of âselling outâ
and being bureaucratic. This is, of course, true, but
anarcho-syndicalists view this as inevitable in organisations which
collaborate with capitalism and the state rather than seek to destroy
them.
How does this play out in practice? Let us start by looking at the basic
building block of any union â the branch. The first thing to note is
that the vast majority of branches exist and function away from the
workplace, the seat of struggle. Rather than the branch proactively
organising in the workplace, activists or workers with specific
grievances find the onus on them to initiate contact and maintain
channels of communication. This they only do on rare occasions and it is
safe to say that most workers only attend branch meetings on a handful
of occasions throughout their working lives, if at all. Indeed, internal
union surveys show that at any given point only 5% of union members
attend branch meetings. Nor is it necessarily the case that even those
who attend on a regular basis have much in common. Many unions organise
meetings on the basis of where members live. These meetings can consist
of groups of people who may not work in the same workplace or even the
same industry, the only thing in common being that they happen to belong
to the same union. This type of meeting can even be reduced to members
just turning up to pay dues.
Even in those few unions that do organise on an industrial basis â one
workplace, one union â and thus donât divide the workforce, union
meetings are still dominated, not by workplace matters, but internal
union business. The staple diet of such meetings is endless
correspondence, various motions, countless elections and nominations for
committees, conferences and union positions. What is rarely acknowledged
is that these decisions are taken by a tiny minority of members. As
decisions are taken further up the union ladder, tens of people acting
for hundreds eventually becomes hundreds acting for millions. The
culmination of this charade is the block vote where union leaders cast
votes on behalf of hundreds of thousands of members on policies, and for
people, that the overwhelming majority of members will never have heard
of let alone voted for. The trade unions may still have millions of
members between them, but in day to day union business it is a minority
of officials and activists that speaks for them.
We should also dispel the idea that all branch activists are also
involved in the workplace struggle against the bosses. For a start, in
many unions branch secretaries are required to be on full time release,
and so never see the workplace. And even when they are not officially
full time, they can end up sitting on so many committees and holding so
many positions they do not have the time for something as mundane as
work. Then there are those who are active in the union but have no base
in the workplace. These people can even be on the so called âleftâ of
the union and will argue for all sorts of motions to be passed from
âtroops outâ to freeing Palestine, but do little to organise in the
workplace. Indeed it could be argued that unions act as a check on
militancy, even at branch level. How often do angry workers turn to the
branch for support and advice over incidents that have happened at work,
only to have all that anger deflected away from taking effective action
by branch officials promising to âget something doneâ by contacting head
office or bringing in a full timer? As British syndicalist, Tom Brown,
put it in 1943:
âCentralisation takes control too far away from the place of struggle to
be effective on the workersâ side in that fight. Most disputes arise in
the factory, bus garage or mine. According to trade union procedure the
dispute must be reported to the district office of the union, (and in
some cases to an area office) then to head office, then back again, then
the complicated âmachinery for avoiding disputesâ devised by trade union
âleadersâ and the employersâ lawyers is set in its ball passing motion,
until everyone forgets the original cause of all this passing up and
down. The worker is not allowed any direct approach to, or control of
the problem.
âWe are reminded of the memoirs of a certain court photographer who was
making a picture of the old Emperor of Austria [and wanted him] to turn
his head a little to the left. Of course he could not speak to an
emperor, so he put his request to a captain of the court guard, who
spoke to his colonel, who spoke to a count, the count passed the request
to a duke and he had a word with an archduke who begged his Imperial
Majesty to turn his head a little to the left. The old chap turned his
head and said âIs that sufficient?â and the message trickled back to the
photographer via archduke, duke, count, colonel and captain. The humble
thanks travelled back by the same road. The steps of trade union
communication are just so fixed.â[8]
Despite their failings, branch meetings do at least retain some links
with the workforce they represent. Once we move above branch level, we
enter that strange world of the full time union official whose working
life consists of endless meetings with other union officials, management
and union activists. The only time these people come across ordinary
union members is when they are called in, often by management, to
âresolveâ a problem. The higher up the union structure, the more remote
they become, reaching a pinnacle of detachment with union leaders, who
only come across ordinary working class people on a day to day basis
when they have a friendly chat with their chauffeur or the office
cleaner.
It is safe to say that the unions exist in the main outside the
workplace with the bulk of union activity taking place above the
membersâ heads. The ordinary memberâs commitment is limited to paying
subs, with the expectation of some level of support should trouble
arise. Outside national struggles and strike ballots there is little
encouragement to see the union as anything more than an insurance
scheme, perhaps requiring support itself.
These tendencies towards bureaucracy and the development of
institutional interests separate from the workers themselves are natural
developments of the representative function. However, they are also
increasingly enforced by law. In the UK, industrial action is only
lawful if it is preceded by a properly conducted ballot, employers are
given sufficient notice, and a host of legal technicalities are
followed. Unions are legally liable for damages arising from unlawful
action, and consequently become even more conservative in authorising
ballots and calling off industrial action at any hint of a legal
challenge. The problems with trade unions donât start with the law, but
union legislation has further crippled effective workplace organisation
whilst strengthening the bureaucratic tendencies that had already
developed.
So, given that the unions organise away from the point of struggle, let
us turn to their aims and how they set about achieving them. The main
aim of any union is to maintain its power within the wider trade union
movement, and also to exert pressure and maintain influence on the
state, management, and society as a whole. They seek to do this in
various ways, one of the most important being maintaining as high a
membership as possible. This is of prime importance, not least in the
TUC pecking order. This has now reached the point where it seems to
matter little how remote or inactive that membership is, just as long as
the dues are coming in and membership figures are up. Of all the areas
in which the unions seek to have influence, by far the most important is
their dealings with management, for it is from this area that all their
power flows. They must retain the right to negotiate wages and
conditions with management. Indeed, a âconsultationâ role in cuts has
often been championed as a victory for the union, even while itâs a
defeat for the workers. The 2009 postal dispute is one of the more high
profile recent examples.[9]
It is by having the power to negotiate on behalf of workers that the
trade unions retain their influence within the workplace and ultimately
attract and retain members. This representative function is fundamental
to the existence of trade unions. In turn it is having that control and
influence in the workplace that they are of use to the boss class. The
unions offer stability in the workplace, they channel workersâ anger,
shape and influence their demands and, if need be, police the workforce.
Perhaps this is best summed up by a quote from the boss class itself:
when asked by a reporter why his multinational had recognised unions in
South Africa, a manager replied âhave you ever tried negotiating with a
football field full of militant angry workers?â It was this threat of an
uncontrollable militant workforce that first persuaded the bosses of the
need to accept reformist unions, seeing them as a way to control the
workforce. As that threat of militancy has receded, the trade unions
have become increasingly sidelined, finding themselves social partners
with bosses increasingly unwilling to play the game.
The idea of a workersâ political party goes a long way back. Perhaps the
most famous and influential example would the 1848 Manifesto of the
Communist Party, more commonly known as the Communist Manifesto, which
even before the days of universal suffrage declared that âthe first step
in the revolution by the working class, is to raise the proletariat to
the position of ruling as to win the battle of democracy.â[10] While
Marxâs ideas subsequently developed (particularly following the Paris
Commune of 1871), what remained constant throughout what became known as
âMarxismâ was the centrality of the âneedâ for a workersâ political
party. This organisational form reflected the political content of
mainstream Marxism, which is concerned with the capture and use of state
power to transform society. One of the great legacies of the 20^(th)
century is the strong association of communism with state power, and
totalitarian bureaucratic state power at that. Whilst most Marxists
distance themselves from the horrors of Stalinism, few reject the idea
that revolution entails the capture of state power or the conviction
that the Party is the organisational form to do it.
For Lenin, the working class on its own could only achieve âtrade union
consciousnessâ, i.e. a consciousness of everyday economic life and bread
and butter struggles.[11] But to become revolutionary, it required the
intervention of intellectuals and the leadership of a vanguard party.
Inscribed in Marxist theory and practice is this separation between the
economic organisations of the working class (trade unions) and the
political one (the Party). And this separation is not neutral, but
hierarchical: the party leads the class, the political trumps the
economic. Leon Trotsky expresses this very clearly:
âOnly on the basis of a study of political processes in the masses
themselves, can we understand the role of parties and leaders, whom we
least of all are inclined to ignore. They constitute not an independent,
but nevertheless a very important, element in the process. Without a
guiding organisation, the energy of the masses would dissipate like
steam not enclosed in a piston-box. But nevertheless what moves things
is not the piston or the box, but the steam.â[12]
Trotsky thinks he is giving credit to the working class, and stressing
the lack of separation between the party and the class. In fact, his
metaphor says far more than he intends. Steam is the unthinking product
of applying heat to water, a mere expression of natural, physical laws.
The intelligence in his metaphor is that of the engineers who design and
operate the piston box which captures and directs the energy of the
unthinking mass within it. It is correct that the Party can only ride to
power on the back of the workers. What is not correct is that we have
any need for them to do so, or that this advances the creation of a free
communist society. Trotskyâs view was shared even by left wing Marxists
(âleft communistsâ), such as Amadeo Bordiga, whose opposition to the
class collaboration of the Bolsheviks âunited frontâ strategy reaffirmed
that âthe dictatorship of the proletariatâ really meant the dictatorship
of the Communist Party: âPolitical power cannot be seized, organised,
and operated except through a political party.â[13]
This idea of âthe dictatorship of the proletariatâ is central to Marxist
theory. Much confusion arises from the word âdictatorshipâ, which today
conjures up images of repressive, unelected regimes. This is not
necessarily what is meant (although itâs hard to ignore that wherever
the âdictatorship of the proletariatâ was established in the 20^(th)
century ended up looking a lot like⊠a dictatorship). Bearing in mind
suffrage had barely extended beyond male property owners in the 19^(th)
century, Marx saw any state as a dictatorship of the ruling class
(anarcho-syndicalists agree on this point). In capitalism the state is a
dictatorship of the capitalist class â the bourgeoisie â and this is the
case whether or not the state in question holds free and fair elections
or respects human rights. If we accept this to be true then any
revolution would necessarily involve the proletariat establishing its
own dictatorship.
The form this dictatorship takes is one of the divisions within Marxism.
More reformist, gradualist, social democratic currents subscribe to
something like the vision of the Manifesto, aiming to âwin the battle of
democracyâ. In this analysis, the state is a dictatorship of capital
because it is controlled by capitalist parties. Therefore, if a workersâ
party obtains power, the state will serve the interests of the workers.
The state is seen as a relatively neutral instrument which serves the
interests of whichever classâ representatives control it:
â[I]t follows that every class which is struggling for mastery, even
when its domination, as is the case with the proletariat, postulates the
abolition of the old form of society in its entirety and of domination
itself, must first conquer for itself political power in order to
represent its interest in turn as the general interest.â[14]
This is, of course, where we part company with Marx. The idea was that
since the state was part of the âpolitical superstructureâ built upon
the âeconomic baseâ, a âworkers stateâ would necessarily âwither awayâ
once it had centralised all the means of production within itself. By
uniting the working class with the means of production and thus
eliminating the âeconomic baseâ of the state in private property it
renders itself obsolete. In practice, centralising all property in the
state means the state becomes the sole capitalist and employer.
It is easy to go reading through the works of Lenin and pulling out
quotes showing an authoritarian politics that prefigures the police
state he ultimately helped create. âWhat is to be done?â, written in
1905 to address the problems of organising under the repressive Tsarist
regime, is a favourite for this kind of criticism. But this is too easy.
Rather, we should criticise Lenin at his most libertarian and his most
radical. The most significant text here is âState and revolutionâ,
written in 1917, between the February and October revolutions in Russia.
In this text, Lenin emphatically rejects the âopportunistâ idea that the
existing state can simply be taken over and made to serve the interests
of the proletariat. Rather, he insists it must be âabolished.â[15] This
has even led some to suggest he was flirting with anarchism.
But a closer reading shows no such thing, as Lenin himself was keen to
stress. In place of the existing state, Lenin had taken up the slogan
âall power to the sovietsâ, which was popular with Russian workers (and
anarchists) at the time. The soviets were councils of workers and
political party delegates which had first emerged in the Revolution of
1905. For Lenin, linking this to Marxâs rethinking of the âdictatorship
of the proletariatâ following the Paris Commune, the soviets were the
form of the âworkers stateâ, through which the proletariat would
exercise its dictatorship. So, why would anarcho-syndicalists take issue
with this? On closer examination, Leninâs views are far less radical and
libertarian than they first appear.
Crucially, Lenin retains the fundamentally bourgeois conception of
politics as a competition for power between political parties. His
âinnovationâ was to transpose this power struggle from the bourgeois
forum of parliamentary politics, to the revolutionary proletarian forum
provided by the soviets. But this change in venue does not change the
fundamental problem of equating the interests of a class with those of
its supposed representatives. Indeed, Leon Trotsky sees the proletariat
and the Communist Party as indistinguishable, writing that âthe
revolution in the course of a few months placed the proletariat and the
Communist Party in power.â[16] Which was it? History reveals it was the
Communist Party which established its rule over the proletariat.
Remember that Lenin had not rejected the idea of the vanguard party. He
had not rejected the idea of âpoliticsâ as a struggle for state power
between competing parties. And so his party competed for power in the
Soviets. Enjoying genuine popularity in many places, they consolidated
their majority by becoming representatives rather than delegates. Where
they could not secure majorities, they did what all politicians do if
they can get away with it, and gerrymandered and manipulated their
majorities. Once majorities were secured, the soviets were sidelined or
suppressed, as the Communist Party formed a government. And indeed this
government was a dictatorship in the more familiar sense, complete with
a secret police which began rounding up revolutionaries, from anarchists
to rival socialists. The brutal suppression of the Kronstadt Commune is
only the most iconic event of this counter-revolution.[17]
Even at its most radical, Leninism maintains the separation of the
economic struggles of the âmassesâ from the political party who leads
them, and maintains that revolution is a question of first the Party
seizing state power, before using that power â those secret police and
standing armies â to impose âcommunismâ from above in the form of
economic and social diktats.[18] By contrast, the soviet/council system
poses economic delegates against political representatives; bottom-up,
direct democracy against top-down decrees; the free federation of
workers against the dictatorship of the proletariat. Against the
nationalisation of all property in the âworkers stateâ, it poses the
expropriation of social wealth to serve human needs, without a
âtransitional phaseâ of a dictatorial state which weâre promised will
âwither away.â To conceive of soviets as a state is to strip them of
their revolutionary character and transform them into a mere alternative
means of electing a government to run the state apparatus. Hence Rudolf
Rocker writes:
âThe council system brooks no dictatorships as it proceeds from totally
different assumptions. In it is embodied the will from below, the
creative energy of the toiling masses. In dictatorship, however, only
lives barren compulsion from above, which will suffer no creative
activity and proclaims blind submission as the highest laws for all. The
two cannot exist together. In Russia dictatorship proved victorious.
Hence there are no more soviets there. All that is left of them is the
name and a gruesome caricature of its original meaning.â[19]
Despite the collapse of the USSR and its allied bloc, which for a long
time provided moral (and sometimes material) support to much of the
statist left, ârevolutionaryâ workersâ parties are still very much the
staple of leftist organisation. These latter day Leninists are most
likely to be found in anything resembling a popular movement, where
theyâll promptly form a âcoalitionâ and appoint themselves leaders.
Calling for âunityâ behind their leadership (often, rival âcoalitionsâ
each calling for âunityâ and decrying the actions of the other), they
tend to smother any grassroots initiative with a stifling routine of
marches (a great recruiting ground) and diversions into parliamentary
politics. The examples are too numerous to list here. But whilst we can
complain about the antics of the Left, ultimately their ability to
control movements rests in the weakness of a libertarian, direct action
culture within the wider working class which would render such
manoeuvres transparent and ineffective.
However, whilst making ample reference to Lenin and Trotsky, in practice
the current array of state socialists fall short even of those flawed
figures. Today, most of the ârevolutionaryâ parties serve as little more
than the extra-parliamentary wing of the Labour Party, urging âvote for
Labour without illusionsâ like clockwork every election. In 2010, this
followed just four months after the very same ârevolutionaryâ party had
co-organised a âRage Against Labourâ march against the Labour Party
Conference in Brighton! We imagine even Lenin would blush at such naked
opportunism. There are exceptions with those socialists who seek to
found an alternative Labour Party, although this pretty much adds up to
the same thing. Revolutionary rhetoric serves as a mask for reformist
practice. And so we come to the Labour party.
Unlike the Communist and Socialist Parties of the mainstream Marxist
position, the Labour Party (and many of its equivalents around the
world) has never claimed to be revolutionary. To criticise it for
failing to be so would therefore miss the point. However, the Labour
Party, as its name would infer, has long purported to represent the
interests of the working class. This pretence only finally expired with
the rise of âNew Labourâ, although many on the left still cling
forlornly to its corpse. Others, having been kicked out of the party for
being too left wing, have resolved to form a new workersâ party to serve
the purpose the old one did before its recent neoliberal turn. What both
of these perspectives share is the assumption that the Labour Party ever
was an asset for the working class. Rose tinted spectacles aside, this
premise cannot be sustained.
The Labour Party was founded in 1906 with the election of 29 MPs from
the Labour Representation Committee, made up mainly of trade union
officials with support from socialist groups. The immediate trigger for
this was the ruling in the 1901 Taff Vale case which had made trade
unions liable for loss of profits during strike action. The ruling was
reversed by the Liberal-Labour supported Trades Disputes Act in 1906.
The honeymoon was short lived. There was a rising wave of class
conflicts in 1910â1914, as discontent with both union bureaucracies and
Labour MPs spread amongst the more combative sections of the working
class. Historian Bob Holton writes that for many militant workers âthe
clear-cut non-parliamentary message of syndicalism proved more
attractive, since it avoided the problems of political incorporation
which increasingly beset the Labour Party in parliamentâ (we will
discuss British syndicalism in the following chapter). Indeed, in 1912
the Liberal cabinet minister, Lloyd George, declared the parliamentary
socialists âthe best policemen for the syndicalist.â[20]
Having opted to support the First World War, therefore sending millions
of workers to die for their bosses, Labourâs first taste of real
political power came during the war when they were rewarded with a part
in a coalition government. They further underlined their ruling class
politics by opposing the upsurge in workersâ militancy that wartime
austerity helped ferment. As strikes spread, particularly on âRed
Clydesideâ, Labour responded by helping break them. As socialists and
anarchists were imprisoned for refusing to sign up, Labour rallied to
âWin the Warâ and sought to expel pacifist/anti-war elements from within
its ranks.
The first two majority Labour governments were no better. When J. H.
Thomas, union leader and MP, âwas appointed to the Colonial Office (âŠ)
he introduced himself to his departmental heads with the statement: âIâm
here to see there is no mucking about with the British Empire.ââ Their
first term only lasted 10 months, but on top of their enthusiastic
imperialism they managed to oppose strikes by dockers, London tramway
workers, and railway workers, invoking the 1920 Emergency Powers Act
against the latter two, threatening to declare a state of emergency. In
1926, and back in opposition, the party feared the general strike would
lead to revolutionary events and scrambled to prevent it. Three years
later they again formed a minority government with a promise to lower
rampant unemployment. Within two years it had more than doubled.[21]
From its very inception âworking class political representationâ acted
like every other capitalist political party â at best simply overseeing
the misery caused by the capitalist economy, and at worst actively
repressing working class self-organisation. In other words, Labour has
acted for the bosses and against the working class.
The single most cited âachievementâ of the Labour Party is the
âfoundationâ of the welfare state in 1948 (in reality, this was an
expansion of the limited welfare state introduced by the Liberals in
1912). Universal healthcare and unemployed benefits certainly represent
gains for the working class insofar as they are paid for by the bosses.
But why were they introduced? The foundations for the welfare state were
laid by the 1942 cross party Beveridge Report, which recommended the
measures later implemented by Clement Attleeâs Labour government when
they came to power in 1945. Wary of the worldwide revolutionary wave
which followed the end of the First World War, there was a cross party
consensus that war weary workers would need to be given incentives not
to turn their discontent, or even their guns, on the government. The
Tory Quintin Hogg summed up the prevailing mood in 1943 when he said âwe
must give them reform or they will give us revolution.â Following the
war, a wave of squatting by homeless workers swept disused military
bases and âbombed outâ residential areas. With the threat of revolution
seeming to lurk behind these actions, the welfare state was a reform
needed as much by the ruling class as the workers.
But even this self-interest was not enough. The second strand of the
cross party consensus was that a welfare state served âthe national
interestâ of building profitable British industry by shifting the cost
of maintaining the workforce from private businesses on to the state via
national insurance payments deducted from workersâ wages.[22] It is
ironic that âLabourâs greatest achievementâ was supported by a cross
party consensus which would have almost certainly seen the
recommendations of the Beveridge report implemented regardless of who
won the 1945 general election. Certainly, the fact it was political
ârepresentatives of the working classâ overseeing its introduction seems
of little importance when they were implementing ruling class consensus.
In any event, without the tangible threat of working class unrest, that
consensus would never have been acted on. So let us fast forward to the
1970s to see how âworking class political representationâ dealt with
significant working class struggle.
The 1970s was a decade of major industrial unrest, as inflation hit
double figures and wages failed to keep pace with the spiralling cost of
living. Legislation limiting pay rises was proving unpopular and
unenforceable in the face of widespread unofficial action outside of the
control of the TUC unions and their Labour Party associates.
Consequently, Labour turned to the TUC to implement âvoluntaryâ pay
freezes, with partial success as unions policed their angry membership.
The crisis deepened and by 1976 Britain went to the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) for emergency assistance. This came with the usual
strings attached â austerity measures and public service cuts which the
Labour government was only too keen to implement. The confrontation
between the working class and their âpolitical representativesâ came to
a head in 1978â79 in the so called winter of discontent.[23] As strike
waves brought the country to a standstill Labour became unelectable.
They wouldnât taste power again until their âNew Labourâ rebranding,
having jettisoned any pretence of advancing working class interests (a
claim by this point thoroughly discredited by their record in office and
in opposition).
From its very beginnings the political representation of the working
class has never served the working class. It cannot. As even Lenin
recognised, the state serves capitalism and cannot be made to serve the
interests of the proletariat. This does not only apply to the Labour
Party, but all political parties. Consider the German Green Party, who
once in government sent riot police against protesters trying to stop
nuclear waste being transported through their communities â precisely
the kind of green activism they had once supported. In 2001 they
supported the invasion of Afghanistan as part of a coalition government.
In Ireland too, the Green Party went from vocal supporters of the âShell
to Seaâ movement against the Corrib gas project to actually implementing
it. Green minister Eamon Ryan was put in charge of the project, the
Greens having dropped their election promises in order to enter a
coalition government. On that note, the Liberal Democratâs rapid u-turn
on tuition fees in 2010, from a promise to abolish them to trebling them
once in government, provides a recent illustration of this dynamic (and
one which fuelled the student protests and riots across the country). In
2011 in Lewisham, one self-described âsocialistâ, the Labour Councillor
Mike Harris even defended his making âdemocratic socialist cutsâ (which
are apparently better than nasty âTory cutsâ).
We are reminded of the anarchist Mikhail Bakuninâs sardonic remark, that
âwhen the people are being beaten with a stick, they are not much
happier if it is called âthe Peopleâs Stickâ.âŠâ Party politics aims at
capturing the state, but when you capture the state, the state also
captures you.
We have seen that while trade unions have their roots in working class
associations, they have become increasingly dominated by their
representative functions. This has led to the development of powerful,
paid bureaucracies who collaborate with bosses and the state, putting
their own needs above those of the membership. The result is often an
inability to even win basic defensive struggles, and frequent
interference with rank and file initiative and militancy. But while the
trade unions at least have their roots in working class associations,
the so called âworkers partiesâ do not. Leninist parties, even at their
most radical, remain fixed on the capture of state power for themselves
in order to implement âsocialismâ by diktat. The Labour Party meanwhile
was founded by trade union bureaucrats and has always played an
anti-working class role. This is because of the nature of political
parties, which have to compete for state power. The prize means getting
to manage capitalism, which pits the party against the working class.
All these mainstream ideologies of the workersâ movement effect a
separation of the economic and the political. âPoliticsâ is seen as the
business of the party, its venue the state (normally through engagement
in the parliamentary process). âEconomicâ issues are seen as the domain
of trade unions. This dual system of political and economic
representation of the working class ends up acting against the working
class. We need to look elsewhere for inspiration.
Units 1â3 of the SelfEd history of anarcho-syndicalism cover the origins
of capitalism and the early workersâ movement. Our critique of the trade
unions stems mainly from our collective experiences with the trade
unions within the Solidarity Federation and its predecessors the Direct
Action Movement (DAM) and the Syndicalist Workersâ Federation (SWF).
Consequently there is little to recommend by way of reading. We have
drawn heavily on the 1991 DAM pamphlet âWinning the class warâ, which
remains a worthwhile read. The basic argument set out there has been
updated and expanded here to feed into the discussions in the rest of
this pamphlet. In terms of Marxism and Leninism, Maurice Brintonâs âThe
Bolsheviks and workers controlâ remains a classic account of the counter
revolutionary role played by Leninâs Bolsheviks in sidelining workersâ
self-organisation in the factory committees and soviets, and ultimately
replacing them with party dictatorship. Daniel Cohn-Benditâs âObsolete
Communism â the left wing alternativeâ also contains a critical account
of mainstream Marxist theory and practice. The author, a prominent
anarchist in the events of May 1968 in France (see Chapter 4) has,
funnily enough, subsequently become a Green MEP. In terms of critical
accounts of the Labour Party, the SolFedâs predecessor the Syndicalist
Workers Federation wrote a three part account of âHow Labour governed
1945â51â.[24]
This chapter will introduce three radical currents from the historical
workersâ movement. First we will look at anarchism, the name given to
the anti-state socialists in the European workersâ movement of the
19^(th) and 20^(th) centuries. Anarchism, as a political doctrine,
opposed itself to all statist politics, whether parliamentary or
ârevolutionaryâ, instead placing its emphasis on human capacities for
voluntary co-operation, mutual aid and working class direct action.
Second, we will encounter syndicalism. Emerging in France, the
syndicalist movement of rank and file controlled, radical unions spread
to many countries taking new forms in different conditions. We will
focus on the French CGT, the North American IWW and the syndicalist
currents in the workersâ movement in Britain. In all cases, working
class direct action was the watchword of the syndicalists who, often
under anarchist influence, formed unions based on the shared economic
interests of workers. Finally, we will look at council communism, a
radical Marxist current which broke with orthodoxies such as the
necessity of the Party and the capture of state power. The council
communists drew some very similar conclusions to many anarchists and
anarcho-syndicalists, but we will also explore some important
differences.
Anarchism has its origins in the working class and socialist movements
of Europe in the 19^(th) century.[25] It was a major force in the âFirst
Internationalâ, an alliance of socialist organisations and unions which
existed between 1864 and 1876. When that organisation split between
pro-state socialists (who became known as Marxists and associated with
the colour red) and anti-state socialists (who became known as
anarchists and associated with the colour black), the German statesman
Otto von Bismarck remarked that âCrowned heads, wealth and privilege may
well tremble should ever again the Black and Red unite!â
Anarchism, covering all the anti-state socialists, took numerous forms.
It is often said the three main currents are mutualism (associated with
Pierre-Joseph Proudhon), collectivism (associated with Mikhail Bakunin)
and communism (associated with Ericco Malatesta and Peter Kropotkin). In
reality, there was considerable overlap and evolution, as ideas
developed in conjunction with the movement. The ideas of mutualism, a
self-managed market economy probably had their greatest influence on the
co-operative movement. Anarchist collectivism proposed expropriation of
private property to be owned communally and operated under worker
self-management, with money abolished and replaced by some form of
labour notes, essentially IOUs for work done. Collectivism was a
significant influence on Spanish anarcho-syndicalism in the 1920s and
30s although its modern influence has waned.
The third school, that to which the anarcho-syndicalist IWA belongs, is
anarchist or libertarian communism. The origins of anarchist communism
are most often credited to âthe anarchist Princeâ Peter Kropotkin,
although he was largely taking up and elaborating ideas that originated
in the Italian section of the First International. Like collectivism,
anarchist communism is for worker self-management and the abolition of
private property, but goes further in advocating the abolition of market
exchange and money to be replaced by production and distribution
according to the principle of âfrom each according to ability, to each
according to needs.â
In all its incarnations, anarchism was never simply âanti-stateâ, but
has always been the anti-state wing of the socialist movement. Anarchist
collectivism was firmly in the camp of the class struggle, as its
leading proponent Mikhail Bakunin was a prominent member of the First
International, and had great influence on the more libertarian sections
(which later fed into the development of anarcho-syndicalism).
In the case of anarchist communism, however, there was sometimes less
emphasis on the class struggle and more on the human capacity for mutual
aid and voluntary co-operation, which Kropotkin had set out at length as
an important factor of evolution.[26] Thus, anarchist communism often
had a more humanist bent and the tradition put varying emphasis on the
class struggle as either a progressive or regressive force:
â[T]he theoreticians of anarcho-communism (Peter Kropotkin, Ericco
Malatesta, and others) maintained that the roots of social development
lie in progress of the ethical concepts of humanity; that capitalism is
a regressive system since it undermines the intrinsic social nature of
humanity based on mutual aid; and that the division of humanity into
warring classes plays a reactionary role, retarding the self-realization
of the human personalityâ[27]
For this reason, early anarchist communism did not focus primarily on
the labour movement. In 1907, there was an important debate between
Pierre Monatte and Ericco Malatesta at the International Anarchist
Congress in Amsterdam. Monatte argued for a neutral syndicalism that was
not political, and not even anarchist, on the grounds that workersâ
economic conditions gave them âidentical interestsâ, so that political
âdifferences of opinion, often subtle and artificial, fall into the
background in the syndicate, enabling agreement.â[28] In contrast,
Malatesta had argued that:
âThe basic error of Monatte and of all revolutionary syndicalists, in my
opinion, derives from an overly simplistic conception of class struggle.
It is a conception whereby the economic interests of all workers â the
working class â are held to be equal (âŠ) The reality is very different,
in my view (âŠ) there are therefore no classes, in the proper sense of
the term, because there are no class interests. There exists competition
and struggle within the working âclassâ, just as there does amongst the
bourgeoisie.â[29]
Monatte and Malatesta agreed that syndicalism was an economic movement,
but for Malatesta this wasnât sufficient, and must be supplemented by
separate anarchist political organisations. This separation was most
clearly articulated in his 1925 article âSyndicalism and anarchism.â[30]
In it, he makes the case for syndicalist unions which unite all workers
on an economic basis, and separate political, anarchist organisations of
varying kinds which operate both inside and outside the unions.
Malatesta by no means denied the importance of the labour movement. On
the contrary, he insisted that âeveryone, or almost everyone, is in
agreement on the usefulness and the need for the anarchists to take an
active part in the labour movement and to be its supporters and
promoters.â
Syndicalist unions, he argued, were often founded on anarchist
principles. However, they either proved ineffective and thus remained
small, barely functioning as unions at all, or they won their initial
battles, and these victories attracted more workers into their ranks,
which enabled them to win more battles and attract more workers and so
on. The problem with this, Malatesta diagnosed, was that there was no
reason to think these workers, who were attracted by the unionâs success
in winning gains for workers, shared the anarchist principles upon which
the union was founded.
âFor a union to serve its own ends and at the same time act as a means
of education and ground for propaganda aimed at radical social change,
it needs to gather together all workers â or at least those workers who
look to an improvement of their conditions â and to be able to put up
some resistance to the bosses. Can it possibly wait for all the workers
to become anarchists before inviting them to organise themselves and
before admitting them into the organisation?â
Thus he held that âsyndicalism (by which I mean the practical variety
and not the theoretical sort, which everyone tailors to their own shape)
is by nature reformistâ and that âpure anarchism cannot be a practical
solution while people are forced to deal with bosses and with
authority.â For that reason he argued for a separation of the
necessarily reformist, economic, syndicalist unions from the various
political anarchist organisations which should propagandise
revolutionary anarchist ideas within them. For Malatesta, the role of
anarchists was not to make the unions more anarchist, but to argue
within them for anarchist tactics while keeping them open to all workers
who wanted to fight to improve their conditions, regardless of political
affiliation. Meanwhile, the anarchists should also fight within the
union to keep it neutral from political parties. âIf the survival of the
organisation and the needs and wishes of the organised make it really
necessary to compromise and enter into muddied negotiations with
authority and the employers, so be it. But let it be the responsibility
of others, not the anarchists.â
For Malatesta, therefore, any concession or negotiation under capitalism
was reformist, and so it was important for anarchists to remain âpureâ,
leaving this dirty business to others. This approach would become known
as âdual organisationalismâ, a current of anarchism that holds that
mass, class organisations such as unions need a specific political
organisation operating within them. But not all dual organisationalists
think alike. While Malatesta saw the role of anarchists as keeping
themselves pure on political lines and keeping unions organised along
economic lines, independent of political ideas, others sought to use
political organisation as a means to politicise economic associations â
to âanarchiseâ syndicalist unions.
This brings us to the âOrganisational Platform of the Libertarian
Communists.â This text was published in 1926 by the Dielo Truda group,
who were anarchists in exile after the Communist Party consolidation of
power in the young and misnamed Soviet Union. Drawing on their
experiences of the struggle against both capitalism and Bolshevism, they
set out a template for anarchist organisation which remains influential
among anarchists today.
First of all, the Platform firmly espouses anarchist communism as its
goal, and situates this firmly within the class struggle. The document
outlines the necessity for violent social revolution and the anarchist
opposition to all states including democratic ones. In terms of their
attitude to unions, syndicalist and mainstream, the Platform argues that
they can have no ideology of their own and therefore any union âalways
reflects the ideologies of a range of political groupings, notably of
those most intensively at work within its ranks.â[31] The necessity is
therefore for anarchists to organise themselves politically and work
intensely both inside the unions to âanarchiseâ them and outside them to
exert a similar influence in other spheres. Thus, the Platform is
supportive of anarcho-syndicalism as âa step forwardâ, but argues that
syndicalist unions only become or remain anarcho-syndicalist because of
the vigorous political organisation of anarchists within their ranks to
keep them that way, and âto prevent any slide towards opportunism.â[32]
Thus âplatformistsâ, as those influenced by the Platform are
colloquially known, are also dual organisationists. But rather than
keeping the economic organisation apolitical, the task of the political
organisation is to politicise it with anarchism. There are four famous
organisational principles set out to define the basis of the political
organisation which should carry out this task: theoretical unity;
tactical unity; collective responsibility and federalism.[33] The
Platform wagers that thusly organised, anarchists will be able to out
organise state socialist parties within the trade unions, soviets and
other organs of the working class, and so ensure the working class
movement develops in an anarchist direction and the revolution develops
in the direction of libertarian communism and not state socialism.
The advocacy of a tight, unified and disciplined political organisation
reminded many anarchists at the time of a political party, and the
authors of the Platform were labelled âanarcho-Bolshevikâ in some
quarters. This criticism strikes us as unfair. If one wants to organise
an anarchist political organisation, the principles set out in the
Platform make perfect sense in terms of combining unity of action with
internal democracy and thus combining effective political organisation
with anarchist principles. From an anarcho-syndicalist point of view the
problems lie elsewhere. For instance, in the next section we will see
how the slide of certain syndicalist unions into reformism was not
because of the lack of political organisation within their ranks, but
rather a function of the very âapoliticalâ nature the Platform affirms.
Thus platformists can also be anarcho-syndicalists, but
anarcho-syndicalists are not necessarily platformists. Certainly to
anarcho-syndicalist eyes, the Platform places too much emphasis on the
ability of political organisations to combat the material contradictions
which arise from unions organising under capitalism, principally the
development and domination of the representative function over the
associational one. As anarcho-syndicalists, we of course believe these
contradictions can be successfully navigated in a way consistent with
our revolutionary principles. But before we can elaborate, we must first
examine some of these contradictions in the case of syndicalism, from
which anarcho-syndicalism has evolved.
The workersâ movement in France had faced severe repression in the
aftermath of the 1871 Paris Commune. Radical tendencies were forced
underground, and it was in this period that the stereotype of the
anarchist bomb thrower emerged, as some anarchists turned away from the
labour movement towards âpropaganda by the deedâ: assassinations and
bombings against the rich. However, by the late 19^(th) century, there
was something of a regrouping of the workersâ movement witfh the
development of an anarchist influenced form of trade unionism â
revolutionary syndicalism. Rudolf Rocker writes that this tendency
âdeveloped quite spontaneously within the French working class as a
reaction against political Socialism, the cleavages in which for a long
time permitted no unified trade union movement.â[34]
This movement had its origins in a coming together of existing unions
and the âbourses du travailâ, mutual aid schemes including âjob
placement, unemployment benefits, relocation aid, and aid for those
injured on the jobâ, as well as cultural, educational and propaganda
services and some of the union functions of organising strikes.[35]
Anarchist involvement was significant in the bourses and, as Rocker
notes, the anarchist message of class unity gained popularity in the
face of a political socialist movement wrought with sectarian divisions.
French revolutionary syndicalism proposed this unity be brought about
through a general union for workers. That union was the CGT (General
Confederation of Labour), founded in 1895. In its early days, the union
was under heavy anarchist influence, and elected a series of anarchist
and non-party socialist general secretaries, including Victor
Griffuelhes. Paul Mason writes that:
âIn the space of a decade Griffuelhes had created a superbly effective
form of trade unionism; with minimal dues-paying and bureaucracy the
militant workers could, every so often, unleash a lean, mean striking
machine. What is more, they did it not just in an atmosphere of
repression but of stolid refusal to negotiate; only in the years 1905
and 1906 did the number of strikes ended by negotiation rise above 10%.
Nine out of ten strikes finished without any formal contract across the
table: either you lost and went back to work or, as with Haviland, the
boss opened the factory gates and upped the wages. Sixty percent ended
this way, with victory to the unions.â[36]
By its very nature as a general union, the CGT was open to all workers.
Consequently âthe CGT was not composed exclusively of revolutionary
trade unions, certainly half of its members were of reformist tendency
and had only joined the CGT because they recognised that the dependence
of the trade unions on the political parties was a misfortune for the
movement.â[37] If we ask why reformists were relatively weak, we need
only note the ruling classâ preference for repression and refusal to
negotiate, which limited the space for reformist unionism and class
collaboration. Social partnership takes two, and the bosses werenât
playing⊠at first at least.
As a result, revolutionary ideas held great sway within the ranks of the
CGT. These were most clearly articulated in the Charter of Amiens in
1906, and in the writings of its leading theoretician, Emile Pouget (to
which we will return in the following chapter). The Amiens Charter was a
clear statement of the CGTâs revolutionary syndicalism.[38] The Charter
espoused a revolutionary programme, but also enshrined âpolitical
neutralityâ, understood as standing outside all political schools and
parties but not opposed to them, leaving political party allegiance (or
lack of) to the conscience of individual members. âThe Charter served to
minimize political dissension in the unions, which were to focus
attention exclusively on the economic struggle.â[39] Against the
political parties, the CGT defined itself as an economic organisation
which grouped âtogether all workers conscious of the fight to be carried
out for the disappearance of wage labour and of employers.â In doing so,
it made the ârevolutionaryâ in ârevolutionary syndicalismâ a matter of
internal democracy. So long as revolutionaries formed a majority, the
union espoused a revolutionary perspective and pursued uncompromising
class conflict and social change via direct action methods.
But in the early 20^(th) century, bosses and the state began to react to
the gains of the CGT with a more conciliatory attitude. This increased
the space for reformists to operate, as class collaboration could be
seen to bear fruit. By 1909, the growth of the union had put the
revolutionaries in the minority (the CGT grew from 100,000 members in
1902 to 700,000 in 1912, out of a population of 7 million). Victor
Griffuelhes resigned as general secretary amidst machinations against
him, and Ămile Pouget left the union, disillusioned. The slide into
class collaboration, reformism and bureaucratisation was crowned by the
CGTâs support for the national war effort in 1914. This was the most
decisive break with its revolutionary, internationalist origins.
Although revolutionaries remained inside the CGT to try and pursue an
anti-militarist agenda, following the First World War it increasingly
fell under the sway of political parties, leading to a series of splits
as revolutionaries and others left the organisation. The CGT still
exists today, and even maintains elements of the Amiens Charter in the
constitutions of many of its member unions. But in practice it has
become almost indistinguishable from other modern trade union
federations, with all the pitfalls that implies
As the CGT grew, syndicalist ideas were also taking root amongst the
working class in North America. The IWW was founded in 1905 amidst
violent class conflict. âFew strikes took place without loss of life.
The resulting bitterness had made the prospect of fundamental change
appealing to most workers.â[40] Much like the CGT, it espoused a
revolutionary intent and oriented itself to the whole working class, not
just particular crafts or trades. They called this model âindustrial
unionismâ, where all the workers in one industry, whatever their job,
belonged to the same industrial union, and in turn these industrial
unions all belonged to the âOne Big Unionâ of the IWW. At the time only
a minority of workers were organised, and the IWW set out to âorganise
the unorganisedâ. From its very beginnings, the IWW was also a racially
mixed union at a time of widespread segregation. âBig Billâ Haywood
issued a statement of intent at the founding conference, declaring that
âwe are here today to confederate the workersâŠinto a working class
movement that shall have for its purpose the emancipation of the working
class from the slave bondage of capitalism.â[41]
On the participants at the founding conference, historian Patrick
Renshaw writes that they were not representative of the working class as
a whole, but rather the radical elements of it.
âMost of them came from unions that, for one reason or another, were at
loggerheads with the AF of L [American Federation of Labour]. They were
all radicals, and most of the leading personalities had been influenced
by socialism of varying kinds, though this was often overlaid with
syndicalism or anarchism. They shared a common conviction that the craft
form of unionism, represented by the AF of L, should be replaced by
industrial organisation.â[42]
Consequently, the IWW represented an uneasy truce between militant
unionists, anarchists, syndicalists and party socialists, with Marxism a
major influence (much of their famous preamble paraphrases passages from
Marx[43]).
âTensions between revolutionaries and reformers manifested itself in
countless disagreements over tactics. The most bitter of these within
the ranks of the IWW itself involved those who urged the IWW to have a
political arm and those who argued that the basic power of workers was
at the point of production.â[44]
The basic fault line was between those who wished for the IWW to be an
economic organisation linked to a separate political wing, and those who
argued for direct industrial action as the means of social and political
change. The most notable of the former tendency was Daniel DeLeon of the
Socialist Labour Party (SLP), who wanted the IWWâs industrial muscle to
back the partyâs electoral ambitions. Opposing this view were the
various shades of direct actionists, who argued that the political aims
of the union, enshrined in the preamble as including âthe abolition of
the wage systemâ, were best pursued on the industrial front and thus
that the IWW was both a political and an economic organisation at the
same time.[45] This battle was settled in favour of the direct
actionists in 1908, with the expulsion of the DeLeonists. Subsequently,
the IWW engaged in a series of high profile free speech fights,
confirming this attitude to pursuing political and social goals through
direct action rather than recourse to party politics.
The Wobblies, as they were known, grew in size and reputation off the
back of several high profile struggles, most notably the aforementioned
free speech fights and the 1912 Lawrence textile strike, where the IWW
had only a few hundred members but exerted great influence. But they
found that membership tended to swell dramatically with struggles, and
then ebb away. Itâs been said that âmany a worker who did not carry the
red membership card or had kept up dues payments was still to be counted
a Wobbly.â[46] The IWW was opposed on principle to the kind of
incentives for member retention pursued by more mainstream unions, such
as health or insurance benefits, and instead opted to deploy a job
delegate system. This entailed travelling organisers authorised to
collect dues and form union locals amongst the highly mobile, casual
workforce of the early 20^(th) century United States. Consequently, âa
local could exist in the hat or satchel of a mobile delegate.â[47]
This was an innovative model and one which refused to succumb to the
temptation to stabilise membership against the ebbs and flows of
struggle with a host of member services. But it also brings to the fore
a dual meaning of the term âOne Big Unionâ. On the one hand, this meant
âOne Big Unionâ as opposed to âmany sectional unionsâ. This conception
was perfectly compatible with the ever shifting membership of the IWW,
and in fact made sense as casual workers could simply transfer from one
industrial union to another within the IWW if they changed industries.
However, the other interpretation was that âOne Big Unionâ meant all, or
at least a substantial proportion of, workers needed to be brought into
the ranks of the union for the purposes of a revolutionary general
strike and the transition to industrial democracy:
â[The] industrial unions would fight for gains within the existing
system until the IWW was strong enough to call a general strike that
would bring all economic activity to a standstill. The condition for
returning to work would be the substitution of industrial unions for all
business enterprises and governmental agencies. The means of production
would then be run by the unions to satisfy social needs rather than
private profit.â[48]
The extent to which this was a literal aspiration or a revolutionary
myth varies with the Wobbly. Some âWobsâ were unaware of the
revolutionary aspect of the IWW when they joined,[49] and the reality is
that both interpretations coexisted within the IWW.[50] What is clear is
that the US government took the revolutionary threat of the IWW
seriously enough to launch a brutal wave of repression. Between 1916 and
1918, dues paying membership soared from 60,000 to 100,000, with
influence extending far further than those numbers alone. This also gave
the Wobblies a significant cultural influence on the wider working
class. In 1917, using damage to war production as the pretext, over 150
leading Wobblies were arrested, tried on spurious charges and given long
prison sentences. Union halls were raided by armed vigilantes and shoot
outs ensued. Of course, only the Wobblies were arrested and sentenced to
long jail terms, or simply lynched, as in the case of Wesley
Everest.[51] The repression broke the IWW as a serious force, and the
apparent âsuccessâ of the Communist Party in Russia led to a resurgent
Communist influence which eventually split the declining organisation in
two in 1924.
After a period of two rival IWWs (who at times fought in the streets for
control of the HQ), the much weakened official IWW continued through the
1920s and 30s under increased anarchist influence, but as an
increasingly fragmented and marginal force (though as late as 1936, the
IWW on the Philadelphia docks had the power to prevent a ship leaving
with munitions for the Spanish fascists[52]). It survived through the
post-war period and remains active today.[53]
Finally, we turn to British syndicalism. The British context was
somewhat different to elsewhere as, by the early 20^(th) century,
Britain had a mature industrial economy and a well established trade
union movement which was soon to gain a parliamentary wing through the
Labour Party. Consequently, the influence of French revolutionary
syndicalism and American industrial unionism led to a different kind of
syndicalist movement. Whereas French and American syndicalists (and
others) had to endure harsh repression, in Britain radical workers faced
a different problem:
âInstead of undue repression, it was increasingly agreed [by the ruling
class] that trade union demands could be more effectively diffused by
bargaining and in particular by utilising union officials as a mediating
influence between labour and capital.â[54]
Thus British syndicalism emerged as a rank and file reaction against the
recuperation of the existing labour movement into a mediating,
representative role. In a sense, it was a rebellion of the associational
function of unions against the representative one. Its idea of unionism
was âthe workers unitedâ as opposed to the bureaucratic apparatus of
paid officials, legalism and so on, which mediated this collective
power. It was also fuelled by the failings of the trade unions and the
parliamentary socialists to defend workersâ living conditions, as
falling real wages, increasing unemployment, and deskilling squeezed the
working class. The great strategic debate in British syndicalism was
between âdual unionismâ â setting up independent revolutionary unions
like in France or America â and âboring from withinâ â building a rank
and file movement which could take independent action as well as push to
reform the existing bureaucratic unions in a syndicalist direction. In
Britain, probably in large part because trade union membership was so
much higher than elsewhere, the latter tendency won out.[55]
This tendency was exemplified by the prominent organiser Tom Mann, who
had played a leading role in the 1889 London Dock strike. Mann had
emigrated to Australia to pursue electoral projects but became
disillusioned with the Labour Party and what he saw as the corrupting
effects of government, as well as the sectional and divisive nature of
the existing trade unions. He saw industrial unionism as the answer. In
1910 he visited French syndicalists and returned to England a convert.
However, rather than set up new revolutionary unions, Mann proposed to
reform the existing ones from within:
âI was thoroughly convinced that the economic struggle would ultimately
be conducted through the trade unions; (âŠ) that however reactionary the
unions might be at the hour, the only sensible policy would be to
recognise them as the proper channels through which, sooner or later,
the working class would have to function. So we declined to be
identified with any policy that aimed at injuring the unions, but on the
contrary, worked with might and main within their ranks to throw them on
the right lines.â[56]
Consequently, syndicalism in Britain did not take the form of separate
revolutionary unions, but a radical rank and file presence in the
existing trade unions. Numerically, syndicalists were a small minority,
but the great labour unrest of 1910â1914 created an unparalleled
platform for their ideas, and their influence, particularly via the shop
stewardsâ movement, extended far beyond their own ranks. Indeed:
âThe facts that neither syndicalists nor syndicalism caused the labour
unrest, and that in any event there just were not all that many
syndicalists in Britain, (âŠ) have forced historians to make the awkward
but perhaps unavoidable distinction between syndicalism proper, of which
there was little, and a syndicalist mood and atmosphere, for which a
stronger case can be made.â[57]
Consequently, British syndicalism was less a coherent, organised force
than a loose network of different tendencies (anarcho-syndicalists,
militant shop stewards, socialistsâŠ) whose influence extended far beyond
its limited numbers. The only formally organised groups were small
propaganda groups like the Industrial Syndicalist Education League
(ISEL). As a result, British syndicalism operated more as a culture of
direct action amongst the working class than an organised alternative to
the TUC unions. Indeed, as Mannâs quote suggests, there was often a
surprisingly pro-TUC attitude insofar as syndicalists felt they could
fill the unions with militant workers and reform them in a syndicalist,
industrial unionist direction.[58] This proved naĂŻve, and alongside
repression (most famously in the Syndicalist Trials),[59] âas important
as the attack, isolation and defeat of syndicalism, was the fact that it
was also partially co-opted.â[60] As some trade unions merged into
industrial ones, syndicalists became sucked into union reform activities
which took their energies away from the shop floor. In this process,
much of the radical political content was lost in favour of changes to
the organisational structure of the unions.
The syndicalist movement took different forms under different
conditions. Everywhere it was more than just a union but also a wider
culture within the working class; âmany workers regarded themselves as
members without paying dues.â[61] Everywhere it was characterised by an
advocacy of class militancy, unity and direct action. The main strategic
divide was between âdual unionismâ and âboring from withinâ, with the
latter approach being favoured where unionisation levels were already
high through the established trade unions. Interestingly, in light of
the renewed wave of casualisation under neoliberalism:
â[I]n the occupational composition of syndicalist movements two
categories of workers were strongly represented. To the first category
belonged casual, seasonal or project labourers, whose working lives were
characterised by forms of discontinuity: by episodic work periods, by
frequent changes of employer, and often of work site and sometimes of
geographic locale as well.â[62]
The second category is the structurally powerful miners and industrial
workers, who perhaps make up the more enduring stereotype of union
militancy. But it seems important today to note that syndicalism once
thrived amongst casualised workers as well as more stable workforces.
In terms of the political content of syndicalism, Marcel van der Linden
and Wayne Thorpe write:
âThe ultimate ends of the syndicalist agenda were undeniably political:
the abolition of the capitalist economic and political system, the
establishment of a collectivist society structured on labourâs economic
associations, and the transfer of decision making and administration to
the producers.â
While many trade unions pay lip service to these same goals, what
distinguishes syndicalism is its direct action methods, highly
democratic structures and minimal bureaucracy. And yet, these political
goals were to be pursued by purely economic or âapoliticalâ
organisations. In many cases, were they not smashed, this opened the
door to creeping reformism, co-option by political parties or the
existing trade unions, and/or outright class collaboration. The CGTâs
degeneration from a fighting workersâ association to a recruiting
sergeant for imperialist war is the most striking example.[63] This
tendency would seem to confirm Malatestaâs scepticism. But as we will
see, this is only partly the case. Despite its shortcomings, the
syndicalist tradition is a rich and diverse one, to which
anarcho-syndicalism belongs and owes much. We will pick this up in the
following chapter.
Council communism emerged in the early 20^(th) century as a dissident
current within Marxism, particularly in the Netherlands and Germany.
Contrary to what the name might suggest, what distinguishes council
communism from other traditions is not advocacy of workersâ councils.
Anarchists, syndicalists, anarcho-syndicalists and even Leninists favour
a council system in some form. Rather, the âcouncilâ serves to
distinguish the council communists from the party communists on a
question central to Marxist revolutionary theory: who should exercise
the dictatorship of the proletariat, the Communist Party or the workersâ
councils?
âState socialism is not control of the means of production by the
workers, but control by the organs of the state. If it is democratic at
the same time, this means that workers themselves may select their
masters. By contrast direct control of production by workers means that
the employees direct the enterprises and construct the higher and
central organisations from below. This is what is called the system of
workers councils.â[64]
This is not to say the council communists abandoned political parties
altogether. The most important of these was the German Communist
Workersâ Party (KAPD), formed in 1920 when they were expelled from the
Communist Party.[65] The KAPD styled itself as a different kind of
political party, which would not seek power but serve as the bearer of
âcommunist consciousnessâ, in parallel to the factory organisations of
the General Workersâ Union of Germany (AAUD), which had been formed by
workers breaking with the trade unions during unofficial strikes.[66]
The AAUD itself adopted a revolutionary programme, including a hostility
to political parties, with the exception of the KAPD.[67] The KAPD and
the AAUD therefore formed the political and economic wings of the
council communist movement respectively:
âThe idea behind the relationship of the KAPD to the AAUD was that the
factory organisations, operating as workersâ councils for the social
[re]organisation of production following the revolution, were to form
the basis of the dictatorship of the proletariat. However they could
only fulfil this function in so far as those participating in them had a
revolutionary and political conception of their tasks and functions â a
communist consciousness. In so far as this was not the case â the KAPD
was conceived of as the separate organisation of conscious communists,
whose role was to promote communist perspectives and goals, through its
own independent activity and influence within the factory
organisations.â[68]
A co-thinker and sometime member of the KAPD was the Dutch Marxist,
Anton Pannekoek. His book âWorkersâ Councilsâ remains one of the most
widely read council communist texts, and was recently republished by
anarchist publishers AK Press. Pannekoek acknowledges that the
self-organised activity he advocates is indeed direct action. For
Pannekoek, direct action takes place against both capital and the trade
unions. In his view, the bureaucratic and inertial nature of the trade
unions is a function simply of their size:
â[T]he increase in the number of workers, the urgent necessity of
association, make the trade unions giant organisations, needing an
ever-increasing staff of officials and leaders. These develop into a
bureaucracy administering all business, a ruling power over the members,
because all the power factors are in their hands.â[69]
He is explicitly referring to the trade unions rather than syndicalist
or anarcho-syndicalist unions, and his criticisms would not seem to
apply so much to the latter, which typically sought to prevent
bureaucracies emerging by rejecting paid officials, and making all
positions into mandated recallable delegates. In fact Pannekoek praises
the IWW, although hoping it is a âtransitional formâ that will become
unnecessary as workers begin to take direct action spontaneously.[70]
In place of trade union organisation, Pannekoek advocated spontaneous
direct action, with workers forming and disbanding strike committees and
factory councils as the struggle dictated. But in the tradition of
deterministic Marxism, he linked this faith in spontaneity somewhat
mechanically to the predicted ever deepening crises of capitalism:
âThe depressing tendencies grow stronger under big capitalism and so the
resistance of the workers must grow stronger, too. Economic crises grow
more and more destructive and undermine apparently secured progress. The
exploitation is intensified to retard the lowering of the profit rate
for rapidly increasing capital. So again and again the workers are
provoked to resistance.â[71]
Pannekoek does not reject organisation; in fact, he stresses the âfight
of the workers against capital is not possible without organisation.â
However, âorganisation springs up spontaneously, immediatelyâ, not in
the form of a new trade union but through forms such as strike
committees.[72] This reliance on spontaneity and intermittent workplace
organisation is one of the main differences with the anarcho-syndicalist
tradition, which we will explore in detail in the following chapter.
However, Pannekoekâs analysis is problematic. If the strike committee is
formed spontaneously, that implies the strike itself⊠just happened.
There may well be examples of such spontaneous strikes, but recent
history does not support the idea that capitalist attacks make for
spontaneous resistance. Rather, numerous factors come into play, such as
the confidence and morale of the workers involved, their experiences of
past struggles, the level of organisation on the shop floor, and so on.
The workplace organisation of the AAUD was formed not to wage these
everyday struggles, but to push for communism. Everyday struggles were
left as a matter of spontaneity.[73]
Nonetheless, the council communism of the KAPD/AAUD drew strong
criticism from the party communists. Amadeo Bordiga wrote that âThe
declaration of the âLeftâ Communists of Germany (KAPD) at their founding
congress in April, that they were founding a party, but ânot a party in
the traditional sense of the wordâ, is an ideological surrender to these
reactionary views of syndicalism and industrialism.â[74] In a sense,
Bordiga is right. However, from an anarcho-syndicalist perspective, a
rejection of revolution as party dictatorship, and an emphasis on the
revolutionary power of workers organised at the point of production is
not a retreat, but a significant advance on mainstream Marxism. And if
Bordiga thought the KAPD and AAUD were surrendering to syndicalism, the
founding of the AAUD-E soon after went one step further.
Otto RĂŒhle was expelled from the KAPD in October 1920, and took with him
some sections of the party, which merged into the AAUD forming the
AAUD-E (the âEâ standing for âunitaryâ). Its programme espoused
hostility to parliament, political parties and trade unions, banned paid
officials, and advocated the international expropriation of capitalists
to be managed by workersâ councils.[75] Whereas the KAPD/AAUD had split
the councillist movement into political and economic organisations, the
AAUD-E sought to serve as a unitary organisation, one which merged the
party into the factory organisation and organised at the point of
production. RĂŒhle was the leading theoretician of this tendency. His
1920 text âthe revolution is not a party affairâ attracted the ire of
Lenin, and set out an account of the revolutionary union as he saw it:
âThis General Workersâ Union is taking root in the factories, building
itself up in branches of industry from the base up, federally at the
base, and through revolutionary shop stewards at the top. It exerts
pressure from the base up, from the working masses. It is built
according to their needs; it is the flesh and blood of the proletariat;
the force that motivates it is the action of the masses; its soul is the
burning breath of the revolution. It is not the creation of some
leaders; it is not a subtly altered construction. It is neither a
political party with parliamentary chatter and paid hacks, nor a trade
union. It is the revolutionary proletariat.â[76]
While the influence of syndicalism is clear, there are a number of
important differences. Firstly, the councillist unions rejected everyday
struggles, leaving these to either reformist unions or spontaneous
action by workers. This can be seen as a product of the time â
revolution seemed on the horizon, so all their energies were directed at
that goal â but the reliance on spontaneity is distinct from the
syndicalist stress on agitation and organisation. Similarly, workersâ
struggles were only seen as being âpoliticalâ on a mass scale, with
widespread strikes and the possibility of revolution. The meaning of
âpoliticsâ for anarcho-syndicalists will be taken up in the next
chapter. The move away from party politics to the shop floor also
brought with it a very crude workerism, rejecting struggles outside the
factories, with RĂŒhle writing that âwhenever the worker is seen outside
the factory, he is a petty bourgeois.â[77] This contrasts sharply with
the wider cultural, educational and social elements of the syndicalist
tradition.
Second, the council communists saw their revolutionary unions as
transitional organisations to be formed on the eve of revolution to make
the final push for workersâ councils and communism. This was pursued by
either maintaining the dual (political) party/(economic) union
organisation from mainstream Marxism, or in the case of the AAUD-E, by a
merger of party and factory organisation into a âunitaryâ political
economic organisation. It was implicit that when the prospects of
revolution receded, these organisations should disband and revert to
more traditional Marxist forms. Indeed, the membership of the
councillist groups dwindled from hundreds of thousands around 1920 to
just hundreds by 1923.[78] Similarly, the struggle up to that point was
to be pursued by a more traditional reformist union-revolutionary party
pairing, with the party propagandising against the limits of reformist
unionism and for workersâ councils.
In this chapter we have encountered three radical currents in the
workersâ movement: anarchism, the anti-state wing of socialism;
syndicalism, a direct action union movement; and council communism, a
dissident Marxist tradition which arrived at some similar political and
organisational conclusions to anarchism and syndicalism. Broadly
speaking, anarchism constitutes a political current, whereas syndicalism
addresses itself to workersâ shared economic interests. The latter
sometimes left the door open for a creeping representative function and
recuperation by the state. But thatâs not to say syndicalist currents,
such as the IWW direct actionists, have not sought to make the political
content more explicit, particularly in favouring unions as workersâ
associations for direct action as opposed to representation. In a
similar vein, council communism broke with the Marxist orthodoxy
separating economic trade unions from the political party and formed
revolutionary unions. These also refused a representative role,
insisting only workersâ councils could express the interests of the
working class. However, these were seen as a temporary formation on the
eve of revolution, rather than the long term organising force within the
working class favoured by syndicalism.
On anarchism, the Anarchist FAQ is the first port of call. Itâs a huge,
encyclopaedic account of the numerous strands of anarchism and their
relation to other currents, and debunks a lot of common myths. The first
volume is available in print, edited by Iain McKay, and the web version
is regularly updated. âNo Gods No Mastersâ by Daniel Guerin is also a
highly regarded anthology. Units 5â12 of the SelfEd history of
anarcho-syndicalism cover the early history of syndicalism (including
anarcho-syndicalism) around the world. In terms of syndicalism, there
are several recommended books. Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpeâs
edited volume âRevolutionary Syndicalismâ is highly informative, as is
Bob Holtonâs âBritish Syndicalism 1900â1914â. âThe Slow Burning Fuseâ by
John Quail also covers much of early British anarchism and syndicalism.
In terms of council communism, there are several introductions available
online which give an overview. âAn introduction to left communism in
Germany from 1914 to 1923â by Dave Graham is available on libcom.org and
provides a good introduction.[79]âThe communist left in Germany
1918â1921â by Gilles DauvĂ© and Denis Authier is also available in full
online and provides a detailed account.[80] Anton Pannekoekâs âWorkersâ
councilsâ was recently republished by AK Press, with an introduction by
Noam Chomsky, and remains one of the clearest statements of council
communism. Mark Shipwayâs âAnti-parliamentary communism â the movement
for workersâ councils in Britain 1917â1945â covers British councillist
tendencies, with some overlap with syndicalism and the shop stewardsâ
movement.
In this chapter we will introduce anarcho-syndicalism as a synthesis of
the anarchist politics and syndicalist methods we encountered in the
previous chapter. This will be explored through the theory of Ămile
Pouget, the Argentine FORA (Argentine Regional Workersâ Federation), the
German FAUD (Free Workersâ Union of Germany) and the Spanish CNT
(National Confederation of Labour). While the mainstream workersâ
movement is separated into political (party) and economic (trade union)
wings, anarcho-syndicalismâs revolutionary unions are at the same time
political and economic organisations. In countries where reformist trade
unionism was not well established (such as Spain) this revolutionary
current sometimes became the mainstream. Where trade unions were
stronger (such as Germany), anarcho-syndicalism constituted a
revolutionary alternative to the mainstream workersâ movement. This
chapter will also show how this synthesis of anarchism and syndicalism
has taken different forms in response to different conditions, but
always rejected the division of the workersâ movement into economic and
political wings, and rejected representation in favour of associations
for direct action.
Anarcho-syndicalism, as a coherent idea, emerged from the actual
practices of anarchists and syndicalists in the late 19^(th) and early
20^(th) centuries. The ideas of anarcho-syndicalism were first developed
within the French CGT. However, as we have seen, the CGT never itself
embraced anarcho-syndicalism but maintained an attitude of political
neutrality (in principle, if not always in practice, with both
parliamentary and anti-parliamentary tendencies). Thus, in tracing the
evolution of anarcho-syndicalism, Rudolf Rocker writes that within the
CGT, âthe revolutionary wing, which had the most energetic and active
elements in organised labour on its side and had at its command,
moreover, the best intellectual forces in the organisation, gave to the
CGT its characteristic stamp, and it was they, exclusively, who
determined the development of the ideas of anarcho-syndicalism.â[81]
Amongst the leading members of this tendency was Ămile Pouget, the
vice-secretary of the union from 1901 to 1908.
Pouget wrote a number of influential pamphlets including âDirect Actionâ
and âSabotageâ, as well as a fictionalised (to avoid the censors)
manifesto of revolutionary anarchism entitled âHow we shall bring about
the revolutionâ written in 1909 with Ămile Pataud. Pouget never saw his
ideas realised fully within the CGT and left the union movement after it
was captured by reformists. But they were taken up enthusiastically by
others elsewhere. For that reason, they are worth exploring further. In
the opening passage of the pamphlet âDirect Actionâ, Pouget sets out the
definition which all anarcho-syndicalism goes by:
âDirect action is the symbol of revolutionary unionism in action. This
formula is representative of the twofold battle against exploitation and
oppression. It proclaims, with inherent clarity, the direction and
orientation of the working classâs endeavours in its relentless attack
upon capitalism. Direct action is a notion of such clarity, of such
self-evident transparency, that merely to speak the words defines and
explains them. It means that the working class, in constant rebellion
against the existing state of affairs, expects nothing from outside
people, powers or forces, but rather creates its own conditions of
struggle and looks to itself for its means of action. It means that,
against the existing society which recognises only the citizen, rises
the producer. And that that producer, having grasped that any social
grouping models itself upon its system of production, intends to attack
directly the capitalist mode of production in order to transform it, by
eliminating the employer and thereby achieving sovereignty in the
workshop â the essential condition for the enjoyment of real
freedom.â[82]
Considering these words were penned over a century ago, we can make only
minor criticisms. The emphasis on producers rather than the working
class in a more general sense could be seen to treat work as the
exclusive site of struggle and thus exclude the unemployed, housewives
and others (although as we will see, the subsequent anarcho-syndicalist
movement did make attempts, with varying success, to organise these
groups too). The rise of mass media and subsequently of publicity stunts
by various campaigners and activists has mystified the once self-evident
clarity of direct action with images of men dressed as superheroes and
imaginative lobbies of parliament. Pouget would have had no time for
such nonsense, insisting that âdirect action thus implies that the
working class subscribes to notions of freedom and autonomy instead of
genuflecting before the principle of authority.â[83] For Pouget
parliament and democracy were just the latest form of this principle of
authority which must be overthrown, not petitioned or participated in.
In âSabotageâ, he sets out a communist analysis of wage labour which
could have been lifted from Marx (distinguishing between labour and
labour power, for instance[84]), but couples this analysis of
exploitation with that of oppression, insisting on the inseparability of
such economic and political struggles and their unity through working
class direct action. Pouget also deals with the criticism that fighting
for concessions under capitalism is either reformist or utopian, by
arguing that what is revolutionary about working class direct action is
that it links the means and ends of the revolutionary union whilst
waging the everyday struggle:
âThis task of laying the groundwork for the future is, thanks to direct
action, in no way at odds with the day to day struggle. The tactical
superiority of direct action rests precisely in its unparalleled
plasticity: organisations actively engaged in the practice are not
required to confine themselves to beatific waiting for the advent of
social changes. They live in the present with all possible combativity,
sacrificing neither the present to the future, nor the future to the
present. It follows from this, from this capacity for facing up
simultaneously to the demands of the moment and those of the future and
from this compatibility in the two-pronged task to be carried forward,
that the ideal for which they strive, far from being overshadowed or
neglected, is thereby clarified, defined and made more discernible.
âWhich is why it is both inane and false to describe revolutionaries
drawing their inspiration from direct action methods as âadvocates of
all-or-nothingâ. True, they are advocates of wresting EVERYTHING from
the bourgeoisie! But, until such time as they will have amassed
sufficient strength to carry through this task of general expropriation,
they do not rest upon their laurels and miss no chance to win partial
improvements which, being achieved at some cost to capitalist
privileges, represent a sort of partial expropriation and pave the way
to more comprehensive demands. From which it is plain that direct action
is the plain and simple fleshing-out of the spirit of revolt: it fleshes
out the class struggle, shifting it from the realm of theory and
abstraction into the realm of practice and accomplishment. As a result,
direct action is the class struggle lived on a daily basis, an ongoing
attack upon capitalism.â[85]
For Pouget, this was to culminate in the insurrectionary general strike.
He held that the revolution could not be planned, but would develop
organically from the overlapping partial struggles of workers. Thus the
general strike would come about through a generalisation of these
escalating struggles, which the revolutionary union sought to organise:
âThe stoppage of work, which on the previous day had been spontaneous,
and was due to the accident of personal initiative and impulse, now
became regularised and generalised in a methodical way, that showed the
influence of the union decisions.â[86]
But this generalisation of the strike, if successful, would pit the
workersâ hunger against the capitalistsâ deep pockets. So once the
strike was generalised and developed, the revolutionary union would seek
to organise expropriations, where workers take over production of goods
and services and self-manage them on the basis of needs. So, while up to
this point, the revolutionary union had been an organising force made up
of âan active minorityâ, it would now throw its ranks open to all, and
use its federal structure as the basis for administering the newly
expropriated social production. Thus, while it âhad been, in the past,
an organisation for fighting (âŠ) [now] it was to be transformed into a
social organismâ.[87] By throwing open its ranks, the revolutionary
union would transform itself from a revolutionary minority of class
conscious workers fighting against capitalism, into a federal structure
for the self-management of the new society. As to the nature of that
society, Pataud and Pouget did not see a contradiction between
collectivism and communism. Rather, they saw it as inevitable that âpure
communismâ would only emerge in fits and starts, and since people had to
eat in the meantime, something like collectivism could be employed for
âluxury itemsâ wherever scarcity meant that free distribution according
to needs was not possible.[88] But from the start of expropriation,
necessary goods and services â food, water and so on â were to be
provided free on the production of a union card (with the union now
transformed from a fighting organisation to an administrative one open
to all workers). Pougetâs brand of anarcho-syndicalism would prove
influential on the Spanish CNT. But first, letâs look at the lesser
known FORA of Argentina.
The FORA was founded in 1904 out of a merger of existing unions on an
explicitly anarcho-communist basis. However, contrary to Pougetâs
vision, they saw the revolutionary union as a necessary product of
capitalism, and thus did not think it should become the structure of the
new society:
âWe must not forget that a union is merely an economic by-product of the
capitalist system, born from the needs of this epoch. To preserve it
after the revolution would imply preserving the capitalist system that
gave rise to it. We, as anarchists accept the unions as weapons in the
struggle and we try to ensure that they should approximate as closely to
our revolutionary ideals. We recommend the widest possible study of the
economic philosophical principles of anarchist communism. This
education, going on from concentrating on achieving the eight-hour day
will emancipate us from mental slavery and consequently lead to the
hoped-for social revolution.â[89]
The FORA had its roots in the immigrant community, which contained many
European radicals in exile, including veterans of the Paris Commune.
Thus, as resident aliens without the right to vote, party politics was
not an option for many of its founders, even if theyâd been that way
inclined. This may help account for the FORAâs overtly anti-state
communist ideology, as opposed to the âpolitical neutralityâ more common
amongst syndicalist unions at the time. In these two aspects, its
anarchist communist ideology and its insistence the union should not
form the basis of the post-capitalist society, the FORA is often
contrasted with the Spanish CNT (who were closer to Pougetâs approach).
There are certainly differences between the two, stemming from the
differences in context, as well as differing theoretical conceptions of
anarcho-syndicalism and revolutionary social change. For instance, while
the CNT advocated industrial unionism, the âFORA took a stand against
industrial (sectoral) forms of organization, considering that they
imitated capitalism.â[90] In part because the FORA did not aim to form
the structure of the new society, it formed a regional federation
optimised for its agitational and organisational activities, as opposed
to an industrial federation which could form the nucleus of a structure
of social administration during the insurrectionary general strike.
FORAâs theoreticians developed a critique of European revolutionary
syndicalism which they considered overly Marxist, of European
anarcho-syndicalism, which they saw as trying in vain to reconcile
revolutionary syndicalism with anarchism, and also of separate anarchist
political organisations as proposed by Malatesta and the Platform. The
âFORA countered this by advancing a model of an âanarchist organization
of workers,â structured like a syndicate but not limiting itself to
strictly economic problems but also taking up issues of solidarity,
mutual aid, and anarchist communism.â[91] Thus, the FORA developed the
most overtly ideological brand of anarcho-syndicalism, and it proved
highly effective. With a membership of between 40,000 and 100,000
throughout the 1920s, they managed to win six hour work days through a
series of local and regional general strikes.
The FORAâs stance, that imitating capitalismâs structure with an
industrial union would lead to imitating capitalist relations after the
revolution, was related to its conception of libertarian communism. This
is worth examining, because it was partly at the root of an important
split. Industrialisation was in its relatively early stages in Argentina
at the dawn of the 20^(th) century, and people had living memory of
their ties to the land. Whilst these had been semi-feudal and hardly
desirable conditions, they were still considered favourably by many
compared with the horrors of modern industry and its giant sweatshops.
The FORA critiqued the Marxist view that capitalist industrialisation
was progressive as it developed the capacity for material abundance
which made communism possible. They warned that imitating the structures
of capitalism, whether its political state or its economic division of
labour, would lead to just another version of capitalism, as had
happened with the Communist Party in Russia.
Instead, the FORA theoreticians turned to the anarchist communist, Peter
Kropotkin, for inspiration. They argued history was not driven by
inexorable economic laws, but also by ideas and ethical concepts (a
critique later taken up by the German anarcho-syndicalist, Rudolf
Rocker, in the first chapter of his âNationalism and cultureâ).
Consequently, rejecting the progressive nature of industry, they
favoured a more agrarian communism based on the free commune and small
scale production. One of their leading theoreticians, Emilio LĂłpez
Arango, wrote that rather than being the inheritor of the earth
following on from capitalist industrialisation, the working class was
rather:
â[D]estined to become the wall which would stem the tide of industrial
imperialism. Only by creating ethical values which would enable the
proletariat to understand social problems independently from bourgeois
civilization would it be possible to arrive at an indestructible basis
for an anti-capitalist and anti-Marxist revolution â a revolution which
would do away with the regime of large-scale industry and financial,
industrial, and commercial trusts.â[92]
This anti-industrialism led to a split in 1915. At the 9^(th) Congress
of the FORA, its commitment to anarchism was overturned in favour of a
âneutralâ syndicalist stance. The anarchist unions immediately convened
an emergency Congress and reverted to their anarchist communist
position. There were now two FORAs. The anarcho-syndicalist one joined
the IWA at its founding in 1922, while the more moderate split, known as
the âFORA IXâ (which wasnât communist and favoured industrial unionism),
merged into the Union Sindicale Argentina in the same year, and then
later into the Argentinean CGT. The FORA IXâs slide into reformism and
class collaboration can be measured by the fact the FORA continued to
face harsh repression, whilst its more moderate splits were relatively
unimpeded (the CGT ended up as part of the Peronist corporatist
settlement in the 1950s, when the Ministry of Labour made it the
mandatory union for workers).[93]
Before we turn to the most famous anarcho-syndicalist organisation, the
CNT, we will consider one more of the lesser known anarcho-syndicalist
unions of the 20^(th) century, the FAUD of Germany. Germany faced very
different conditions to Argentina. There was already an established
trade union movement several million strong, and outside of this was
only the small Free Association of German Trade Unions (FVdG), a
decentralised federation whose membership typically hovered around 6,000
nationally, and had peaked at 18,000 in 1901. The FVdG was originally
the economic wing of the Social Democratic Party (SDP), but as this
party gained power and revealed its reformist, class collaborationist
nature, the FVdG increasingly adopted an anti-parliamentary stance and
advocated socialism by means of the general strike rather than
parliament led reforms. The years of World War I saw rising discontent
amongst German workers at war discipline in production and austerity in
living standards. This regime was being managed by the mainstream trade
unions (Gewerkschaften), and led to increasing dissent amongst the
workers in their ranks. The Russian Revolution of 1917 was taken by many
as the signal that international revolution was imminent, and this
sparked an upsurge in militancy.
During 1918â19, there was a near revolution in Germany. Workers occupied
factories in some regions, forming factory councils to manage them; âthe
influence of the syndicalists rose quickly after the armed suppression
of a general strike in the Ruhr in April 1919.â[94] Indeed,
âdisappointed with the âold unionâ, the workers withheld membership
dues, symbolically burned union cards, and urged entry into the
FVdG.â[95] In December 1919, the FVdG, together with several breakaways
from the mainstream unions and some anarchists, formed the Free Workersâ
Union of Germany (FAUD). The shift from âgewerkschaftâ (trade union) to
âunionâ (association of workers) signified the shift to
anarcho-syndicalism. In 1920, there were open, civil war type battles in
the industrialised Ruhr region. In the âRed Army of the Ruhrâ, 45% of
the soldiers were FAUD members.[96] The FAUD, numbering some 112,000,
called in vain for a general strike to turn back the tide of counter
revolution, which was seeing revolutionaries extrajudicially murdered by
the social democratic SPD government in league with the Freikorps, right
wing militias of demobilised troops. The counter revolution most
famously claimed the lives of Rosa Luxemburg and Karl Liebknecht of the
Communist Party.
At the FAUDâs founding congress, the organisation had near unanimously
adopted Rudolf Rockerâs âdeclaration of the principles of
syndicalism.â[97] Rocker was a communist anarchist who put an emphasis
on both union action by workers and cultural change. A year later the
FAUD appended âanarcho-syndicalistâ to their name, confirming this
orientation. However, âthe ebb of the revolutionary wave and government
repressions led to a rapid decrease in the membership of the
organizationâ, dwindling from over 100,000 to under 70,000 by 1922.[98]
As part of its cultural activities, the FAUD also formed womenâs leagues
in order to discuss the situation of working class women. These peaked
at around 1,000 members and declined through the 1920s. The FAUDâs
membership as a whole continued to decline through the 1920s as the
Weimar Republic established itself. Membership stabilised around 25,000,
higher than any of its pre-war, pre-revolution predecessors. The FAUDâs
emphasis on political and cultural organising also meant that, despite
its decline, âthe FAUD remained relatively the strongest element within
the anti-authoritarian camp of the Weimar Republic.â[99] Summarising the
FAUDâs brand of anarcho-syndicalism, Vadim Damier writes that:
âAccording to the notion of the German anarcho-syndicalists, in the
course of a victorious general strike it was appropriate to carry out
the expropriation of private property, enterprises, food stores, real
estate, etc. The management of enterprises was to be transferred into
the hands of Councils of workers and employees [office workers]; the
management of dwellings into the hands of Councils of tenants. Delegates
from enterprises and districts would constitute a Commune. Money and the
system of commodity production (for sale) was slated to be
abolished.â[100]
The possibility of implementing this receded as the revolution was
crushed by the combined forces of the Social Democrats and the
Freikorps, who handled their dirty work. The Social Democrats legalised
the factory councils in 1920, causing the FAUD to boycott them, as they
turned from revolutionary organs into organs of class collaboration
(similar institutions â works councils â were adopted across Europe
after World War II). The fact the working class largely remained behind
the Social Democrats in doing both of these things canât be ignored
either, and would seem to reflect the lack of anti-parliamentary
agitation and organisation amongst the class prior to the war and
revolution. The FAUDâs council model of social revolution meant they
often worked alongside the council communist organisations, particularly
in several armed uprisings in 1920 and 1921. But they remained critical
towards the AAUDâs subjugation to the tutelage of the KAPD. When the
AAUD-E rejected political parties, they were invited as observers to
FAUD conferences. But despite some overlap of membership, there remained
important differences over the âdictatorship of the proletariatâ, and
the role of revolutionary unions.
The FORA and the FAUD were not of course the only anarcho-syndicalist
organisations of the 20^(th) century. But these examples help to show
how anarcho-syndicalism has taken different forms in different places in
response to different conditions. Having surveyed the FORA and the FAUD,
we can now turn to look at their more famous sister section in the
International Workers Association, the CNT.
It is ironic that the CNT is the most famous, indeed often taken as the
definitive, anarcho-syndicalist organisation. Yet, when compared to the
FORA, the FAUD and others, it was perhaps the least successful in
synthesising anarchism and syndicalism into a coherent whole. That is
not to say it was not anarcho-syndicalist â what else do you call a
syndicalist union with an anarchist programme that organises for
anarchist revolution? Rather, the two tendencies antagonistically
battled it out within the organisation, and the CNT as a whole was thus
a contradictory amalgamation of syndicalist union and anarchist
organisation. It was simultaneously non-ideological and libertarian
communist, revolutionary and reformist, collectivist and communist, with
different tendencies winning out at different times under different
conditions. Founded in 1910 by a merger of existing unions, roughly on
the model of the French CGT, from the start the CNT was under heavy
anarchist influence and rejected âneutralityâ for a libertarian
communist programme. Two decades of agitation culminated in the
revolutionary events of 1936.
The libertarian Marxist, Guy Debord, no fan of anarchism, writes that
âin 1936, anarchism in fact led a social revolution, the most advanced
model of proletarian power in all timeâ â high praise indeed. However,
he continues to summarise the paradox of the Spanish revolution:
â[T]he organized anarchist movement showed itself unable to extend the
demi-victories of the revolution, or even to defend them. Its known
leaders became ministers and hostages of the bourgeois state which
destroyed the revolution only to lose the civil war.â[101]
Even for disinterested students of history, this would pose a conundrum.
For anarcho-syndicalists even more so: is this where our efforts lead,
to inevitable counter revolution? Clearly, we donât think so, but this
puzzle cannot go unaddressed. The explanations are often unsatisfactory.
On the one hand, sympathisers often dismiss the CNTâs turn to class
collaboration as either a product of extraordinary circumstances, or
mistakes. But the extraordinary circumstances of social revolution were
after all the CNTâs declared goal. And the mere concept of an anarchist
Minister of Justice, never mind its actual existence, requires a more
convincing explanation than the mistakes of individuals.
But on the other hand, critics of anarcho-syndicalism tend to find in
the complex events of Spain the confirmation of their own particular
ideology. So we are told that this is what happens when you lack a
vanguard party, or this is what happens when you make a revolution in
the wrong period of history, or that this confirms that any union is by
its very nature destined to side with the state against the working
class. This last claim is the most common anarchist criticism of
anarcho-syndicalism, so itâs worth looking at why it doesnât hold up.
For one thing, weâve already seen examples of anarcho-syndicalist unions
which didnât do this in the FORA and the FAUD. But also, the claim
doesnât tell us what about the CNTâs very nature supposedly doomed
it.[102] There certainly were tendencies towards class collaboration in
the CNT before 1936, but these were not the sole source of the
collaboration with the Popular Front government. Additionally, when we
look closely, mistakes do appear to play a role, but one which poses as
many questions as answers.
None of this is to say that even if everything had gone perfectly, the
revolution in Spain could have established durable libertarian
communism. Even if Francoâs fascists and the bourgeois republic had been
defeated, there would have likely been a foreign intervention by the
imperialist powers. By this time, fascism had already crushed the IWA in
Italy and Germany, British workers had been pegged back by the
manoeuvrings of the TUC and Labour Party in the 1926 General Strike, and
the CGT in France was by now thoroughly collaborationist and
bureaucratised, and the anarcho-syndicalist movement small. Even if the
Spanish proletariat had defeated imperialist intervention, it would have
stood alone in a world on the brink of total war.[103] Itâs impossible
to see how âlibertarian communism in one countryâ could have triumphed.
However, this recourse to âobjective conditionsâ only explains the
failure of the revolution in a general sense. It doesnât explain why it
ultimately failed the way it did, and why the CNT collaborated with the
bourgeois state.
On the 17^(th) of July 1936, General Franco staged a military coup. The
coup had been long expected, and in fact came largely as a result of the
militancy of the working class and peasantry in general, and of the CNT
in particular. The CNT had been pursuing a strategy of ârevolutionary
gymnasticsâ, launching a wave of militant strikes, occupations and
insurrections which had rendered the state relatively powerless to
enforce the rule of the propertied class. Increasingly, the ruling class
turned away from republican democracy towards monarchy, church and
military, as sources of authority to discipline the labouring classes, a
peculiarly Spanish variant of fascism. So when rumours of the impending
coup spread, the CNT was at the forefront of organising resistance, or
rather social revolution, as they saw the choice as one between fascism
and libertarian communism. On the docks, CNT unions requisitioned arms
shipments, and their militants disarmed police of their firearms in the
weeks leading up to the coup, stockpiling them for arming the workers.
When the coup came, the CNT called a general strike and the fascist
forces were met on the streets by armed workers, with CNT militants on
the front lines.
Years of direct action, coupled with libertarian communist propaganda,
meant when the opportunity arose, workers and peasants didnât hesitate
to take over the factories and fields and start running them on the
basis of needs. In much of the countryside and many of the cities,
production was restarted under workersâ control along libertarian
communist lines, with free access (sometimes on production of a union
card along the lines Pouget had advocated). Other factories and firms
were run on a collectivist basis, or where money and markets still
existed as a sort of âself-management straddling capitalism and
socialism, which we maintain would not have occurred had the revolution
been able to extend itself fullyâ, as participant, Gaston Leval, put
it.[104] Whether this reflected collectivist ideology within the CNT, or
the limits of trying to implement âcommunism in one regionâ, or whether
the former was merely a rationalisation of the latter, are questions to
be taken up another time. But that millions of workers and peasants took
part in the most sweeping social revolution in history is not in doubt.
There is also no doubt that the CNT initially played the revolutionary
role ascribed to it by anarcho-syndicalist theory. Indeed, without the
CNT, there would have been no revolution.
When the dust settled following the street fighting on the 19^(th) July
1936, Francoâs forces controlled about half the country, whereas the
other half was controlled by the insurgent workers and peasants. Indeed:
â[T]he regional government of Catalonia (the Generalitat) headed by Luis
Companys controlled only its own building. Local administrations were
either removed or neutralized. The army and police were either disbanded
or destroyed. Barcelona was controlled by workersâ militias, primarily
anarcho-syndicalist in composition.â[105]
Thus in Barcelona, the CNTâs heartland, events transpired which help us
untangle the perplexing series of events which followed. Catalan
President Luis Companys recognised his position of weakness, having
virtually no forces at his disposal, while workers were in control of
the streets and busy expropriating the fields, factories and workplaces
across Catalonia and beyond. He invited the CNT to a meeting and told
them the following:
âFirst of all, I must acknowledge that the CNT and FAI [anarchists
within the CNT] have never been treated as merited their true
importance. You have always been harshly persecuted. Even I, who had
been your ally, was forced by political realities to oppose and
persecute you, much as it pained me. Today you are masters of the city
and Catalonia. You alone defeated the fascists, although I hope you will
not take offense if I point out that you received some help from Guards,
Mozos [Catalan police] and men loyal to my party. (âŠ) But the truth is
that, harshly oppressed until two days ago, you have defeated the
fascist soldiers. Knowing what and who you are, I can only employ the
most sincere language. Youâve won. Everything is in your power. If you
do not want or need me as President of Catalonia, tell me now, so that I
can become another soldier in the battle against fascism.â[106]
The heavily armed CNT-FAI delegation stood before the President of
Catalonia and heard him effectively beg their mercy. Companys had one
proposal: a collaboration against fascism with the republican political
parties, whose leaders he had gathered in an adjoining room.
âThe anarcho-syndicalists, who now enjoyed a dominant influence among
the workers of Catalonia, were confronted by a decision about what to do
with this power: whether to destroy it, take it into their own hands, or
hand it over to others.â[107]
How did the CNT snatch defeat from the jaws of victory? As they saw it,
they faced a stark choice: either the CNT took power in an oxymoronic
âanarchist dictatorshipâ, or the CNT shared power with the bourgeois
political forces via Companysâ proposal for an anti-fascist popular
front.
âWithin the CNT there had long existed a belief that a genuine social
revolution would be possible only when the CNT represented an
overwhelming majority of the workers in the whole of Spain.â[108]
Even in its Catalonian heartland, the CNT only accounted for less than
half of the working class. Having made access to collectivised services
like transport conditional on a union card, they faced an impasse. As
they saw it, they could either substitute themselves for the working
class as a whole and take power as the CNT, without having gathered all
the workers and peasants in their ranks (they rightly saw this
âanarchist dictatorshipâ as substitutionism, repeating the errors of the
Russian Revolution, where the Communist Party did just that). Or they
could join Companysâ popular front.
While the workers were busy forming neighbourhood and factory
committees, often jointly with workers in the socialist UGT, the third
option of a council system had already been ruled out in the inter-war
years. While the German anarcho-syndicalists, as well as the Russian
syndicalist GP Maximov, had both supported the workersâ councils in
their respective revolutions, and indeed a âsystem of free councilsâ is
enshrined in the statutes of the IWA, the CNT had reflected on the
failings of the Russian and German revolutions. They concluded that, in
part at least, these failings were down to the ability of political
parties to infiltrate and manipulate the councils (as the Communist
Party did in Russia). Their alternative was the kind of model Ămile
Pouget had outlined, where the union would throw open its ranks to the
class during the revolution, but thereby exclude professional
revolutionaries and other non-working class or peasant forces from
influencing the course of the revolution. Therefore, having ruled out
the option of a council system, and fearful of repeating the path of the
Russian Communist Party in taking power on behalf of the working class,
by a process of elimination the CNT was left with class collaboration
through the popular front.
This was probably the worst option. At least taking power would have
meant the possibility of a Pouget type scenario, where any worker or
peasant could just join the union and have control of it through the
rank and file assemblies, as the CNT was far more member controlled than
the centralised, hierarchic Russian Communist Party. No sooner had the
CNT-FAI delegation left Companysâ office than he set about working
towards the popular front. Thus, collaboration fast became a fait
accompli, with the CNTâs lay activists outmanoeuvred by experienced
politicians as the CNT entered the unfamiliar world of representative
politics it had so long opposed. While the CNT unions had the
possibility of recalling their delegates and thus stopping the decision
to collaborate, those who were so inclined were talked out of it by
others in the union.
âThe activists of the CNT did not risk taking the path of independent
revolutionary action, dreading the prospect of war on three fronts:
against the fascists, the government, and possibly foreign
interventionists. In other words, the majority of the activists believed
it was premature to talk about social revolution on a country-wide
scale, while libertarian communism in Catalonia alone was inevitably
doomed.â[109]
This leaves one more dilemma. Fast forward 10 months, and the CNT, as
part of the Catalan government, opposed its own armed rank and file in
the âMay daysâ. How had an anarcho-syndicalist union, where delegates
arenât meant to have any power over the members in assembly, ever
developed to the point where this was possible? The answer to this lies
in the contradictory nature of Spanish anarcho-syndicalism.
âOne must also take note of the fact that the CNT had always harboured
reformist tendencies which from time to time took control of the
organization. Thus, Pestaña and Piero, who headed the CNT at the end of
the 1920âs and the beginning of the 1930âs, supported close contacts
with republican political organizations, and in 1931â1932 became the
leaders of a reformist group, the âTreintistas.â A significant part of
this fraction quit the CNT, but returned to it in 1936. However, besides
the âTreintistasâ there remained a substantial number of âpureâ
syndicalists in the union federation as well as members who were simply
pragmatically inclined. To a certain extent, this was a consequence of
the contradictory organizational vision of Spanish anarcho-syndicalism,
which tried to combine anarchist goals and social ideals with the
revolutionary syndicalist principle of trade unions being open âto all
workers,â independently of their convictions. The membership of the CNT
were far from being made up entirely of conscious anarchists; this was
particularly true of those who had joined during the period of the
Republic (from 1931 on). These partisans of a pragmatic approach could
be relied upon by those activists and members of the executive organs of
the CNT who preferred to avoid risky, âextremistâ decisions.â[110]
Thus, the CNT had never really moved away from the French CGTâs model of
âneutralâ economic unionism, but had nonetheless tried to bolt anarchist
politics on the top. To prevent the tendency of neutral syndicalism
towards reformism which, in crude terms, derives from lots of reformist
members plus internal democracy, the Iberian Anarchist Federation (FAI)
had been formed in 1927. The FAI served as a counter weight to the
reformist political factions within the CNT such as Angel Pestaña and
the other âTrientistasâ (âthe Thirtyâ). But what this meant was
recreating the split between the political and the economic. However,
here the split was not between a union and a party, rather it was a
vertical split between the economically recruited rank and file and the
political factions vying for control at the top. The internal split
between the economic and the political created a space in which a
creeping representative function began to develop, with competing
tendencies elected to run the union on the membersâ behalf (though there
were no paid officials, and they were still subject to mandates and
recall).
The reformists had from time to time taken control of the CNT, so canât
simply be dismissed as an insignificant minority. They clearly had a
base in the unions which they could rely on for support. The CNT was
trying to have its cake and eat it: it wanted a membership recruited on
a non-ideological basis, but it didnât want that to result in the
election of reformists to key positions, or to otherwise compromise the
CNTâs anarchist ideology.[111] The vertical split between the political
and the economic, though well intentioned as an attempt to maintain
revolutionary anarchist politics with a âneutral syndicalistâ
organisational model, carried within it the seeds of bureaucratisation.
It did so because it created a cleavage between an ideological
leadership and the rank and file (of which at least a substantial
minorityâs, and sometimes a majorityâs, views were at variance with that
leadership). The booming membership growth under the Republic
exacerbated this dynamic, though for most of that time the main
reformists were outside the CNT. But the problem didnât go away with the
expulsion of âthe Thirtyâ in 1931. On hearing of a secret meeting
between reformists in the CNT and the Catalan government in 1934, CNT
militant, Buenaventura Durruti, wrote:
âWhy did we fight âthe Thirtyâ if weâre also practicing âthirty-ismâ?
Isnât it a form of âthirty-ismâ to complain to Companys about the fact
that weâre persecuted? Whatâs the difference between Companys, Casares
Quiroga, and Maura? Arenât they all bourgeois? They persecute us. Yes,
of course they do. Weâre a threat to the system they represent. If we
donât want them to harass us, then we should just submit to their laws,
integrate ourselves into their system, and bureaucratise ourselves to
the marrow. Then we can become perfect traitors to the working class,
like the Socialists and everyone else who lives at the workersâ expense.
They wonât bother us if we do that. But do we really want to become
that?â[112]
We can therefore conclude the tendency was a structural one rather than
being attributable to individual reformist leaders. While the FAI and
other revolutionaries succeeded in combating the reformists, the
unintended consequence of this was to create a separation between the
ideological leadership and the rank and file which, with collaboration
with state power, was turned against that rank and file when the
leadership failed them and they were making the revolution. And this
raises one final point. Ultimately, both the FAI and other political
groups, such as the Friends of Durruti, proved impotent, despite their
significant efforts, to prevent the CNTâs slide from revolutionary force
to a counter revolutionary one. This reflects the fact that the tendency
towards bureaucratisation and collaboration was a product of the, albeit
modified, neutral syndicalist model the CNT had adopted. The very
particular conditions of pre-1936 Spain had prevented this tendency
manifesting more strongly earlier, though there had been signs such as
âthe Thirtyâ. For example, it was the state which rebuffed the overtures
of the reformists, who subsequently drew Durrutiâs above quoted ire.
Yet, neither does this make the case for political organisation to
supplement union organisation. On the contrary, the political
organisations within the CNT ultimately failed. And indeed, their number
included more reformist anarchists such as Juan Peiro[113] and,
arguably, Diego Abad de SantilliĂĄn,[114] who had supported the
industrialists in the FORA,[115] advocated collaboration with the
popular front from the start,[116] and advocated collectivist economics
not too dissimilar to self-managed capitalism, with prices, tax reforms
and so on.[117] So the political organisations charged with ensuring the
revolutionary fidelity of the CNT werenât free of reformists themselves.
Indeed, thereâs absolutely no reason why ideological anarchists cannot
be reformists; revolutionary ideology is often a foil for reformist
practice.
But this wasnât a problem inherent to all anarcho-syndicalism, but one
specific to the CNTâs particular contradictory fusion of âneutral
syndicalistâ structures and revolutionary anarchism, a fusion that was
only tentatively possible under particular historical conditions. The
problem does not lie simply in the CNTâs openness to âall workersâ
resulting in a lack of anarchist ideology (the rank and file, after all,
made the revolution), but rather in its contradictory and contested
nature. The problem was not that the leadership were anarchist or
reformist, but that a leadership layer had emerged at all. After all,
there was always a reformist tendency within the CNT leadership, which
could draw support from reformist sections of the rank and file. The CNT
was both a reformist and a revolutionary union at the same time. These
tendencies would not decisively split until after the death of Franco in
the 1970s, when the more reformist CGT split from the
anarcho-syndicalist CNT over the question of participating in works
councils and accepting state funds.
The tragedy lay in the fact that this contradiction was largely masked
by circumstances until it mattered most. Precisely as the rank and file
overtook their ârevolutionary leadersâ who had kept the reformists in
check, those very same revolutionary leaders were co-opted against the
insurgent rank and file. Thus, in a curious way, the failures of Spanish
anarcho-syndicalism were twofold. On the one hand a failure to be
syndicalist enough, tolerating the separation of a leadership layer from
the rank and file to keep the reformists at bay. On the other hand, a
failure to be anarchist enough, failing to smash the state (in Catalonia
at least) when given the chance and thus allowing it to recompose its
forces against the revolution and co-opt the CNTâs leadership to that
end. It is easy, of course, to supersede the failings of the revolution
in theory. But that means little until they are superseded in practice.
We must learn from the failings of the CNT. But that is only half of it.
The task is to do better.
The history of the twentieth century makes clear there are two distinct
currents within syndicalism. On the one hand, âneutralâ or economic
syndicalism, which seeks to unite all workers within its ranks on the
basis of economic interests.[118] Pierre Monatte, in his debate with
Malatesta at the 1907 International Anarchist Congress, was one of the
clearest exponents of this tendency.[119] On the other hand, there is
the tendency which seeks to unite syndicalist methods with anarchist
philosophy and its goal of social transformation â anarcho-syndicalism.
However, history does not follow such neat conceptual distinctions, and
these opposing tendencies often found themselves battling it out inside
the same organisation. In the French CGT, the anarcho-syndicalistsâ
influence waned as the union grew. In the Spanish CNT, the price of
keeping the reformists at bay was a semi-bureaucratisation which, in the
course of the Spanish revolution, proved the CNTâs undoing. In
Argentina, these tendencies spun out into the anarcho-syndicalist FORA
and the âneutralâ FORA IX, on a trajectory of integration into the
state. Such a split did not occur elsewhere in the anarcho-syndicalist
movement until 1956, when the Swedish SAC left the International Workers
Association (IWA) in a row over administering state unemployment
benefits; again in 1979, when the CNT in Spain split, producing the
CGT-E; and 1993, when the French CNT split into the CNT-AIT and
CNT-Vignoles, the latter two over participation in state sponsored works
council elections (state backed bodies in which unions compete for votes
to represent workers, and receive proportional state subsidies in
return). By the end of the 20^(th) century, these tendencies had more or
less all spun out into separate organisations. It is the
anarcho-syndicalist (i.e. IWA) current with which we are concerned
here.[120]
As we have seen, anarcho-syndicalism combines the political philosophy
and goals of anarchism with the economic organisation and methods of
syndicalism. This political economic organisation is a matter of
practical experimentation, taking different forms in different places,
adapted to circumstances. As the then secretary of the IWA, Pierre
Besnard, wrote in 1937,
âlike any truly social doctrine, anarcho-syndicalism is essentially a
matter of trial and error. (âŠ) [T]he idea springs from the act and
returns to it.â[121]
This trial and error approach inevitably includes errors, such as those
in Spain. But if the economic content of anarcho-syndicalism is
self-evident â organising workers as workers to fight for their
interests â then what is the political content? Lenin famously commented
that âpolitics begin where millions of men and women are; where there
are not thousands, but millions.â[122] Anarcho-syndicalists could not
disagree more strongly. This is in fact one of the fundamental
differences with Marxism, even in its more libertarian forms. Pepe
Gomez, a CNT militant active in the Puerto Real shipyard disputes of
1987, shrewdly noted that:
âThere are two points inherited from a Marxist perspective. First of
all, Marxism separates the political and the economic to try and promote
the idea of economic unions, unions that deal purely and simply with
economic issues, whereas the political issues are tackled by the
political party. Secondly, we are left with the need to struggle against
the whole culture that has been built up around delegating activities,
around delegating power to others. Anarcho-syndicalism is trying to
oppose these negative legacies of Marxism, so that people are actually
re-educated in order to destroy this culture of dependency and to build
up a new kind of culture that is based on activity and action for
people, by themselves.â[123]
The contention that politics requires millions is precisely the reason
Marxism separates the political and the economic; the party needs to
develop the ideas with which to lead the millions. For the council
communists of the AAUD-E, this is why their political economic union was
meant to be temporary; for them, political and economic struggles only
combined in the mass struggles of the revolutionary period in Germany.
For anarcho-syndicalists, however, politics begin long, long before
there are blossoming mass movements. Mass movements are only the
culmination of a huge number of smaller, preparatory struggles which are
both economic and political in nature and which shape the character of
mass movements when they occur. Politics is weaved into our everyday
lives and conflicts. To begin to explore this contention, a quote from
the historian of syndicalism, Marcel van der Linden, is instructive:
âIn practice there seem to be at least three analytical levels which
quite often are not, or not sufficiently, distinguished. In the first
place, we could distinguish the ideological level, at which one thinks
about the movement in a general, political-philosophical way. At issue
here are questions such as: what is the world really like? What is
unjust, bad, etc.? Who are our enemies and friends? What social changes
are possible, and how can they be accomplished? Secondly, we could
distinguish the organisational level: how is the trade union structured
(for example subscriptions, strike funds) and how does it behave in
daily practice, when labour conflicts occur, towards employers and the
state? Thirdly, there is the shopfloor level: are the workers who are
members militant and strike prone? What forms of action do they
favour?â[124]
Thus, we can think of the political content of anarcho-syndicalism as
consisting of three interconnected levels. On the shop floor level, it
consists in seeing that even âeconomicâ struggles for wages or rents
are, at the same time, political struggles for power over the workplace
and community. At the organisational level, it consists of the
associational function of a union, stripped of any representative
functions, and with structures, based on mandates and delegates, within
which workers can collectively speak for themselves. At the ideological
level, it consists of an opposition to integration into the state and
the management of capitalism, and the goal of libertarian communism.
These levels are interconnected; for example, integration into the state
funded system of works councils would result in a development of a
representative function at the organisational level and changes to the
functioning of the union at the shop floor level, where managementâs
right to manage would need to be accepted as a condition of
participation in the industrial relations framework. While the emphasis
between the different levels may differ, e.g. the FORAâs âideological
unionismâ compared with the CNTâs ânon-ideological unionismâ, in reality
all three levels are intimately connected to both the form and content
of the unionâs activity. Together, they distinguish revolutionary
unionism from reformist versions, although there is not, and cannot be,
a monolithic anarcho-syndicalism across all times and places.
Another example of the political content of a revolutionary union would
be the commitment to approaches to anti-racism and the emancipation of
women. The old IWW was multiracial at a time of widespread segregation,
and this was certainly a political assertion of class principles, going
against the prevailing grain of the times. The FAUD attempted, albeit
with only modest success, to set up womenâs leagues for self-education
and discussion about the situation of working class women. Perhaps the
most famous case is Spainâs Mujeres Libres (âFree Womenâ). This was a
group formed by anarcho-syndicalist women of the CNT in 1936, largely in
response to the marginalisation of women within the male dominated
union, despite its formal commitment to womenâs emancipation. The very
existence of the Mujeres Libres was an indication of a failing of the
CNT to express the needs of the whole class, i.e. not just the male half
of it. It is a clear example of the way political content does not exist
only on an ideological level, but is an immensely practical thing too.
Indeed, itâs relatively easy to adopt a formal ideological position in
favour of womenâs emancipation, without really integrating that
organisationally or in practical shop floor activity. In this sense the
ideological level is the least important.
Van der Linden argues that confusion arises when some but not all of
these shop floor, organisational and ideological levels are present.
Certainly, this is true in some of the syndicalist unions we considered
in Chapter 2. But in practice, such contradictions will tend to be
resolved one way or another. A union which organisationally excludes
women or minorities is likely to reproduce divides along these lines
rather than traversing them. A militant and strike prone union, without
any revolutionary ideology, will either develop one and refuse to be
integrated into state and management structures, or it wonât and will
likely find its militancy increasingly checked by bureaucratic obstacles
thrown up by developing representative functions. Or, of course, it
could take up the offer of integration into the system, as many a once
militant union has done before. On the other hand, ideological
anarcho-syndicalist groups which lack any organisational or shop floor
capacity for direct action are not unions at all, but propaganda groups
(the Solidarity Federation has only recently begun to develop beyond
this). The question of how to move from such a position towards being a
functioning revolutionary union is one we take up in our final chapter.
Van der Linden is right to stress that ideology is not decisive. Just
because an organisation says it is anarcho-syndicalist (or libertarian
communist, revolutionary, feminist etc) doesnât make it so. But neither
is ideology unimportant, whether it is expressed implicitly through
refusal to be integrated into state and management structures and other
aspects of its practice, or is more overtly stated.
However, for anarcho-syndicalism, fidelity to revolutionary principles
has come at a cost. Since World War II, the capitalist strategy for
dealing with organised labour in the most developed countries switched
definitively from repression to recuperation (this is the subject of the
following chapter). Unions were invited in as partners in social
management. For the IWA, this provoked a series of splits. When the SAC
withdrew from the IWA in 1956, with Francoâs dictatorship still strong
in Spain and the CNT in exile, this left the IWA with no functioning
union sections. Thus, Malatestaâs claim about the impossibility of
synthesising anarchism and syndicalism seemed to be proved correct, as
the only functioning syndicalist unions were of a reformist character.
The aforementioned splits in Spain and France over participation in
worksâ councils were another reflection of this problem. By the end of
the 20^(th) century, anarcho-syndicalism was reduced to a militant,
minority current, even in its strongest sections.
Today, the organised labour movement is plural and reflects the working
class, with a range of unions and initiatives from revolutionary to
reformist, and through to outright fascist and scab unions at the other
extreme. Consequently, if revolutionary unionists are to avoid the
division of the working class via separate unions, we need to find ways
to organise struggles which unite workers beyond our membership and
avoid divisions along union lines. The struggles in Puerto Real were one
clear example; there, the CNT played a pivotal role in organising
workplace and community assemblies which united workers and their
families regardless of union membership. Consequently, the CNT was able
to catalyse self-organised struggle along direct action lines. It
couldnât have done this without a well established, organised basis in
the workplace (i.e. its union section in the shipyards). But equally, it
didnât require the CNT to turn itself into a purely economic union and
recruit a majority of workers regardless of whether they shared its aims
and approach (though it surely grew from its activities).
Such assemblies are far from a panacea and are prone to many of the
weaknesses of soviets, such as co-option by political parties, or larger
reformist unions, or the degeneration into reformism and bureaucracy.
But ultimately this is a âweaknessâ of democracy, i.e. if enough workers
do not want revolutionary change or direct action methods, little can be
done to force them whether they are organised in assemblies, committees,
councils or unions. Rather, the fact the union is made up of those who
do want these things means the struggle can be used as a prove the
necessity for social revolution and direct action methods, and through
the struggle, to win more workers round to revolutionary unionism. For
example, as gains are eroded by inflation or legislation, or as the cops
intervene on the side of the bosses, the anarcho-syndicalist unionâs
anti-capitalist, anti-state perspective can be shown to make sense and
can thereby broaden its appeal as the best way to advance our economic
and wider class interests. The organisational forms taken by
anarcho-syndicalism are intimately related to its practical content, the
twofold task of waging the everyday class struggle in defence of and to
advance our living standards, and doing so in such a way which prepares
the working class for social revolution, building confidence through
collective direct action, engendering a culture of solidarity, and
creating a working class public sphere where revolutionary ideas can be
debated and developed as part of a real, practical movement.
âHere we come to the general cultural significance of the labour
struggle. The economic alliance of the producers not only affords them a
weapon for the enforcement of better living conditions, it becomes for
them a practical school, a university of experience, from which they
draw instruction and enlightenment in richest measure.â[125]
Through the process of struggle, people change. A revolutionary union
presence on the shop floor or in the local area can regroup those who
want to organise along anarcho-syndicalist lines to carry on further
struggles, even when the wider struggles ebb. The CNT continued to
organise when the big Puerto Real struggles and the mass assemblies ran
their course, and indeed was strengthened by this process. Much the same
was in evidence with the FAUD, which declined following the
revolutionary period in Germany, but still remained consistently larger
than their pre-revolution predecessors until fascist repression finished
them off. This exposes a fundamental flaw in Malatestaâs argument for
the separation of economic syndicalism and political anarchism. Itâs not
necessary, after all, for a union to drop its anarchist principles in
order to organise. It just needs a more radical approach which does not
see the union as the container into which to bring the whole working
class, but rather as a catalyst which acts within the working class to
organise direct action along anarcho-syndicalist lines. Even as a
minority, a revolutionary union can organise struggles, and through
these struggles demonstrate its ideas in practice, grow, consolidate,
and organise bigger struggles in turn. Of course this process is not
continuous or without setbacks. The membership and influence of even the
CNT in the 1920s and 1930s fluctuated wildly with wider social
conditions. But whatever the conditions, the revolutionary union seeks
to organise class conflicts using direct action, in such a way as to
prepare workers for revolutionary social change by experiencing
self-organised struggles, practical solidarity and the taste of
victories won by our own efforts.
Furthermore, while trade unions often divide the class, a plural union
movement, which by the end of the 20^(th) century was a point of fact,
does not have to mean divided workers. We absolutely want to win as many
workers as possible to anarcho-syndicalism. But while theyâre not won
over, we still need solidarity on a class basis. A revolutionary union
can commit itself to supporting the struggles of workers in the more
reformist unions on a principled class basis. The recent rapprochement
between the CNT and CGT in Spain, with co-operation in working towards a
general strike against austerity measures, bodes well for such class
based unionism.[126] Of course, there is no guarantee this will be
reciprocated. Anarcho-syndicalists may respect a TUC union picket line,
but we can hardly expect TUC unions to respect ours. We can, however,
appeal directly to the workers in more reformist unions to respect class
solidarity, and will be in a stronger position to do so if weâve already
supported them, and have the organisational capacity to do so. If the
principal form taken by anarcho-syndicalism is the revolutionary union
as a political economic organisation, the principal content of its
activity is the organisation of class conflicts which serve as both the
means to directly meet our immediate demands and as a âpractical
education in social philosophy.â[127]
As we have seen, anarcho-syndicalism found its widest appeal in Spain
and Argentina. Where conditions differed, e.g. in Germany or within the
French CGT, anarcho-syndicalism operated more as a revolutionary
minority. Indeed, as we saw, even Emile Pouget foresaw that, going into
a revolutionary process, the revolutionary union would be âan active
minority.â[128] The million strong CNT of 1936 would surely have amazed
him! The mass appeal of anarcho-syndicalism in certain times and places
seems to stem from three main factors.
aspects. First, the dramatic social turmoil of industrialisation and
urbanisation made capitalism something new, and meant many workers had
either direct experience of this novelty, or it was within living
memory. Capitalism was clearly a historical system and millions of
people had experienced something else (even if that was rural poverty).
The second aspect was that the countries where anarcho-syndicalism
flourished the most, i.e. those that lacked widespread industry, also
lacked developed trade union movements, meaning anarcho-syndicalism was
âthe only game in townâ, or at least lacked the competition of
established reformist unions with a high and stable membership and a
cosy relationship to the state. Contrast this with the more developed
countries like Britain and Germany, where syndicalism and
anarcho-syndicalism operated mainly as militant minority tendencies
inside and outside the established unions.
Argentina and Spain were dictatorships or fragile republics. Suffrage
was rarely universal. In Argentina, many militant workers were migrants
too, and ineligible to vote. Workers had little opportunity to
participate in party politics even if they wanted to. This did not
eliminate party socialism, but did provide a huge boost to direct
actionists, as well as increasing the appeal of anarchist ideology which
preached that the state was a tool of the ruling class and couldnât be
used for liberatory purposes. This is different today, although the
dismantling of the welfare state and the declining appeal of
âpost-politicalâ party politics may be taking things back in the
direction of a more naked âus and themâ (this will be explored in the
following chapter).
opted for repression of working class organisation rather than accepting
and seeking to integrate it (as had happened in Britain for example, or
Germany, with the legalisation of the factory councils). Of course they
used repression because it could be effective; we saw how the IWW was
smashed in the US. However, the flipside of this was that it polarised
society between haves and have nots and legitimised revolutionary ideas.
If you were going to be imprisoned or murdered for being a union
activist, once you made the decision to become a union activist, you did
so as a revolutionary unionist almost automatically. There is another
side to this. As weâve seen, reformists within the CNT argued that they
could reduce repression by playing by the rules and seeking a
rapprochement with the state. However, their overtures were rebuffed
(until after the events of July 1936 at least), which limited the space
for the reformist tendency to grow. Class collaboration takes two, and
with bosses and the state favouring repression over recuperation,
reformists had little gains to show for their efforts and thus had less
appeal than they otherwise might have had. The ruling class preference
for repression made it appear as a choice between revolution or nothing,
which suited the revolutionaries.
None of these conditions from Argentina, Germany or Spain in the early
20^(th) century are likely to be replicated wholesale, certainly in the
most developed countries, or even elsewhere where the ruling classes
have the benefits of learning from their class brethrenâs mistakes. But
we should also not make the mistake of taking the historical high points
of anarcho-syndicalism as defining the whole tradition. Even in Spain
and Argentina, membership and influence fluctuated wildly. And in their
survey of revolutionary syndicalist currents, Marcel van der Linden and
Wayne Thorpe remind us that overall, syndicalism of all stripes
represents âa distinctive minority tradition.â[129] That is not to say
anarcho-syndicalism cannot seek or achieve mass appeal. Obviously, we
work for the widest possible adoption of our ideas and methods. But we
donât rely on such a mass appeal.
Anarcho-syndicalists can get on with the business of organising
collective direct action in our own lives and workplaces perfectly well
as a militant minority if needs be, while hopefully earning the respect
of fellow workers with our principled and consistent solidarity, even if
they, for now, do not share our revolutionary, anti-capitalist,
anti-state perspective. As contemporary conditions are not identical to
those in 1900s France, or 1910s Argentina, or 1920s Germany, or 1930s
Spain, we cannot simply pluck Pouget, or the FORA, or the FAUD, or the
CNT from history as a ready made blueprint. Rather, we must adapt by
trial and error the political economic core of anarcho-syndicalism to
present conditions, just as they did, whilst learning from their
mistakes. We must therefore analyse the changing conditions since World
War II (Chapter 4), before setting out our revolutionary unionist
strategy for the 21^(st) century (Chapter 5).
In this chapter we have encountered four distinctive forms of 20^(th)
century anarcho-syndicalism in the theory of Ămile Pouget, the Argentine
FORA, the German FAUD and the Spanish CNT. We then drew on these
examples to understand anarcho-syndicalism as a practice of trial and
error around a political economic core, combining anarchist principles
and syndicalist methods in ways adapted to the conditions of particular
times and places. We ended by taking stock of the situation at the end
of the 20^(th) century, with anarcho-syndicalism constituting a militant
minority current within the working class, and discussed how this need
not be a barrier to effective agitation and organisation on a class
basis, nor to an effective revolutionary unionism.
Vadim Damierâs âAnarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) centuryâ is the most
comprehensive account in the English language, itself an abridged
translation of a longer Russian text. Rudolf Rockerâs
âAnarcho-syndicalism in theory and practiceâ remains an important read
on the origins of anarcho-syndicalism and the movement up to WWII. Units
13â18 of SelfEd focus on anarcho-syndicalism and Spain in particular,
while unit 9 looks at Argentina. The Direct Action Movement pamphlet
âRevolutionary unionism in Latin America â the FORA in Argentinaâ is
also well worth the read. Hans Manfred Bockâs chapter in Marcel van der
Linden and Wayne Thorpeâs edited volume âRevolutionary Syndicalismâ is a
good account of the FAUD in Germany. Abel Pazâs âDurruti in the Spanish
Revolutionâ is far more than a simple biography (though it excels at
that) and contains important information on the period, as well as the
internal wrangling in the CNT between reformists and revolutionaries.
Jose Peiratsâ three-volume âThe CNT in the Spanish Revolutionâ is
considered the most official and authoritative account. Martha
Acklesbergâs âFree Women of Spainâ is a book length account of the
Mujeres Libres.
In this chapter, we will analyse some of the changes to capitalism and
society since World War II, the point at which anarcho-syndicalism was
all but wiped out by fascism, Stalinism, total war and social
partnership. We will see how the post-World War II social democratic
settlement limited the space for a re-emergence of radical currents in
the workersâ movement by integrating trade unions, as the
representatives of workers, into the capitalist system. We will then
look at the upsurge of class struggles from 1968 which marked the crisis
of the social democratic settlement, and how their eventual defeat paved
the way for the rise of neoliberalism and the âoffshoringâ of the
traditional centres of militancy in the mines and factories. In
analysing neoliberalism, we bring the analysis up to date with the
conditions for organising today, characterised by casualised service
sector employment and a withering of the institutions of political and
economic representation â political parties and trade unions â which
were central to the post-war settlement.
âThe war changed the balance between labour and capital. Most think that
it shifted the balance in labourâs favour. The real lesson of the Second
World War was that it crushed the independent organisations of the
working class.â[130]
World War II all but wiped out the radical currents in the workersâ
movement, with the strongholds of Germany, Spain and Italy crushed by
fascism and total war. But following the war, the ruling class feared a
repeat of the revolutionary wave which spread across Europe and beyond
following World War I. In the first chapter we encountered Tory MP
Quintin Hoggâs 1943 remark that âwe must give them reform or they will
give us revolution.â But this idea had older roots.
âWhen introducing the electoral reform to the British parliament in
1831, the prime minister Earl Grey said âThere is no-one more decided
against annual parliaments, universal suffrage and the ballot, than am I
(âŠ) The Principal of my reform is to prevent the necessity of revolution
(âŠ) I am reforming to preserve, not to overthrowââ[131]
The British ruling class in particular had had the longest experience of
capitalism and had arrived at the idea of âreforming to preserveâ fairly
early on. What changed following World War II, almost universally across
the most industrialised countries, was that this was integrated into the
prevailing management of capitalism. The strategy of repression which
had characterised pre-war industrial relations (tanks on the streets in
1926, gunboats in the Mersey in 1911) was eclipsed by a strategy of
recuperation. This was not entirely new, but was adopted in a far more
systematic way than ever before, particularly in the form of the welfare
state. Class conflict was institutionalised and harnessed as a motor for
capitalist development, with reforms improving living standards
sufficiently to marginalise revolutionary tendencies amongst the working
class.
The post-war settlement was the ruling class being forced to accept the
fact of the working class as a collective social force. This meant the
temporary suspension of the capitalist project to reduce us all to
atomised individuals offering our labour power on the market, in favour
of the institutionalisation of the working class as a collective entity.
This involved taking the reformist tendencies which had emerged within
the workersâ movement and giving them a seat at the table. The working
class threat was accepted as a fact of life, an overhead cost of doing
business. Thus, it had to be given representation within the capitalist
system to prevent it disrupting or rupturing that system. The economic
representation of the working class was to be handled by the trade
unions. The political representation of the working class was to be
handled by the Labour Party. We have already encountered these
institutions in Chapter 1. Here, we are more concerned with how this
model of âreforming to preserveâ stabilised post-war capitalism and
marginalised the revolutionary tendencies within the workersâ movement.
The other side of this institutionalisation of the working class as a
collective was the development of consumerist individuality. Keynesian
economics, which became mainstream after the great depression of the
1930s, stressed the importance of aggregate demand, the economistsâ term
for the total money available for consumption. This was to be stimulated
by two sources: wage rises and state spending. For the wage rises, the
trade unions were brought in as social partners in productivity deals.
The unions would guarantee peace on the shop floor and assist management
in making productivity improvements (such as through new technology or
working practices). In return, management would share some of the
productivity gains with the workers in the form of annual wage rises.
These productivity deals were the backbone of post-war social
partnership in the workplace, and provided the basis for the expansion
of the consumer market outside of it. At the same time, state spending,
particularly via the new welfare state, provided direct employment for
millions and stimulated the economy somewhat independently of the booms
and busts of the business cycle. State deficit spending was used to
smooth out dips in private sector activity and thus soften recessions,
whilst maintaining more or less full employment.
This regime meant building a domestic consumer market to absorb some of
the output of the post-war boom, and created a virtuous circle of
economic growth, consumerism and relative industrial peace. Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) grew continuously until 1974, and days lost to
strikes remained relatively low until the late 1960s. The role of the
state, into which the trade unions were more or less integrated, was to
guarantee order and social peace. We should note that the basis of this
post-war recognition of the working class as a collective force had a
material basis, not just in the balance of class forces, but also in the
organisation of production. The economy was approximately 70% primary
(extractive industries, agriculture) and secondary sectors
(manufacturing). Mining and manufacturing had been the backbones of
industrial militancy before the war, and would be again in the 1970s.
Consequently, large employers often dominated employment in a given
town, which meant there were large collections of workers who could be
represented through institutionalised collective bargaining. This was
fairly successful at keeping workersâ militancy in check, and
channelling it away from open class struggle. The social democratic
logic is captured in a quote from across the Atlantic. A leader of the
Canadian Auto Workersâ Union writes:
âGood unions work to defuse [workersâ] anger â and they do it
effectively. Without unions, there would be anarchy in the workplace.
Strikes would be commonplace, and confrontation and violence would
increase. Poor-quality workmanship, low productivity, increased sick
time, and absenteeism would be the preferred form of worker protest. By
and large, unions deflect those damaging and costly forms of worker
resistance. If our critics understood what really goes on behind the
labour scenes, they would be thankful that union leaders are as
effective as they are in averting strikes.â[132]
This social partnership was fairly successful from capitalâs point of
view for the first two decades following the war. However, in the late
1960s and early 1970s it began to break down. Throughout the post-war
period there had been a slow decline in political party membership, from
peaks of over 2 million for the Conservatives and 1 million for Labour
to around half that by the late 1970s. However, trade union membership
continued to grow, peaking in 1979. The reasons for the breakdown of the
post-war regime were numerous. The post-war boom was coming to an end.
The international financial system was breaking down, with the US
withdrawing from the gold standard in 1971, inaugurating an era of
floating currency rates. The 1973 OPEC oil embargo sent energy prices
soaring. At the same time, labour unrest was on the rise, and social
struggles from anti-racism to feminism, to environmentalism and gay
liberation, were also breaking out. A full account of all the factors
leading to the breakdown of the post-war social contract could take a
pamphlet in its own right. For our purposes, it is enough to note that a
convergence of factors put increasing strain on profits and thus on the
regime of relative social peace based on productivity deals. This set
capital and labour on a collision course once more.
In Britain, the first major salvo in the resurgent class war was the
first national postal strike in 1971, which was kept in check by the
trade union,[133] followed by the successful minersâ strike of 1972. The
latter strike had a strong autonomous streak to it, with action led by
the rank and file and the union playing catch up. Fearing wildcats would
break out, the National Union of Miners (NUM) called an official strike
for January. The employers offered a new productivity deal, but this was
rejected and the strike began. From the first day, all 289 pits were
closed and the strikers at many of them, against the instructions of the
NUM, refused to provide safety cover. Having already warned that
âpressure from belowâ would âlead to anarchyâ, by the third day of the
strike, NUM president Gormley said that âthe men are being a damn sight
more militant than we would want them to be.â The following day he
complained that âsome men have been overambitious in applying the
strike.â[134]
The strike was spread through flying pickets organised mainly by rank
and file NUM members and shop stewards. Strikers organised mass pickets
of power plants and coking plants (most famously at Saltley), leading to
power cuts due to lack of coal. There were solidarity actions by other
groups of workers, including transport drivers, many of whom refused to
cross picket lines, or even tipped off strikers of their destinations so
there could be a flying picket waiting to turn them away. This
culminated in a one off, three day week in February with over 1.5
million workers temporarily sent home due to the effects of the strike.
The result was an emphatic victory for the miners, which helped set the
expectations for workers in other sectors.
âA hastily cobbled together government enquiry recommended wage
increases of between 15% and 31.6%, about 4 times what the NCB had
originally offered, and a bit more than the miners had originally asked
for. Even then, the NUM, under pressure from the miners who had clearly
realised the enormity of their power, even rejected this deal, holding
out for an extra ÂŁ1 a week for the non-faceworkers. After appropriately
romantic candle-lit beer-and-sandwich-type negotiations at 10 Downing
Street, this demand was precisely what the miners got â a pretty good
result which boosted working class confidence everywhere.â[135]
The miners struck again in 1974. Tory Prime Minister Ted Heath called a
general election just two days after a union ballot went in favour of a
strike, asking the question of voters, âWho governs the country?â
Neither Heathâs Tories nor Labour won a clear mandate. The minersâ
strikes thus more or less ensured the downfall of Ted Heathâs
government, which had introduced the 1971 Industrial Relations act
precisely to curb such examples of working class power. And they also
sent shock waves through the ruling class as a whole. One of the first
acts of the 1974 Labour government was to work with the TUC to impose
wage restraint. This was agreed in the region of 5%, at a time when
inflation was running between 15% and 25%. In effect, these were massive
pay cuts. In 1976, Labour called in the International Monetary Fund to
bail out the UK, demanding austerity measures in return. The Labour
government, the TUC, and international capital were on a collision
course with the working class.
What became known as the âwinter of discontentâ began with a strike by
15,000 Ford workers, emphatically rejecting the 5% pay offer and
demanding 25% and a 35 hour working week. They were soon joined by
67,000 more Ford workers, bringing 23 Ford plants to a halt. As the
unofficial strikes spread, the Transport and General Workers Union
(TGWU) sought to regain control and made their demands official.
Strikers returned to work a month later, accepting a 17% pay offer. Next
up were lorry drivers and public sector workers, including refuse
collectors, nurses and ambulance drivers, and famously, the Liverpool
gravediggers. Working days lost to strike action reached 2.9 million in
1979, and trade union membership peaked at 13.2 million. Workers across
many sectors struck for, and won, pay increases far in excess of what
the government was willing to offer. These went some way to clawing back
the income lost to rampant inflation throughout the 1970s. They also
marked the definitive death of the post-war social contract.
This was also the point where the strike movement reached its limits.
Capitalism was being squeezed by numerous factors, not just industrial
unrest, but also international and economic pressures. In many cases
employers genuinely couldnât afford workersâ demands. Now, of course,
employers always claim they canât afford the demands made of them. The
difference was that in the 1970s many of them opened their accounts and
empty order books to the workers, demonstrating they really were up
against it. In other words, working class militancy collided with the
limits of possible gains under capitalism. As sociologist Michael Mann
wrote of this social contract:
âBritain has enshrined the rule of both interest groups and classes,
jointly. The labour movement is part sectional interest group, part
class movement, irredeemably reformist, virtually unsullied by Marxist
or anarchist revolutionary tendencies.â[136]
He was right; the post-war social settlement had marginalised
revolutionary tendencies on the shop floor. This meant when workers ran
up against the limits of capitalism, the movement stalled. Many workers
felt betrayed by the trade unions and the Labour Party, but no
revolutionary movement emerged. There was no serious attempt to push
beyond strike action into more radical action, such as expropriating
workplaces (as happened in France and Italy around the same time).
Having made the country ungovernable, the working class blinked, unsure
what to do with this power. This paved the way for the neoliberal
counter revolution, which sought to systematically break the bastions of
that power in the mines and factories, and impose a new social
settlement based on individualism and debt. But before looking at this,
let us consider the movements in France and Italy during this same
period, which had much in common with the industrial unrest in Britain,
while in many ways coming closer to revolutionary upheaval.
In the late 1960s and early 1970s, struggles erupted around the world in
both the NATO and Warsaw Pact countries, both on the industrial and the
social fronts, with anti-war, womenâs struggles, civil rights, and
studentsâ movements all coming to the fore. We will focus on two
movements, which provide some of the clearest glimpses of what a
revolutionary movement might look like in a developed country: France in
1968 and Italyâs âHot Autumnâ of 1969. Much like in Britain, here we see
workersâ struggles coming up against the trade unions, but also pushing
beyond them, but also falling short of any revolutionary break with
capitalism, and ultimately being recuperated back into capitalism and
the trade unions.
The unrest in France began with a student movement. In May, a wave of
university occupations was violently repressed by the CRS (riot police).
Alleged student leaders were victimised, and mass demonstrations were
held to support them. Many of these demonstrations clashed with the
police, who suppressed them with considerable force. The demonstrations
grew, with many workers joining students in the streets. These climaxed
in the ânight of the barricadesâ (May 10^(th)-11^(th)), which saw
running battles between students and CRS well into the early hours of
the morning. Student and education workersâ unions called for solidarity
strikes against the repression. Initially these were resisted by the
main union confederations, but workers began striking locally
regardless:
âFrom a few hundred strikers on 14^(th) May at the Sud-Aviation air
craft factory in Nantes the strike spread rapidly: 2 million strikers by
18^(th) May, 9 million by 24^(th) May, reaching nearly 10 million two
days later.â[137]
Before going further, a brief note on French industrial relations is in
order, as it is somewhat different to Britain. In France, there is a
system of works councils (âComitĂ©s dâEntrepriseâ). These function like
workplace parliaments, with workers voting for unions to represent them,
and union reps taking up seats on the council proportionate to their
vote. Workers donât have to be members of unions to vote for, or be
represented by, the works councils, and as a result of this union
density is quite low, around 20% in 1968. Consequently, union branches
were not particularly strong, but normal disputes would be run by a
negotiating committee, often cross union, in consultation with mass
meetings/assemblies of the workforce (although usually treating these as
a rubber stamp). In 1968, however, the workers at a rank and file level
met and initiated strike actions without the sanction of any of the
unions, although some retrospectively made the strikes official as the
movement developed.
Consequently the strike wave spread and developed through initiative
from below. Without any official strike call, the largest general strike
in European history blossomed on a wildcat basis.[138] Workers report
listening to the radio as they occupied their factories, hearing the
movement spread and gather momentum:
âSocialism seemed possible. (...) It was a ten year pressure cooker
which finally exploded, and without the control of the Stalinists and
other reformists and other professional organisers.â[139]
Workers set about marching on other factories to bring them out on
strike and, in many places, formed joint action committees with radical
students, which sought to spread the strike, discuss the political
implications and spread propaganda, such as the famous slogans daubed
across the walls of Paris (âall power to the imagination!â, ânever
work!â, âbeneath the pavement, the beach!â). However, strikers found the
gates of factories policed by union men:
âI went to the gates of 5 or 6 factories and each time I arrived full of
enthusiasm. I bumped into the CGT delegates, probably members of the PCF
[French Communist Party]. It was impossible to enter the factories and
discuss with the strikers. I realised that the factories were not
occupied (âŠ) we were not in 1936. I hoped that the demos would arrive
and break through this blockade. (âŠ) At no point did we have sustained
and political contacts with workers in the large workplaces, independent
of the unions.â[140]
Thus the strikers, who had seized the initiative to generalise the
strike, began to lose that initiative. In fact, it would be an
exaggeration to say they ever really controlled the struggle, even when
they were spreading it. Despite the feeling of many participants that
they were making their own destiny, the trade unions remained largely in
control:
âIn every factory, a strike committee (or occupation committee) was set
up to organise and co-ordinate the strike, but its composition and mode
of election or nomination varied. Although the unions had not actually
called for the strike, they successfully controlled it in most cases:
the strike committee was an inter-union committee composed of union
officials and shop floor delegates.â[141]
In other words, while not authorised by the unions, in most places the
struggle stayed within the normal forms of French industrial relations,
with control firmly in the hands of union dominated committees. As
befits the nature of a blossoming movement from below, the demands
raised varied from strike to strike, from occupation to occupation. Some
focussed on solidarity with the students, others on wage rises, others
on shorter hours. This allowed the trade unions to set about
demobilising the strike:
âThe trade-union strategy had a single goal: to defeat the strike. In
order to do this the unions, with a long strike-breaking tradition, set
out to reduce a vast general strike to a series of isolated strikes at
the individual enterprise level. The CGT led the
counter-offensive.â[142]
This was to be achieved by creating separate negotiations for each
strike or occupation in a factory by factory basis, dividing and ruling
the movement. Workers, lacking any pre-existing channels outside the
unions to allow them to co-ordinate activity, were largely unable to
form such direct links within the struggle itself, finding the factory
gates policed by union officials. The trade unions gradually succeeded
in degeneralising the strike. Both the trade unions and the government
united in calls to ban demonstrations and enter negotiations. The CGT,
very much degenerated from the radical roots we encountered in Chapter
2, called for a return to work. The strike wave ebbed, and by June was
over. Order prevailed once more in Paris.
A final point to discuss is what effect the struggles had on the
participants. Indeed, many workers were radicalised by the experience,
demoralising though it was to be demobilised and outmanoeuvred by the
trade union apparatus.
âThe real gain of 1968 for our class was elsewhere. This was the birth,
everywhere, in all the factories, of a minority of workers who had more
or less broken with the union apparatus. There, something changed and in
the ten years which followed, we can talk about the important strikes of
the 1970s which escaped, in whole or in part from the apparatus of the
PCF/CGT, and there were some big strikes in those years.â[143]
There was talk amongst Trotskyists that a âworkersâ vanguardâ had been
born in the factories. However, where did they go? Some became sucked
into the trade unions, aiming to reform them but finding themselves
reformed to the realities of trade unionism. âA good number went to the
LCR or LO [Trotskyist Parties] and the Maoists, and the biggest part
went nowhere.â[144] Consequently, while 1968 created militants who would
shape the disputes over the following decade, many were either absorbed
into the trade unions and political parties or demobilised altogether.
The following year in Italy saw struggles which, although not as large
numerically, in many ways went further beyond the control of the trade
unions. The âHot Autumnâ saw waves of strikes and occupations alongside
a growing student movement and increasing mobilisations outside of the
factory, with mass squatting and womenâs movements prominent. In the
huge car factories of the north, industrial action was rippling beyond
the control of the trade unions. Workers developed autonomous tactics
and forms of shop floor organisation. One of the most effective was the
âcheckerboard strikeâ, where one part of the assembly line would stop
work, and by the time the management and union officials had got them to
start up again, another part of the line would stop. Due to the linear
nature of the production process, these small stoppages would bring
whole factories to a halt. A worker at Fiatâs Mirafiori plant described
the situation:
âThe presses werenât producing a thing, the crane men and the trolley
drivers had nothing to transport, and thus the production lines were
virtually at a standstill. This was dangerous for the unions. They had
lost control (âŠ) The very fact that the line was not running sparked off
meetings and discussions among the men: first of all inside the factory,
next to the stationary assembly lines, and then outside, together with
the groups of students who had gathered at the gates. The strike spread
down the line, and political discussion followed it. Everyone was
arguing and talking, and it was suggested that the demands of the Press
Shop could be taken up by the assembly lines. The strike had begun in
protest against the speed of the line. But work speeds are decided from
above in the factory, and are based on the whole way that capitalism
organizes work, that is, gradings and wages. So our initial limited
protest soon spread to all aspects of the work relationship.â[145]
This captures very well the dynamics of the struggle, where seemingly
everyday demands about the pace of work quickly gave way to an openly
political struggle for power, contesting managementâs right to manage.
In this context:
â[M]any comrades thought that we should begin to push harder. But for
the time being this was difficult, because there was nowhere they could
turn for organizational support. The unions were out of the question,
and the students hadnât yet arrived on the scene.â[146]
The workers organised through impromptu assemblies, using recallable,
mandated delegates outside the trade unions to negotiate with
management. In many places, these delegates came together in factory
councils. The trade unions sought to recapture the initiative and turn
the delegates into representatives. Many militants saw this for what it
was â an attempt to demobilise them and recreate representative
structures. Consequently, they raised the slogan âwe are all delegates!â
and stopped work to negotiate with management en masse. Against this,
âunion officials aimed to discipline the movement so the workers acted
through the organization which represented them, and not outside
it.â[147]
They did this through an âinstitutionalisation from belowâ, dividing the
most active militants from the rest of the workers and sucking them into
union positions. The CGIL union (Italian General Confederation of
Labour), which had originally opposed the delegate system, did a u-turn
and made it the basis of the union structure. As the tide of struggle
ebbed, the most active militants found themselves stranded as union
representatives, mandated by assemblies which were rapidly dwindling.
âMany leading activists became full-time union organizers after 1969,
while in 1970 up to 50 per cent of delegates resigned.â[148] There was
no real organised revolutionary alternative to this, so many of the best
militants became absorbed into the trade union structures for lack of a
better strategy. This is partly reflective of the fact many of the most
organised revolutionary elements in the Hot Autumn were those coming
from Leninism. The âworkeristsâ, organised in groups like Potere Operaio
(Workers Power), Lotta Continua (Continuous Struggle) and Avanguardia
Operaia (Workersâ Vanguard), had nonetheless broken with the mainstream
Marxist conception of the party and support for the trade unions.
Instead, they sought to organise politically in the economic sphere,
with bulletins and anti-union agitation within the factories. The
workerists recognised how the post-war settlement had harnessed class
conflict to drive capitalist development, and discerned a âstrategy of
refusalâ amongst the workers in the vast factories of the Italian north:
â[T]he refusal of even passive collaboration in capitalist development:
in other words, the renunciation of precisely that form of mass struggle
which today unifies the movements led by the workers in the advanced
capitalist countries.â[149]
They made the argument that the assemblies and delegate councils would
inevitably be recuperated. Thus, they did not seek to provide a
revolutionary counter force to the trade unions, but to organise
negatively, against all demands for better wages, conditions and so on
and as a refusal of work, of wage labour â of capitalism. However, this
left the trade unions unopposed in the factories, while the workerists
turned their focus away from the economic sphere towards armed struggle:
ââŠthe majority of workerists chose in effect to abandon to the
confederations those militant workers still unconvinced by the
tendencyâs critique of unionism. In doing so, they would help to make
their fears of union recuperation a self-fulfilling prophecy. As a
consequence, Potere Operaio would encounter great difficulties in
building a factory presence outside established strongholds like
Petrolchimico; there as elsewhere, a number of its activists would
choose to participate in the new councils of delegates. (âŠ) the unions
would soon prove successful in overtaking most of the radical
rank-and-file factory groups of the creeping May. While Lotta Continua
remained influential at FIAT, and the CUBs [workplace committees]
sponsored by Avanguardia Operaia continued to spread through Lombardy,
the unionsâ resurgence was to have direct consequences for workerismâs
political ambitions. In the crucial years of the early 1970s, the
tendencyâs major organisational expression would turn away from the
problem of class composition [workplace organisation], towards the
all-or-nothing gamble of âmilitarisingâ the new revolutionary
movement.â[150]
The armed struggle proved disastrous, and the state unleashed a huge
wave of repression against the social movements, sweeping thousands into
prison. Itâs hard to avoid the conclusion that the workerists cut off
their nose to spite their face. Itâs true that wage demands were
harnessed by the post-war settlement as a motor of capitalist growth.
But this was precisely a period where workersâ demands were exceeding
what capital could profitably concede, opening up a potentially
revolutionary moment. As the previously quoted Fiat worker argued,
âFor us the password is FIGHT INSIDE THE FACTORY, because it is only
through fighting inside the factory that we shall be in a position to
outlast a prolonged clash with the bosses and the State. We must put
them in the weakest position, where they will have to pay the highest
price, and not us.â[151]
But in time the workerists rejected the idea that these struggles could
prefigure a revolutionary break: âthis would not be a pre-figuration of
the future, because the future, from the working class point of view,
does not exist; only a block on the present.â[152] Thus, the only
struggles within the factory they could conceive of were refusals to
make demands, wanting to turn the tables so that management had to make
demands of the workers to return. This was no doubt a radical position.
It affirmed the political (i.e. power struggle) nature of the class
struggle and correctly insisted that revolution is more than the
self-management of wage labour. In this sense âthe refusal of workâ was
not simply an invention of workerist intellectuals, but an attempt to
theorise the rejection of the work ethic and the refusal to let life be
reduced to work that characterised parts of the strike movement.
However, in practice this stance, and the turn away from the economic
sphere to armed struggle, left the field clear for the trade unions to
recuperate the movement. This meant turning militancy away from the
strike movement, where workers were on home turf, towards the armed
struggle, where the state had the advantage.
This is not to say everything would have been fine in the winter of
discontent, France 1968 and the Hot Autumn 1969 if there had been well
established anarcho-syndicalist unions. The point is that there were
not, and there could not have been, since World War II had all but
destroyed the independent organisations of the working class, and the
social democratic settlement had limited the space for their
re-emergence. But in all three cases, a lack of an organised
revolutionary perspective on the shop floor was one of the factors
preventing these struggles pushing beyond the limits of capitalism.
Compare them with Spain, where decades of revolutionary agitation meant
workers and peasants knew what to do immediately when the chance
presented itself for expropriation and a push towards libertarian
communism. Likewise, the lack of organisational links outside the trade
unions limited the horizontal spread of the struggles and allowed the
trade unions to regain the initiative. This was especially the case in
France, where the factory gates were patrolled by Communist Party/trade
union officials. The attractive idea of forming the organisations needed
to struggle in the midst of struggle proved harder than anticipated, in
part because the forces of reaction and leftist recuperation had a huge
head start.
Finally, we can note that the lack of an organised revolutionary union
movement meant those radicalised by the struggle were generally sucked
into the trade union bureaucracy, the Leninist and Maoist parties, or
drifted away altogether. They certainly didnât regroup themselves on the
shop floor to push a revolutionary perspective and oppose the
recuperation of the committee/delegate/council forms developed in the
struggle. Compare this with the German Revolution, where the FAUD was
able to regroup newly radicalised militants and boycott the factory
councils when they were recuperated by the Social Democrat government.
Their numbers declined with the struggle, but they remained much
stronger than they had been before the revolutionary period and were
able to carry on other struggles and agitation. There is no point
lamenting this absence. What we can do is see that autonomous,
democratic forms of workersâ organisation such as councils and
committees are often prone to recuperation if no clear alternative
strategy is in play. As was written of the French wildcat general strike
of 1968:
âThis was the first step towards questioning legalism, the first attempt
to enter a revolutionary insurrectionary phase: but there was no
follow-up in that direction, and the movement was kept well under union
control on the whole.â[153]
Thereâs much to learn from the struggles of this period about how a
revolutionary movement could develop, and also how it can fail. These
discussions could fill a pamphlet in their own right, and we have only
skimmed the surface of them here. The failure of these struggles to
develop into an insurrectionary movement against capitalism and the
state also highlights the necessity to have some organised revolutionary
effort by workers to generalise strike movements, to counter the efforts
of the trade unions and political parties to return to normal, and to
spread militancy between and beyond workplaces into wider society. It
seems highly unlikely such a revolutionary workersâ organisation can be
created on the fly, especially when the trade unions and political
parties have decades of head start. But we also have to acknowledge that
the basis of the militancy of this period, particularly in the mines and
the vast car factories, has since been swept away through âspatial
fixesâ (i.e. relocating industries abroad), and economic and social
restructuring. In other words, the neoliberal counter revolution has
destroyed the bases of these revolts, in the West at least.
Margaret Thatcherâs conservative government came to power in 1979, oft
repeating the infamous mantra âthere is no alternativeâ. In a sense, she
was correct. Workers had pushed more or less up against the limits of
capitalism, and been unable or unwilling to push beyond. Consequently,
capital needed to counter attack, to restore order on the shop floor,
discipline the working class and kick start capital accumulation after a
decade of industrial turmoil. Within the capitalist frame of reference,
there was no alternative; the working class needed to be broken.
There are a couple of common myths about neoliberalism which we should
first put to bed. The first is that it represents a âminimal stateâ and
a âfree marketâ. This is false on both counts. While those directly
employed by the state fell with the privatisation of the old state
monopolies of British Rail, British Steel, British Telecom, British Gas
and so on, general government expenditure has remained relatively
constant since World War II, rising gradually until the late 1960s and
levelling off around 40% of Gross Domestic Product (GDP).[154]
Widespread privatisations have been compensated for by subsidies and
state contracts awarded to private sector firms. We should recall that
Thatcher reportedly carried a copy of the classical liberal economist
Adam Smithâs âWealth of Nationsâ in her handbag, and remind ourselves of
what Adam Smith had to say about the state and free market:
âLaws and government may be considered in this and indeed in every case
as a combination of the rich to oppress the poor, and preserve to
themselves the inequality of the goods which would otherwise be soon
destroyed by the attacks of the poor, who if not hindered by the
government would soon reduce the others to an equality with themselves
by open violence.â[155]
The neoliberal state is thus only âminimalâ in the sense that it is
focussed on its core function of class warfare, outsourcing many of the
welfare functions and representative organs which were supposed to
guarantee social peace under the social democratic regime. It is not the
sidelining of the state, but a redefining of its role. Utilities, health
care, education and so on are all seen as non-core functions and so
there are ongoing attempts to privatise public services across the
board. This âminimalâ state, concerned chiefly with the management of
disorder, has been called a âsecurityâ state. As political philosopher
Michel Foucault wrote:
âThe essential function of security (...) is to respond to a reality in
such a way that this response cancels out the reality to which it
responds â nullifies it, or limits, checks or regulates it.â[156]
The neoliberal state is thus literally laissez faire. Rather than trying
to guarantee order, it âlets things happen.â Periodic disorder in the
markets, especially the deregulated financial markets, or on the streets
is more or less taken for granted, with the state seeking to nullify
undesirable effects (such as eruptions of class struggle). This is the
link between the market liberalisation and the security state that
characterises the neoliberal regime. The dominance of the market over
social life and the increase in repressive state power, ubiquitous
surveillance, militarisation of the police and so on, are by no means
contradictory; they presuppose one another. As the state sheds its
social functions, political representation withers; membership of
political parties and participation in elections falls. As this happens,
the state can rely less and less on presumed âconsentâ to legitimise its
rule, and is likely to rely more and more on brute force. Students
witnessed this in the repression of the movements against the tripling
of tuition fees and the abolition of education maintenance allowance
(EMA). The governmentâs own official report into the August Riots of
2011 cites âcynicism/anger towards politicians, authority, negative
experience of the policeâ as amongst the causes.[157] Such conditions
are endemic to the neoliberal regime, especially for those at the wrong
end of rising inequality.
However, while disorder outside the workplace is taken for granted,
order within the workplace is insisted upon. This brings us to the
second myth, that neoliberalism is anti-union. This is only partly true.
Everyone remembers Thatcherâs battle with the miners in 1984â85. Indeed,
the working class is still feeling the consequences of that defeat
today. But in order to take on the miners, Thatcherâs government did
deals with other unions. The state picked its battles one by one, and
unions which were willing to adapt themselves to the new conditions were
somewhat spared. Essentially, trade unions were no longer to serve
primarily as the mediators of class conflict by negotiating productivity
deals, but rather were to be an outsourced wing of management,
disciplining workers and pushing through âmodernisationâ where bosses
couldnât do so alone. Itâs unsurprising therefore that trade union
membership has fallen steadily since its 1979 peak of 13.2 million, to
around 7.4 million today.
The changing role of the trade unions can be seen in the evolution of
industrial tribunals (now employment tribunals). These were introduced
by the 1964 Industrial Training Act as a low cost alternative to the
civil courts for dealing with labour related matters. The official
presiding over the case was known as a âchairâ, who sat with both a
union official and an employerâs representative. They are now known as
âemployment judgesâ, which gives an indication of the increasingly
legalistic nature of the process. In the early days, to prepare for an
industrial tribunal didnât require any specialist legal knowledge on the
part of the worker. Although a knowledge of the case law always helped,
it was by no means essential. Nowadays, your prospects are pretty slim
without an employment lawyer; something which trade unions often provide
to their members as part of their service model. While in the past there
were many workplaces which would take wildcat action if a worker was
unfairly disciplined or sacked (and there still are a few, some post
office branches and the London Underground being the most frequent),
âwait for the tribunalâ is among the most effective ways of making sure
this doesnât happen, diffusing anger into an individual, legalistic
process.
Thatcherâs government wasnât stupid, and was not prepared to leave the
centres of working class power untouched, trade union mediation or not.
While the trade unions had long served to police militancy on the shop
floor, theyâd proved unable to discipline the working class during the
winter of discontent. And there was a strong correlation between those
industries with strong rank and file union organisation and wildcat
militancy. When the union hierarchy tried to call off strikes, often the
branches and shop stewards ignored them to take unofficial wildcat
action. Up until 1968, 95% of strikes had been unofficial, and the same
was true of many of the conflicts of the 1970s.[158] Consequently, the
strongholds of the organised working class, particularly mining and
manufacturing, were to be dismantled. So-called âanti-unionâ laws were
introduced to clamp down on unofficial action and secondary picketing.
But in practice these laws were not so much anti-union as anti-strike,
imposing financial ruin (asset sequestration) on unions which didnât
clamp down on their members taking unofficial action.
The National Union of Miners couldnât be trusted to discipline the
miners, who had brought the country to a standstill in 1972 and brought
down the government in 1974. The miners had shown a strong capacity for
autonomous action at a rank and file level, particularly in 1972. A
secondary stronghold was in manufacturing, particularly the car
industry. These centres of working class power had to be destroyed lest
they rise up again. The defeat of the miners was well planned, dating at
least to the 1978 âRidley Planâ which had been leaked to the Economist.
Coal was stockpiled well in advance, some power plants were converted to
run on petroleum, a fleet of scab hauliers was recruited in case rail
workers refused to move coal, and riot squads were deployed to smash
picket lines. Deals were done with other unions to pre-empt sympathetic
action. In 1984 the government, via the National Coal Board (NCB), tore
up the 1974 agreement and announced a programme of pit closures, costing
20,000 jobs. Without waiting to ballot, miners in the affected pits
walked out. They soon spread the strike to other pits via flying
pickets. But the story is a familiar one etched into the collective
memory of todayâs militants, even those who werenât born at the time.
Despite a long and bitter struggle, the miners were successfully
isolated. They fought and lost almost alone.
For the manufacturing sector, the process was less sudden. Instead,
firms increasingly employed a âspatial fixâ, relocating to countries
with lower wages and laxer conditions. Often, these were military
dictatorships like Brazil and South Korea. Here too, they often found
that the workers they brought together on the production lines got
organised, fought and won better conditions. But in terms of Britain,
the militancy was successfully exported.[159] Whereas in the 1970s the
British economy had been 70% extractive industries and manufacturing,
today it is more than 70% services. The economic restructuring has
imposed a generational break in militancy across almost all sectors.
Most workers born in the 1980s or since have never been on strike, and
for those who have it has been mostly in one day, largely symbolic
actions. Certainly, memories of effective industrial action are few and
far between, and the sectors where this was commonplace are long gone.
We have yet to see much in the way of effective service sector
organising, something any contemporary anarcho-syndicalist strategy
needs to address.
The advent of neoliberalism thus represented a shift in the balance of
class forces, with capital once more on the offensive. Consequently, the
meaning of âreformâ was redefined, not as concessions to placate the
threat of revolution, but as an ongoing process of restructuring society
in capitalâs interests. âLabour market reformâ means casualisation,
âflexibilityâ (for employers), an increasing role for employment
agencies, and rising job insecurity. Pension reform means cutting
pension pay outs and increasing employee contributions. Financial market
reform means deregulation of the sector, leading to greater financial
instability, growing inequality and the massive expansion of personal
credit (all factors in the current crisis). Public sector reform means
privatisation and outsourcing, tearing up terms and conditions and the
introduction of private sector management norms. Industrial relations
reform means transforming the notion of relations into âhuman
resourcesâ, representing the relegation of the working class from
collective subject to disciplined, individualised, managed object.
Welfare reform means cuts and workfare, i.e. forced labour. Housing
reform means the widespread privatisation of the housing stock, and the
decline of social housing. In the absence of a strong working class
movement âreforming to preserveâ was superseded with âreforming to
developâ.
In short, reform has become a euphemism for attacking our living
standards. Unions have been allowed to remain social partners so long as
they accepted their role was no longer to police the shop floor in
return for annual improvements in pay and conditions, but simply to
manage their stagnation and decline with minimal disruption. This is
normally called âconsultationâ, a managerial euphemism if ever there was
one, since the outcome is rarely in doubt. During the âboomâ before the
great financial crisis of 2007, pay was cut year on year in the form of
sub-inflation pay offers. During the following austerity, this process
accelerated. Neoliberalism has thus all but eliminated the space for
reformism in the old sense of working through the representative
institutions of unions and parliament to achieve gradual improvements in
working class living standards. This is the paradox of reformism:
without the revolutionary or at least, militant and uncontrollable
threat, the reformists lose their seat at the table and capital and the
state lose any incentive to concede reforms. Whether they could do so
once more if faced with a renewed working class threat, or whether that
ship has sailed, is an open question. We would err on the side of
caution and say that it may indeed be possible, and as much as possible,
we should organise in such a way that is wise to attempts at
recuperation or buy offs.
With all this in mind, we can arrive at the counterintuitive formulation
that neoliberalism constitutes class collaboration on an individual
basis. No longer is social partnership institutionalised via collective
bargaining and productivity deals. Rather, productivity and incentives
are increasingly individualised. Home ownership and the corresponding
mortgages were vastly expanded under Thatcher (and since with the âright
to buyâ council housing). This formed a class basis for this
âindividualised class collaborationâ, a burgeoning middle class identity
to replace the âold fashionedâ working class identity associated with
pit villages and manufacturing towns, which were in inexorable decline.
The expansion of personal debt served to discipline the working class,
first through mortgages (which mitigate against strike action which
could cost your home) and later through the expansion of credit card
lending which, together with rising house prices, plugged much of the
gap in aggregate demand which, under the social democratic regime, had
been served by productivity deals. Workplaces have seen a proliferation
of minor hierarchies â team leaders and so on â to provide a semblance
of truth to the ruling ideology of meritocracy that, if you keep your
head down and crack on, you can progress your career. With the working
class ever more atomised, inequality has risen dramatically. Britainâs
Gini coefficient (0 = perfect equality, 100 = perfect inequality) rose
from the mid 20s in the post-war period to 40 and above today, a figure
which continues creeping upwards.
The atomisation of the working class has gone hand in hand with a mental
health epidemic. Depression is rife as stresses, which were once seen as
a collective battle between workers and bosses, are turned inwards as
personal failings. After all, since our society is now a meritocracy, if
youâre stuck in a dead end job, perma-temping or on the dole, youâve
only yourself to blame. Or so the story goes. One in four people suffers
a mental health problem in any given year, most commonly anxiety and
depression.[160] Studies suggest that unemployment and rising income
inequality are implicated in rising suicide rates.[161] When the Greek
economy went into crisis following the global recession, its suicide
rate shot up from the lowest to the highest in Europe.[162] The
depression epidemic is not solely caused by neoliberal capitalism, of
course; mental health is far more complicated than that. But itâs
certainly an important factor. Writer Mark Fisher notes:
âIn Britain, depression is now the condition that is most treated by the
NHS. (âŠ) it is necessary to reframe the growing problem of stress (and
distress) in capitalist societies. Instead of treating it as incumbent
on individuals to resolve their own psychological distress, instead,
that is, of accepting the vast privatization of stress that has taken
place over the last thirty years, we need to ask: how has it become
acceptable that so many people, and especially so many young people, are
ill? The âmental health plagueâ in capitalist societies would suggest
that, instead of being the only social system that works, capitalism is
inherently dysfunctional, and that the cost of it appearing to work is
very high.â[163]
With the fragmenting of working class identity, the Labour Party, whose
membership collapsed from 666,000 in 1979 to 348,000 the following year,
became âunelectableâ. That is, until they reinvented themselves as New
Labour, declaring âweâre all middle class nowâ (Labour membership was
down to 194,000 at the latest count in 2010). Party politics has thus
been transformed from a spectacular image of class conflict, where the
party of the bosses and the party of the workers would do battle (the
social democratic tragedy), into a contest between interchangeable
administrators of the capitalist economy (the neoliberal farce).
Neoliberal politics consists of a bland managerial face off, where
increasingly indistinguishable candidates compete for a handful of
decisive votes in marginal constituencies. Personality becomes decisive,
but in truth mediocrity reigns. Real power lies elsewhere, and the
sharpest of the ruling class no longer aim at a career in politics,
leaving social administration to a succession of identikit clones.
Miliband imitates Cameron who imitates Blair; a copy of a copy of a
copy, becoming more dull and unappealing each iteration. No wonder
interest in party politics is waning! And good riddance. But itâs
testament to the weakness of the working class that these mediocrities
are able to rule us. With barely a semblance of anything at stake,
membership of political parties is in steady decline, and electoral
turnout too. Only the occasional short lived spectacle like the hype
around New Labour or Obamamania can buck this trend. The incumbents
promise a steady hand. The opposition promise change. They change places
and change promises. In the 2010 general election, every major party ran
on a slogan of âfairnessâ,[164] no doubt after some pollster discovered
it was the value that really spoke to the fabled âmiddle Englandâ. In
the past, revolutionaries had to make the case against parliament as the
avenue for social change. Increasingly, parliament makes the case for us
all by itself. As a BBC journalist writes:
ââŠthe big parties have effectively given up on becoming mass membership
organisations. There will be no return to the 1950s. What we might be
witnessing instead is the birth of a new kind of political party. Not so
much a religion to be followed by faithful, as a pastime to be pursued
once or twice a year, when other commitments allow.â[165]
This more or less brings us to the present crisis. As of 2012, much
remains to be seen. But the Keynesian solution is no longer on the
table. Even if thereâs the profitability to sustain new productivity
deals (doubtful), or the wealth available for redistribution
(doubtless), the ruling class arenât going to give it up, save in the
face of a renewed class offensive. This has been contemplated in the
pages of the Economist:
ââŠrelatively undemocratic governments have historically extended voting
rights in order to convince a restive public of the promise of future
redistribution. In the West, that is not an option. A bit more growth
and a bit less austerity might take the edge off public anger. But if
social unrest has its roots in the effects of structural economic
changes, a more fundamental societal reckoning may be needed. A study
(âŠ) examined inequality and unrest in India and found that
redistribution can quell an outcry. That may well be the outcome of the
current turmoil, too.â[166]
But while one off redistributions might placate social movements, they
cannot fix the economic crisis. There is plenty of existing wealth in
the world which can in principle be redistributed, but as Karl Marx
pointed out, capitalism is a system of producing new, surplus value.
Moving existing wealth around wonât in itself kick start that
accumulation process. A more fundamental societal reckoning may be
needed. The Keynesian/social democratic regime failed due to its own
internal contradictions. It couldnât be sustained for more than 25 years
or so in only a small part of the world (i.e. the most developed
countries). There can be no return to the post-war settlement, whatever
the nostalgic wishes of the left, for the conditions which made it
possible no longer exist. But the original neoliberal solutions are now
off the table too. The basis of neoliberal individualised class
collaboration was the expansion of home ownership and the extension of
easy credit to compensate for stagnating real wages. But with the
bursting of the credit bubble and the fact much of the housing stock has
already been sold off, that option is no longer viable.
What comes next remains to be seen. Neoliberalism may stagger on with
further privatisations, casualisation and reliance on repression to
compensate for falling political legitimacy. This seems to be the
favoured course of the British ruling class. But this can be contested,
resulting in either an alternative model of capitalist accumulation, or
the re-emergence of a working class movement aiming beyond capitalism
and the state, and towards a free society based on human needs. The
latter, in fact, is likely to guarantee the former, to the extent it
falls short. That is to say, it may take a push from the class struggle
to put the final nails in neoliberalismâs coffin, but there may be some
other form of capitalism that follows, if we donât push all the way
through to libertarian communism. Certainly, the best capitalism can
offer us is alienated boredom and insecure employment; the worst,
medicated misery and unemployment. Wherever the present crisis leads, we
can be sure that the better organised we are, the stronger our
solidarity, then the better prepared we are to influence things
favourably in our direction. At the minute we are far from strong enough
to do so. But a revolutionary unionist practice seems to us more
relevant than ever, especially now the possibility for even modest gains
through the reformist unions has been so much eroded.
In this chapter we looked first at the social democratic compromise.
This marginalised revolutionary tendencies in the workersâ movement by
integrating the political and economic representatives of the working
class into the stateâs management of capitalism. When this compromise
broke down in the 1960s and 1970s, the working class took the offensive
with waves of strikes and militancy. However, these struggles did not
reach the intensity of revolutionary working class insurrection,
although at times in France and Italy it came close. With the stalling
of these struggles, capitalism and the state counter attacked with
neoliberal reforms. These destroyed the old bases of militancy, put
limited individual advancement in the place of collective struggles, and
created a paradoxical âindividualised class collaborationâ. These
neoliberal conditions by no means mean a minimal or weak state, but a
security state which creates the conditions for disorder whilst seeking
to neutralise any outbreaks. This shapes the conditions for organising
collective working class struggles today.
Units 19 and 20 of the SelfEd history of anarcho-syndiclaism cover the
rise and decline of social democracy. Aufheben #13 contains a good
article on housing and how it was used to decompose the working
class.[167] Aufhebenâs two part series on the financial crisis is also
worth reading.[168] Salt by Escalate is an interesting take on the
current crisis of capitalism and neoliberalism.[169] Libcom.org has a
good brief introduction to the winter of discontent,[170] as well as
several good pieces on France 1968. These include âEnragĂ©s and
Situationists in the Occupations Movementâ by the Situationist
International, âGeneral Strike: France 1968 â A factory by factory
accountâ by Andre Hoyles and âMay-June 1968 â A Situation Lacking in
Workersâ Autonomyâ by Mouvement Communiste. Daniel Cohn-Benditâs
âObsolete Communism â the left wing alternativeâ provides a book length
account of the general strike in France. On Italy, the complete text of
Robert Lumleyâs âStates of emergency: Cultures of revolt in Italy from
1968 to 1978â is available on libcom and covers the period of unrest
well. Steve Wrightâs âStorming Heavenâ covers the same period, with
particular focus on the âworkeristâ Marxist political currents. Mario
Trontiâs âStrategy of Refusalâ remains a key workerist text from the
time, outlining their unorthodox Marxist perspective. These can also be
found on libcom.
In this final chapter, we set out our vision of anarcho-syndicalism
today. We discuss how to move from being a simple political propaganda
organisation to a revolutionary union capable of taking the initiative
in organising and catalysing class struggles in the economic and social
spheres. Central to this strategy is the potential for direct action to
build confidence, capacity and self-organisation amongst the working
class, and thus for struggle to serve as âthe school of socialismâ. We
argue that a revolutionary union is an essential component of a
revolutionary workersâ movement. Not only for organising and catalysing
struggles, but providing both a physical and organisational
infrastructure for the working class, and a point of departure for
numerous anti-oppression, self-education and cultural initiatives, both
inside and beyond its ranks. We set out how this kind of political
economic organisation can help the re-emergence of a militant and
revolutionary workersâ movement, and the necessity for this to seek to
unite all the revolutionary workers of the world. Finally, we will
sketch what a social revolution might look like on a world scale, and
the role that revolutionary unions should play in this process.
In many ways it is easiest to start from what not to do. History
furnishes us with ample cautionary examples. Certainly,
anarcho-syndicalists do not want to function as a political organisation
of anarchists. Political organisation leaves the organising of struggles
either to reformist organisations (such as the trade unions), or to
spontaneous action by workers. If we leave it to reformist unions or
other organisations, the methods they will use will be representative,
disempowering ones. This short circuits the power of direct action to
serve not just as a means to achieve results but a school of social
change. The main thing we learn from struggles organised along reformist
lines is how to be marched out on strike and back in again, feeling
thoroughly demoralised when union leaders snatch defeat from the jaws of
victory. We certainly donât experience self-organisation, control of our
own struggles and the confidence and exhilaration of forcing concessions
directly through collective action.
On the other hand, we reject the idea that the conditions created by
capitalism will spontaneously lead to workersâ resistance. Conditions
may shape struggle; they do not guarantee it. For us the key determinant
in workersâ resistance is organisation; the greater the organisation,
the more resistance, the greater the chance of success. It is notable
that when council communists like Pannekoek (for whom âorganisation
springs up spontaneously, immediatelyâ[171]) championed workers
âspontaneouslyâ organising strike committees in Germany and elsewhere,
they did so from the base of highly organised union shops. So when the
union bureaucracy didnât back their actions they were in a position to
launch wildcat strikes, form strike committees and so on. A similar
pattern has been seen in the UK in recent years, with unofficial action
concentrated amongst highly organised workers such as in the postal
service, refuse collection, and rank and file electricians. In the
absence of such organisation (and even many unionised workplaces are not
organised, as we set out in Chapter 1) capitalist offensives far more
often result in resignation, demoralisation and defeat, as has
overwhelmingly been the case in Britain since the neoliberal counter
offensive from the 1980s. As this culture of defeat sets in, it becomes
ever more entrenched, until it becomes impossible to imagine doing
things differently as the neoliberal mantra of âthere is no alternativeâ
takes root.
So we can neither leave the organisation of class conflicts in the hands
of reformists, nor wait for struggles to emerge spontaneously. We need
to organise struggles ourselves along direct action lines. And if weâre
not capable of doing so at present, we need to aspire to that
capability; we need to move from being a political propaganda group to
being a revolutionary union. The Solidarity Federation describes itself
as a revolutionary union initiative to signify this intent. So far, the
struggles we have initiated have been small scale and often focussed on
individual grievances. But that merely reflects the limits of our
present capacities, capacities we are always seeking to expand. Specific
political organisation is not sufficient to this task. We seek to become
an organisation which is at once political and economic.
We can also reject the fanciful notion of reforming the bureaucratic
unions, commonplace amongst socialists and not unheard of amongst
anarchists either. Bureaucratisation is a one way process. Or rather,
while it could theoretically be reversed by a strong enough rank and
file movement, it would be a misdirection of energy to pursue union
reform at the expense of direct action (a mistake that helped co-opt
British syndicalism, as we saw in Chapter 2). Whatever energy and
self-organisation it would take to dislodge entrenched bureaucracies,
backed by the state, would be far better spent organising struggles
directly, and regrouping workers into organisations based on the
principles we espouse â revolutionary unions. This does not mean we
should tear up our trade union cards, but rather abandon any pretensions
to reforming the existing union structures, and regardless of trade
union membership seek to pursue an anarcho-syndicalist strategy.
An argument commonly raised against revolutionary unionism is the
numbers game. Unions, it is said, are âmass organisationsâ, which far
exceed the scale of what itâs possible to organise along revolutionary
lines. Thus, we are told, you can be revolutionary, or you can be a
union, but never the twain shall meet. This gives rise to a reformist
argument masquerading as âpragmatismâ, that we must drop our
âideologicalâ opposition to reformist methods â works councils, full
time officials, representative functions, state funds, compliance with
the law and so on â in order to grow into such a âmass organisationâ.
This may be the way to âbuildâ, but build what? We have no interest in
building new bureaucracies, which is the sure fire result of building a
union on anything other than clear anti-capitalist and anti-state
principles. In the âpost-politicalâ neoliberal world, we should be wary
of anyone denying ideological motivations. The denial itself is the
surest sign of ideology! Reformist ideology always presents itself as
post-ideological âpragmatismâ, as if this somehow makes its embrace of
class collaboration any less ideological. Sure, revolutionary unionists
are starting out as a tiny minority of the working class. That doesnât
mean we canât organise class conflicts beyond our limited numbers, and
win workers over to revolutionary unionism through the victories we win
in the school of struggle.
In any event, a closer look at the trade unions should dispel the
simplistic notion that they are âmass organisationsâ in any meaningful
way. It is true that in this country, the trade unions together maintain
a membership numbering millions, with several of the largest topping a
million members each. But what does this mean in practice? On a day to
day basis, the union is run by a bureaucracy of paid officials and a
minority of lay reps. These reps â shop stewards, health and safety reps
and so on â are often the most militant workers in their workplaces.
Itâs not at all uncommon that less militant workplaces donât even have a
rep, or regular membersâ meetings. When membersâ meetings are held, and
we sometimes encounter opposition from the bureaucracy to doing even
this, typically only a tiny minority of the paper membership attends.
This only changes in the course of a big dispute, when meetings may
swell to most or all of the membership, and new members may even sign up
to participate. So in practice, in the workplace the trade unions are
organisations of worker activists which, in the course of disputes,
organise mass meetings of the workforce. The strategy we are setting out
merely recognises this reality of what a union is.
The trade unions are centralised, bureaucratic and hierarchical
organisations, and so they donât link worker activists horizontally with
one another. Rather, workplaces are only linked to one another via the
branch or the region, often staffed by full time officials or lay reps
with an eye to becoming full time officials, and not infrequently by
ârevolutionary socialistsâ with their eye on a trade union career path.
Consequently, they work against the circulation and co-ordination of
self-organised struggles. Worker activists such as shop stewards in
different areas or departments are limited to communicating with one
another through âthe proper channelsâ. This gives the union apparatus
the chance to mediate, diffuse and control the rank and file should they
get any ideas above their station (such as carrying on a strike which
has been called off by head office despite strong rank and file support,
a fairly frequent occurrence in recent British industrial relations).
This leads many on the left to advocate some form of rank and filism,
i.e. a networking of rank and file activists independently of the union
structure.
Our predecessor, the Direct Action Movement, was involved in such rank
and file networks, but came to the conclusion that the very nature of
these groups, and of the politics of those who have tried to organise
them, has meant that they were doomed to failure. Since World War II we
have seen various political groups try to set up rank and file networks,
from those set up by the Communist Party (CP) in the 1950s and 1960s,
such as Flashlight and the Building Workersâ Charter, through to the SWP
dominated rank and files of the 1970s and, of course, the Militant
Tendency (now Socialist Party) dominated Broad Lefts. Needless to say,
such Marxist groups were not slow to manipulate rank and files for their
own ends, even if this was to the detriment of those rank and files and
the workers involved. For instance, Building Workersâ Charter, which had
widespread support in the building industry, failed to appear in the
massive and bitter building workersâ strike in the early 1970s due to
the manoeuvring of the CP. Thus, they not only failed to provide an
alternative lead to the reformist unions in a crucial strike, but so
demoralised supporters of Building Workersâ Charter that it led to its
eventual collapse. Again in 1973, when the International Socialists (IS;
now the SWP), tried to set up a national rank and file movement, the CP
dominated rank and files boycotted the conference organised to launch
the movement, with the Morning Star newspaper denouncing the whole event
as an IS plot. We saw it once again with the 2011 implosion of the
National Shop Stewards Network (NSSN), when the Socialist Party made its
long anticipated move to try and turn it into an anti-cuts front, and
most of the anarchist, syndicalist and independent activists walked out.
It would be a mistake, however, to put the lack of politics down simply
to malign Marxist influence. Instead, we should look at the nature of
rank and file groups themselves. They are not made up of masses of
ordinary workers but trade union activists (often members of political
groups), sinking their political differences to the lowest common
denominator â militant trade unionism. Perhaps a quote from the paper of
one of the more successful rank and files of the 1970s, the NALGO Action
Group, will illustrate this. An editorial stated: âthe future
development of NALGO Action Group remains as it always has, in the hands
of its supporters whose political persuasions are less important than
their common desire to work for greater democracy and militancy within
NALGO and [the] larger trade union movement.â[172] Here, the problems
are similar to those of âneutralâ syndicalism. The result is not the
desired horizontal networking of workplace activists, but lowest common
denominator trade unionism. This means many well meaning militants and
revolutionaries end up being foot soldiers for leftist agendas, such as
reforming the union or party political adventures (this was certainly
the experience of DAM). This is not to say rank and file initiatives
cannot also be a vehicle for workers to begin to take struggles into
their own hands. The recent victories for the âSparksâ electricians are
a clear example of this potential, notably organising around a specific
grievance (pay cuts) rather than a union reform agenda. But for
anarcho-syndicalists, rank and filism, much like trade unionism as a
whole, is no substitute for revolutionary unionism.
So while it is always necessary to organise with as many workers as
possible on a class basis, the unions we seek to build cannot afford to
water down their principles to the lowest common denominator. Nor should
we content ourselves with tailgating the struggles organised by the
mainstream unions which, under neoliberalism, normally means defeat sold
as victory. Rather, we should be seeking to build a revolutionary
workersâ organisation based on clear anti-capitalist and anti-state
principles which can take the initiative in organising struggles. This
is what the Solidarity Federation means when it describes itself as a
revolutionary union initiative. Having recognised that the existing
unions are but minority organisations of activists, and dispensed with
the fallacy that âpolitics begins with millionsâ, we can recognise that
everyday struggles are political. The question becomes a practical one â
how to organise collective direct action for ourselves?
We unite the political and the economic because it reflects the
realities under capitalism. The working class is at one and the same
time oppressed and exploited. If we are ever to be truly free, we must
challenge both capitalist exploitation and the power capitalism and the
state have over us. The coming together of exploitation and oppression
can be clearly seen in the smallest of workplace or community actions.
When workers organise they challenge the managementâs ârightâ to manage.
When tenants organise they challenge the Iandlordâs ârightâ to their
private property. It matters little whether this takes the form of a
fight for increased wages, or reduced rents, or a fight to resist
attempts to impose new working or residency conditions. In fighting one
we fight the other; the economic and the political cannot be separated.
Should the workers win a strike for increased wages, their power to win
better conditions improves and vice versa. The revolutionary union
unites the political and the economic, seeking to organise collective
direct action in the here and now, not waiting to follow the lead of
reformists or for struggles to arise spontaneously.
What we are describing is sometimes called âminority unionismâ, but this
is somewhat misleading on two counts. First, as we have argued above,
even million strong trade unions are in practice, in terms of their
presence in the workplace, minority organisations. It is not uncommon
for there to be no workplace activists in a given âunionisedâ workplace.
Even when there is, itâs most commonly one or two shop stewards for a
whole department or employer. Itâs rare for a trade union to have a
large density of workplace activists in a single workplace. So all
unions, in terms of everyday activity, are as Emile Pouget said, âan
active minority.â[173] Secondly, we are not a minority out of
aspiration, but out of recognition of reality. We, of course, seek the
widest possible adoption of anarcho-syndicalist ideas and methods
throughout the working class. Itâs just that we see no reason to wait
until then to organise. We need to use what capacity we have to organise
what struggles we can in the here and now.
When we talk of organising direct action, what most immediately springs
to mind is the strike. But in truth, a strike requires significant
organisation to pull off, and often we may find ourselves setting our
sights on other forms of action. Generally speaking, the fewer the
number of participants, the less direct economic pressure we can bring
to bear, and thus the more we rely on moral pressure. This could be as
simple as shunning the boss, such as the members of a team refusing all
non-essential communication, perhaps all verbal communication full stop,
until their concerns are addressed. This type of action can certainly be
organised by individuals, and any propaganda organisation capable of
bringing out a newspaper can surely orient itself to such practical
activity as well as, or indeed instead of, propaganda activities. Doing
so and shouting about it has been, in our experience, a way to attract
more militants of a similar persuasion.
Conversely, the greater the number of participants, the more economic
pressure we can bring to bear and the less we need rely on moral
pressure. At this end of the spectrum is the insurrectionary general
strike. We will discuss this more in the following section, which
discusses the role of the revolutionary union in the revolutionary
process. Needless to say, such an action requires the ability to
mobilise millions of workers, and thus a serious level of organisation
far beyond anything existing today. We are not saying we can grow into
such an organisation by sheer force of will. Such a revolutionary union
could be formed by many possible means, and probably through some
combination of all of them: simple membership growth, radicalised
breakaways from other unions, recruitment from wider waves of struggles,
mergers between existing and new organisations along anarcho-syndicalist
lines⊠What we are saying is that by organising class conflicts along
anarcho-syndicalist lines in the here and now we can, via the school of
struggle, develop both an organisation and wider culture of solidarity
and direct action within the working class greater than that which
exists at present. The exact path between here and the revolutionary
process remains to be trodden. The important thing is that we begin to
walk it. What role does the revolutionary union have to play in this
process?
The aim of the anarcho-syndicalist union is to act as an organisational
force in the daily lives of the working class. We seek to organise
workplace and community resistance, and to constantly link this to the
need to overthrow the double yoke of capital and the state. We seek the
overthrow of capitalism, and for it to be replaced by the self-managed
libertarian communist society. Though the physical organisation of
resistance is central to our ideas, we do not reject revolutionary
theory. But for anarcho-syndicalists, theory grows out of practice and
as such, should be seen as an aid to organising workers struggle and
not, as so often is the case, a means of dominating and controlling it.
And as capitalism is dynamic with conditions constantly changing, so
must the methods used by workers to fight it. Engaged in this daily
struggle we are best placed to ensure our theory keeps pace.
As anarcho-syndicalists, we oppose all forms of political parties. We
reject the notion that governments act in the interest of the working
class. They may bring forward minor improvements in order to make
electoral gains, but fundamental change can only come about through the
power of organised labour. We also reject the so called ârevolutionaryâ
parties, on the grounds that, like all political parties, they seek
state power. Our aim is the democratically controlled, self-managed
libertarian communist society, not one in which the capitalist parties
are simply replaced with a Marxist dictatorship. We argue that the
workers must take control of their own struggles, as opposed to relying
on politicians. We argue for, and seek to organise, direct action both
as a means by which workers can democratically control their struggles,
and as the most effective weapon in the fight against capitalism. As
opposed to voting every few years for some useless politician, we argue
that people must organise and confront capitalism and the state head on.
For anarcho-syndicalists, direct action is much more than a tactic to be
employed against capitalism. Through the use of direct action, we seek
to build a culture of solidarity and mutual aid in direct opposition to
the dominant capitalist culture, based on narrow self-interest and
greed. Through direct action, the working class can develop the skills,
confidence, and understanding of the nature of society needed to
administer the future libertarian society. Direct action doesnât just
meet our immediate demands, but frees us from the stultifying reliance
on political leaders and the state. Through direct action, the working
class can forge the bonds of solidarity that will form the ethos that
will underpin the future libertarian communist society. Through direct
action, workers can begin to build the foundations of the future
libertarian communist society now.
The aim of anarcho-syndicalism is to build militant workersâ
organisation, but from a clear revolutionary perspective. It fully
realises that conditions in society may vary, and accordingly so will
the possibility of organising class struggle. But no matter what the
conditions, anarcho-syndicalists argue that militant workersâ
organisation cannot be achieved by a political group organising outside
of the workplace. Organisation in the workplace will have to be built by
the revolutionary union that involves itself in the day to day struggle
of workers. But the aim of anarcho-syndicalism is not to enrol every
worker into the revolutionary union, but rather to organise mass
meetings at which the union argues for militant action. âMassâ does not
necessarily mean âmassiveâ. If a team consists of five people, then a
meeting of four is a mass meeting. Obviously, at the other end of the
spectrum, these could include hundreds of workers. But such large
meetings can stifle opportunities to participate, and so splitting into
smaller meetings, co-ordinated by a delegate council may be more
appropriate. The precise forms employed by the revolutionary union are
dictated by the needs of the struggle and not by theory. And the
revolutionary union does not limit itself to the workplace. Class
struggle also takes place against landlords, property developers, the
benefits regime, letting agencies, temp agencies, the tax authorities,
the prison regime, and other representatives of capital and state.
But neither should the anarcho-syndicalist union be seen as a monolithic
organisation that seeks to organise every aspect of human activity. Our
aim is to build a revolutionary culture within the working class that
will form the basis of the future libertarian communist society. And
this revolutionary culture will be as rich and diverse as humanity
itself. It will comprise of countless groups and interests, formal and
informal, that will operate both in and outside of the union. The role
of the union is to bring this diversity together on the basis of class
in opposition to capitalism and the state. At the heart of the
anarcho-syndicalist union is the Local, which aims to be at the centre
of community and workplace struggle in the surrounding area. But the
role of the Local goes beyond that. It provides the physical space where
a diverse range of groups, such as oppressed, cultural, and education
groups can organise. The Local acts as the social, political, and
economic centre for working class struggle in a given area. It is the
physical embodiment of our beliefs and methods, the means by which
workers become anarcho-syndicalist not just on the basis of ideas but
activity.
The Local aims to be a hive of working class self-activity in the area,
inside and outside the union, a catalyst for workersâ self-activity, an
infrastructure and tool of struggle for the working class. Itâs a base
not only to organise against capital and state, but for all sorts of
marginalised and oppressed groups to organise. If weâre serious about
prefiguring a libertarian communist society, we must challenge
patriarchy, racism, and bigotry of all forms within society and, when
necessary, within our own ranks too. So long as we donât have our own
premises, we can use drop in sessions in whatever venues are available,
we can use picket lines, or hold regular stalls, to discuss organising
with workers. And out of these weâre likely to find fights to pick with
capital and the state. In the early days, these fights are likely to be
small, attempts to collectivise individual grievances. We can only bite
off what we can chew. But by taking on instances of wage theft, stolen
deposits, and the other everyday little attacks, we can both win
concrete demands but also start to build a culture of direct action, and
normalise the idea of standing up for our interests, of fighting for
ourselves.
Casualisation is often said to be a new phenomenon which undermines the
possibility of organised labour. But this is only partly true. Short
term contracts and temp jobs will mean building up a permanent
organisation on the job will likely prove difficult to impossible. But
this simply calls for different tactics and forms of struggle, in which
the Local can play a central role. The Local is the place for casual
workers to meet, discuss and develop tactics adequate to their
conditions. Remember the casual workers who formed the militant backbone
of the early French CGT, and recall the IWWâs itinerant agitator
organisers with branches in their satchels. Capital will always seek to
break down our areas of strength. But this only forces us to develop new
tactics. If we are lucky, we can turn our weaknesses into strengths.
Workers may move between jobs too frequently to build up lasting
collective organisation on the job, but theyâll often remain in the same
sector. So, for instance, restaurant workers belonging to a Local could
share ideas and knowledge about employers, and draw on the Local to
organise pickets to enforce demands. The flipside to casualisation is,
if youâre not going to be in the job long anyway, the threat of losing
your job for standing up for yourself is much reduced. For those in more
permanent positions, building up solid workplace organisation which
could resist victimisation would likely be a better approach.
The typical vanguardist position is that consciousness precedes action.
This is, after all, why the vanguard party, bearer of ârevolutionary
consciousnesses,â must lead the working class. This attitude is explicit
in Leninist Marxism but implicit in many other political organisations,
even when they seek only to be âthe leadership of ideas.â For
anarcho-syndicalists, it is the other way around. Workers may not all
share our goals of overthrowing capitalism and the state, but weâre not
asking them to sign up to that as a precondition of organising. Weâre
simply asking them to take direct action with us in their own interests.
If, in this process, anarcho-syndicalism begins to make more sense to
them, then the union gains another member. It should be explained that
this is not any old union, concerned only with bread and butter issues,
but a revolutionary one also pursuing radical social transformation.
This isnât a question of identifying as an anarcho-syndicalist, but
rather of identifying with our methods and goals, whatever your
preferred political label (or lack of). It doesnât do us any good to be
recruiting workers who donât share our aims and methods, nor does it do
workers any good to be joining a union whose aims and methods they donât
share. But we should not be afraid to actively recruit through activity
either, as this is the only way to expand beyond the existing pool of
politicised militants. Revolutionary union activity can expand the pool.
Workplace organisations may be militant but that does not automatically
make them revolutionary. We cannot just limit ourselves to organising
workplace meetings and hoping they will, as if by magic, gain a
revolutionary perspective. Many a militant struggle has demanded union
recognition, won it, and then settled down into the normal routine of
mediated industrial relations. Our aim is to organise militancy as a
stepping stone to revolutionary thinking. The revolutionary union can
play a catalytic role in creating such a culture of solidarity and
direct action amongst the working class, recruiting those who share our
aims and goals into our ranks. As well as raising issues and, where
possible, organising action, we should be putting out regular
propaganda, attempting to organise workplace meetings, and generally
attempting to draw people into SF. In the long term, the aim would be to
increase the organisation to the point where workplace meetings will
slowly transform, from being simply militant, or primarily economic,
meetings to being meetings of revolutionary workers. In effect, the
workplace meeting would become the foundation of the anarcho-syndicalist
union branch in a given workplace. A similar process can take place in
the local area through the Local, which is especially important for
casual, unemployed, domestic or retired workers.
We sometimes hear the argument that, by negotiating within capitalism,
we risk becoming part of it. But this does not stand the reality test.
This is to equate negotiation with class collaboration. But as every
demand short of revolution is a negotiation, this approach would in
effect brand every organisation that did not demand revolution in every
situation as reformist. This is nonsense and pure posturing.
Negotiations are simply meetings between workers and the enemy, whether
management, the letting agent, or whoever. The factor that determines
the nature of negotiations is who is doing the negotiating. Our approach
to negotiations is to see them as part of class struggle. Negotiations
should be done en masse, or by delegates mandated by all the workers
taking action. The revolutionary union does not negotiate on behalf of
workers, workers negotiate for themselves, but we donât shy away from
being delegated. We donât seek negotiations looking for a âjustâ or
âfairâ result, but rather to demand as much as possible in any given
circumstance. If an action has management on the run, then we do not
limit ourselves to the original demand but rather, we seek to press home
our advantage and make as many gains as possible. Revolutionary practice
consists of the relationship between means and ends. It is the use of
direct action to win immediate demands in such a way that builds the
confidence, solidarity, and culture needed for further struggles, and
ultimately, revolution itself. Revolution is a matter of deeds not
words, in our everyday struggles as well as the future upheaval.
It has to be understood that direct action is economic war carried out
at a distance. As such, it is always hard to assess what effect a
dispute is having on the other side. The only time that the two sides
come together is during negotiations. One of the primary aims of
negotiations, therefore, is for one side to try to assess what effect
the action is having on the other, while attempting to conceal any
weaknesses of their own. Should it become clear that the effect of the
action is having a greater effect than first thought, then obviously the
demands made should increase. The anarcho-syndicalist goes into
negotiations as a mandated delegate. But only an idiot would not ask for
more if it becomes apparent that management are on the run. Negotiations
also have a further role in that they can be used as part of the process
of demoralising management. The anarcho-syndicalist union engages in
class war, and as in any war, morale or alternately demoralisation plays
an important role in the battle. The anarcho-syndicalist union seeks to
instil in management a sense of fear, hatred and bewilderment. We want
to get to a point where theyâre tearing their hair out at our
âunreasonableâ demands and are desperate to make it stop. On this note,
one of our members was once involved in an action which forced the
manager to go and buy everyone ice creams on a hot day. When the manager
relented and offered to pay for ice creams, they insisted he went to buy
them in person. This is the kind of âunreasonableâ and demoralising
power we seek to have over management. And needless to say, ice cream
does not equal reformism.
The anarcho-syndicalist approach is to pick fights we can win, and use
these victories to attract more workers into our orbit and to
demonstrate the validity of our anti-capitalist and anti-state approach.
It is true that most workers donât share our perspective at the present
time. But this is not a fixed fact, but dependent on numerous variables,
some of which we can control and others which we cannot. In practice, we
have found that at least some of our fellow workers are open to our
revolutionary ideas and methods, whereas reformism is most often pushed
by politicos convinced that âideologyâ puts off âthe workersâ (remember
the Treintistas). And we should add, the distance between
disillusionment in your job and party politics, attitudes which are
widespread, and a revolutionary perspective is not as great as many
specialists in ârevolutionary theoryâ like to insist. Many of us have
traversed it, and thereâs nothing special about us. Being against
capitalism and the state in the abstract doesnât make much sense. But
when itâs expressed through direct action, asserting our independence
from those we struggle against, itâs almost common sense. Through the
process of struggle, we are confident our perspective will come to
appear more and more self-evident, even as it evolves through these
experiences.
For example, it is often difficult to conduct anything resembling direct
action in the streets these days without coming into conflict with the
police. Marching without prior permission, or leaving the route of a
march (or sometimes for no apparent reason at all), is likely to attract
police repression. Police repression vindicates our anti-state
perspective. Many of our newest members have been politicised by the
baton in the recent struggles over tuition fees and austerity. But the
police are in a bind. If they donât respond with repression, then weâre
free to organise direct action, such as picketing temp agencies and
organising economic or communications blockades. When these tactics get
the goods, they vindicate our anti-capitalist, direct action ethos. If
our understanding of the nature of society is broadly correct, then
struggles should expose the fault lines between the working class on the
one side and capital and the state on the other. Through waging the
everyday class war, anarcho-syndicalist ideas can become a working class
common sense. Deposit stolen? Picket, occupy, and blockade the bastards.
Problems at work? Get some workmates together and get organised.
SF members in the same industry also form industrial networks. At
present, these are small and function mostly as email lists for
discussion and the production of propaganda. Unlike Locals, Networks are
geographically dispersed and so lack the immediacy of face to face
organisation, and are thus limited in what they can do, for now at
least, with most practical activity being carried out through Locals.
But as we grow, there is the potential to form industrial Locals, as
well as workplace branches of SF, which linked together through the
industrial networks, will form embryonic revolutionary industrial
unions. We, of course, do not mean âindustrialâ in the sense of
smokestacks, but in the sense of âone workplace, one unionâ. So for
instance on a university campus, porters, cleaners, teaching assistants
and academic staff (assuming they were not bosses of some sort) would
form a workplace branch, which in turn would form part of the Education
Workersâ Network. For us, this is still in its early stages. For our
sister-sections in Spain and Italy, workplace branches and industrial
unions are far more advanced. British conditions, particularly with
regard to trade union legislation, are somewhat different. But that only
impacts the details, not the broad thrust of what weâre trying to do.
As we are presently a tiny minority of the working class, we will need
to organise beyond our membership. Even if we were 10,000 times larger,
this would still be the case; as we saw, it was even the case in
Catalonia in 1936. Various organisational forms can be employed for this
purpose: from workplace committees, mass meetings, neighbourhood
assemblies, and strike committees, through to factory committees,
delegate councils, or a fully fledged federation of workers councils.
None of these forms are a panacea and all have their drawbacks as well
as benefits. Rather, they are democratic means of organising which can
be employed by the revolutionary union as the needs of the struggle
dictate. The particular forms of organisation we employ reflect the
content of the struggle. In Puerto Real, workplace and community mass
meetings were a vital part of the struggle. But we have also attended
âmass meetingsâ organised by reformist unions, where a string of top
table speakers mouth platitudes to a bored audience, or which simply
serve to rubber stamp decisions already made elsewhere. In the case of
the Workmates collective on the London Underground, the delegate council
they set up was sidelined by action coming directly from the mass
meetings. But if similar mass meetings were happening across multiple
work sites, something like a delegate council could have proved
indispensible in joining up the struggles.[174] The content of the
struggle must shape the forms we use. The role of the revolutionary
union is to take the initiative in organising struggles in the first
place.
Just as the anarcho-syndicalist union cannot and does not wish to
organise all aspects of human activity, nor does it seek to organise the
revolution on behalf of the working class. For us, revolutions come
about when the anger of the oppressed can no longer be contained by the
power of the oppressors, leading to an explosion of anger that drives
revolutionary change. Revolutions break out, they cannot be planned,
they cannot be predicted, they cannot be organised. But if they are to
succeed, revolutions have to move quickly from anger to decisive action.
The revolution has to be advanced and defended, people have to eat, they
need water and electricity, and these things have to be organised. The
role of the anarcho-syndicalist union is to act as a catalyst and
organising force within the revolution to ensure its success.
Within the revolutionary process, the anarcho-syndicalist union seeks to
organise the insurrectionary general strike as the means by which the
workers take control of the streets and the workplaces. This means that,
amidst strike waves and street demonstrations, riots and political
turmoil, the revolutionary union looks to generalise the strikes, to
turn them from walkouts into expropriations, restarting production and
distribution under self-management to meet social needs. The
insurrectionary general strike marks the start of the process of
building the libertarian communist society. The production and
distribution of goods and services is taken over under workersâ
democratic control and run on the basis of human need. The revolutionary
union seeks to organise a system of free councils without subordination
to any authority or political party, bar none. These organisations of
the working class both administer production and distribution according
to needs, and supplant the authority of the state. Militias are formed
to defend the revolution from the external forces of capitalism and to
shut down the forces of the state. The building blocks of the new
society are put in place on top of the foundations laid by the preceding
struggles.
In truth, the idea of revolution in one country always belonged to the
bourgeois revolutionaries, who sought to seize control of the state and
turn it into an instrument of capitalist development. The 20^(th)
century is a striking indictment of the notion that revolution in one
country could ever result in anything remotely communist. Isolated and
surrounded on all sides, even the most impeccable revolution would leave
revolutionaries stranded on an island, facing the permanent threat of
military intervention, and the necessity to source resources unavailable
domestically from the world market. Whilst defensive forces can be
organised in a non-statist manner through workers militias, it is hard
to see how a permanent war footing in such an embattled revolutionary
pocket could establish and maintain libertarian communist social
relations. The necessities to engage with the world market and to
maintain war production would undermine the reorganisation of society to
meet human needs. The revolution we seek will be worldwide or it will
not be at all.
Thus, the revolutionary process we have described should not be
conceived of as a national one, or even a series of national revolutions
one after the other. Indeed, there is no reason to think such waves of
class struggle will respect national borders. The international wave of
class struggles following World War I certainly did not, and nor did the
wave of struggles from 1968. To be sure, national identity is a powerful
force for many workers, but the daily work of the revolutionary union in
its cultural and educational aspects, as well as practical international
solidarity, should have helped to undermine its appeal in favour of
working class internationalism. As Rudolf Rocker wrote of the First
International, it âbecame the great school mistress of the socialist
labour movement and confronted the capitalist world with the world of
international labour, which was being ever more firmly welded together
in the bonds of proletarian solidarity.â[175]
Language too is a material barrier to the international circulation of
struggles. A true revolutionary international could only assist in this
process of circulation and co-ordination. Here too, there is much work
to be done. The IWA is mainly centred in Europe and South America. Many
of our sections, including ourselves, are not (yet) functioning unions.
We hope this text can help in the movement from propaganda groups
towards revolutionary unions across the International. But even then,
there is still work to do. It is now impossible to conceive of the kind
of worldwide revolutionary wave weâre discussing, without the working
class populations of China, India, Bangladesh, Vietnam, and countless
other countries playing a prominent part. Conditions for organising in
many of these places are hostile to say the least. But yet they have
seen massive waves of autonomous struggles outside the control of the
official unions which dwarf the struggles in Europe in recent years. If
we are serious that âall the revolutionary workers of the world must
build a real International Association of Workersâ, we must find ways to
open a dialogue with such groups.
It is difficult to know where to start. This is a profoundly practical
question beyond the scope of this text. It will require much discussion,
and trial and error to move towards an answer. We raise it here simply
to acknowledge the scale of the task we have set for ourselves. Perhaps
this process could begin with making anarcho-syndicalist materials
available in Mandarin, Cantonese, Hindi, Arabic, Farsi⊠and by seeking
to initiate a dialogue around revolutionary unionist practices,
translating any correspondence that results back into European tongues.
Perhaps we could seek out and build contacts in parts of the world where
the IWA lacks a presence, then seek to turn contacts into sections,
small sections from propaganda groups into unions, and for union
sections to begin to weave a culture of direct action into the daily
life of the working class. Perhaps there are already radical workersâ
groupings operating along similar lines and we simply are unaware of
each othersâ existence. Such working class internationalism represents a
practical task of vital importance to the prospects of any global
revolutionary wave that sweeps away capital and states to instantiate
libertarian communism.
However a global revolutionary wave starts, somewhere goes first. Some
factory or office or infrastructure is the first to be taken over. The
drive for this is likely to be material necessity. People need to eat,
people need electricity, people need water. If the revolutionary wave
isnât sparked by an economic crisis, itâs sure to provoke one. With a
worldwide wave of strikes, occupations, demonstrations and riots,
workers will begin to go hungry, while the capitalists, who have the
deepest pockets, will be stockpiling reserves. Thus, within this
process, the revolutionary union seeks to generalise the strike wave,
across industries, localities, and national borders. And as it
generalises, it seeks to organise for the strikes to become occupations.
To expropriate the expropriators and seize back social production for
human needs.
Everything we know about social revolutions suggests they are messy,
contradictory processes, an open clash of opposing forces that sees
advances and retreats, consolidations and capitulations. They proceed
unevenly in fits and starts, ebbs and flows, and all the more so when
weâre not talking about the overthrow of one state, but 200 or more! The
rupture with capitalism is likely to follow this pattern, developing
unevenly, with revolutionary surges battling counter revolutionary
inertia and attempts to restore the sanctity of private property. Some
of these clashes are likely to be armed. However, revolution is not
principally a military question but a social one. Stripped of their
capital by workplace occupations, and stripped of their states by the
beating back of the police, and mutinies amongst the troops when ordered
to fire on âtheir ownâ, the ruling class will represent a much
diminished force.[176] Still, they will likely unleash whatever violence
they can via the state or mercenary forces to crush the revolution, and
this will need to be met with violence, organised along libertarian
lines through a militia system.
The libertarian communist revolution is a process. It is a movement. It
will likely develop and blossom from strike waves to expropriations over
a period of years. This isnât a âtransitional phaseâ, it is what the
revolution is. We do not wake up one morning and find that libertarian
communism has been proclaimed. We seize back society from capital and
the state as much as we can, and push for libertarian communist social
relations as much as possible. We aim for the abolition of wages and the
distribution of goods and services according to need. We aim for the
abolition of all state power and the destruction of all social
hierarchies, whether based on gender, colour or anything else. Through
direct action in our daily struggles, the working class forges the bonds
of solidarity and forms the ethos that will underpin the future
libertarian communist society. The foundations will have been laid by
the preceding struggles. The idea of revolution as a glorious day was
born on the threshold of the Bastille and embellished with the Bolshevik
mythologising of the storming of the Winter Palace.[177] We must let it
go.
Any global revolution will have its dramatic days, but the idea of
revolution as an instantaneous transition belongs to those who wish to
seize power in a single state. It is utterly inadequate for the
overthrow of an entire mode of production. Libertarian communism is not
something to be established âafter the revolutionâ. The revolutionary
process is the process of creating libertarian communism, a process
which is likely to build in rising waves, rather than be achieved on a
single glorious day. As more and more workplaces are seized, and as the
state forces are weakened and states begin to crumble, private property
becomes a mere memory of a bygone era, like tithes and tributes before
it. Expropriated workplaces do not relate to each other as isolated
enterprises trading in a market. They federate together into a single
entity, pooling resources on the basis of needs under self-management,
and doing away with wage labour, as the necessities of life become
available to the working class directly from our own efforts, without
the mediation of the market.
The revolutionary union is vital to play both a preparatory role for
these decisive struggles, and to generalise the libertarian communist
movement within them towards the insurrectionary general strike when
they erupt. Yes, the task is a great one. But of course, we only want
the world.
Endnotes
[1] IWA statutes, see:
[2] Quoted in Abel Paz, Durruti â the people armed.
[3] Unit 24 of SelfEd â SolFedâs self-education course on
anarcho-syndicalism. See:
[4] John Quail, The slow burning fuse, p. 246â247.
[5] John Turner was one of the publishers of the agitational syndicalist
paper âThe voice of labourâ which advocated direct action and the
general strike. However, his position as a bureaucrat undermined in
practice the politics he espoused in theory.
[6] See this blog by an anarcho-syndicalist in the PCS trade union:
[7] This is not to say a shop steward position cannot sometimes be used
to further a direct action based organising strategy, e.g. by using a
union recognition agreement as legal cover to hold workplace meetings
which organise unofficial, on the job action.
[8] Tom Brown, Principles of syndicalism:
[9] The CWU union called off planned Christmas strikes â the most
powerful weapon in the postal workersâ arsenal â for âmeaningful
negotiationsâ prompted by unspecified concessions. The talks, of course,
had to be kept secret from the membership. Three months of silence and
demobilisation later, and the CWU recommended acceptance of an almost
identical deal involving 40,000 job losses. The âvictoryâ was that the
CWU would be âconsultedâ on these cuts. Demoralised by three months of
silence and having squandered building momentum in the pre-Christmas
strikes, posties voted to accept the deal, though it was widely seen as
a âsell outâ.
[10] Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, The communist manifesto:
[11] Vladimir Illych Lenin, What is to be done?:
[12] Leon Trotsky, The history of the Russian revolution:
[13] Amadeo Bordiga, Theses on the role of the Communist Party in the
proletarian revolution:
[14] Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, The German ideology:
(the quoted passage appears as an added note in margin of the original
manuscript).
[15] Vladimir Illych Lenin, State and revolution:
[16] Leon Trotsky, The history of the Russian revolution:
[17] For a good introductory account, see Ida Mett, The Kronstadt
uprising of 1921:
[18] See Maurice Brinton, The Bolsheviks and workersâ control â state
and counter-revolution:
[19] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[20] Quoted in Bob Holton, British syndicalism 1900â1914, myths and
realities, p.36.
[21] Subversion, Labouring in vain â a critical history of the Labour
Party:
[22] To what extent it did so will be taken up in chapter 4; successful
post-war wage struggles ultimately shifted the costs on to the bosses,
which is part of why they came to hate the welfare state.
[23] See 1978â1979: Winter of Discontent:
[24] Syndicalist Workers Federation, How Labour governed 1945â51:
[25] Efforts are often made to find âanarchismâ in figures as diverse as
the 6^(th) century BC Chinese mystic Lao-Tse, ultra-individualist Ayn
Rand, and even leaders of states such as Reagan and Thatcher. Peter
Marshallâs liberal history of anarchism, âDemanding the impossibleâ, is
amongst the worst offenders here as a consequence of stripping away the
socialist opposition to private property, like a good liberal, and
reducing anarchism to mere âanti-stateâ sentiment, so vague even heads
of state can share it. There certainly are libertarian and anti-state
ideas and movements throughout history, but labelling these âanarchistâ
is anachronistic.
[26] Peter Kropotkin, Mutual aid: a factor of evolution:
[27] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) Century:
^(th)-century-vadim-damier
[28] Quoted in Maurizio Antonioli (ed), The International Anarchist
Congress of Amsterdam (1907), p.113.
[29] Quoted in Maurizio Antonioli (ed), The International Anarchist
Congress of Amsterdam (1907), p.123. Malatestaâs analysis is astute in
that workersâ economic positions alone cannot be assumed sufficient to
create unity in struggle, let alone libertarian communism. Simply
recruiting all the workers into one organisation doesnât dissolve the
hierarchies and ideological conflicts among them, nor necessarily make
for common struggle.
[30] The following quotes and paraphrased argument is drawn from Errico
Malatestaâs 1925 Syndicalism and anarchism:
[31] Dielo Truda, The organisational platform of the libertarian
communists, part 3:
[32] Dielo Truda, The organisational platform of the libertarian
communists, part 3:
[33] Dielo Truda, The organisational platform of the libertarian
communists, part 5:
[34] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[35] Fernand Pelloutier, History of the bourses du travail:
[36] Paul Mason, Live working or die fighting, p.124.
[37] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[38] CGT, The charter of Amiens:
[39] Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe, The rise and fall of
revolutionary syndicalism, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe
(eds) Revolutionary syndicalism, p.3.
[40] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.3.
[41] Quoted in Patrick Renshaw, The Wobblies: the story of the IWW and
syndicalism in the United States, p.46.
[42] Patrick Renshaw, The Wobblies: the story of the IWW and syndicalism
in the United States, p.47.
[43] IWW, Preamble to the IWW cconstitution:
[44] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.5.
[45] Many of the anarchists described this as âanti-politicalâ, equating
politics with party politics and the state. We use the term in a more
everyday sense, that someone who is an anarchist has political beliefs.
[46] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.9.
[47] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.8.
[48] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.3.
[49] For instance, see Fred Hansenâs recollections: âI didnât know about
the revolutionary part at first, but as soon as I got in the
organisation, I started reading an awful lot â not only IWW literature,
but the communist literature, the anarchist literature, anybodyâs
literature.â In Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds),
Solidarity forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.189.
[50] A recent series of pieces in the IWWâs Industrial Worker argues
thereâs at least four interpretations of the term âOne Big Unionâ, some
of which complement and some of which contradict one another: 1) every
worker or most workers join the IWW; 2) a vision of a
universalism/libertarian socialist principles for the IWW; 3) a vision
of a new society (where unions run things instead of states, not unlike
Marxâs comment about replacing governance of people with administration
of things); and 4) a vision for revolutionary change (the class united).
See
[51] 1919: The murder of Wesley Everest:
[52] Stewart Bird, Dan Georgakas, and Deborah Shaffer (eds), Solidarity
forever: an oral history of the IWW, p.179.
[53] See
for a timeline up to 1983. The IWW has recently enjoyed something of a
resurgence, most notably with the Starbucks Workers Union. As a living
organisation in much changed circumstances, this is omitted from the
analysis here. Many of the debates and contradictions of old live on.
However, the contemporary debate of most interest to
anarcho-syndicalists is that around the notion of âdirect unionismâ,
which advocates a form of direct action unionism rather than reliance on
representation and contracts. See
for a developing archive. See also the Recomposition blog, which
contains much of the âdirect unionismâ material as well as accounts of
contemporary workplace activity along direct action lines:
[54] Bob Holton, British syndicalism 1900 â 1914, myths and realities,
p.32.
[55] However, there were attempts to form independent syndicalist unions
in Britain before WWII. Some of these are documented in âFirst Flightâ
by Albert Meltzer and âDare to be a Danielâ by Wilf McCartney, both
published by the Kate Sharpley Library. The shop stewardsâ committees in
Clydeside during WWI had their roots in this agitation.
[56] Quoted in Joseph White, Syndicalism in a mature industrial setting:
the case of Britain, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe (eds),
Revolutionary syndicalism, p.103.
[57] Joseph White, Syndicalism in a mature industrial setting: the case
of Britain, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe (eds),
Revolutionary syndicalism, p.104.
[58] The 1912 pamphlet âThe Minersâ Next Stepâ is one of the most famous
examples of this union reform agenda, although it went largely
unrealised. It also advocated use of parliament, but making MPs
recallable by the unions, a novel compromise between
anti-parliamentarism and parliamentary socialism. See
[59] 1912: the syndicalist trials:
[60] Joseph White, Syndicalism in a mature industrial setting: the case
of Britain, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe (eds),
Revolutionary syndicalism, p.115.
[61] Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe, The rise and fall of
revolutionary syndicalism, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe
(eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p.6.
[62] Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe, The rise and fall of
revolutionary syndicalism, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe
(eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p.7.
[63] There is also the infamous case of the Casa del Obrero Mundial in
Mexico which, during the Mexican Revolution, sided with the liberal
government against Zapataâs insurgent peasants only to be repressed by
the government once the peasant uprising was under control (see John M.
Hart, Revolutionary syndicalism in Mexico in Marcel van der Linden and
Wayne Thorpe (eds), Revolutionary syndicalism), and the aforementioned
partial co-option of British syndicalism into a trade union reform
movement.
[64] Anton Pannekoek, Letter on workersâ councils:
[65] Council communists love acronyms. We will only touch on the main
ones here, but see the further reading for more detailed accounts.
[66] The German word âunionâ (Ger: âunionâ) has nothing to do with the
word âtrade unionâ (Ger: âGewerkschaftâ). Both the council communist
unions and the anarcho-syndicalist FAUD used the word âunionâ in part to
distinguish their revolutionary organisations from the mainstream trade
unions.
[67] Program of the AAUD:
[68] Dave Graham, An introduction to left communism in Germany from 1914
to 1923:
[69] Anton Pannekoek, Workersâ councils, p.60.
[70] Anton Pannekoek, Workersâ councils, p.65â66.
[71] Anton Pannekoek, Workersâ councils, p.61.
[72] Anton Pannekoek, Workersâ councils, p.62.
[73] In Pannekoekâs defence, itâs worth noting that he was writing at a
time (1936) where revolutions had been breaking out in recent memory in
numerous countries, and it may be unfair to generalise his writings from
that specific context to the present day conditions. Pannekoek likely
had the AAUD in mind when writing âWorkersâ councilsâ.
[74] Amadeo Bordiga, Theses on the role of the Communist Party in the
proletarian revolution:
[75] Guidelines of the AAUD-E:
[76] Otto RĂŒhle, The revolution is not a party affair:
[77] Otto RĂŒhle, From the bourgeois to the proletarian revolution:
[78] Gilles Dauvé and Denis Authier, The communist left in Germany
1918â1921 (appendix):
[79] Dave Graham, An introduction to left communism in Germany
1914â1923:
[80] Gilles Dauvé and Denis Authier, The communist left in Germany
1918â1921:
[81] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[82] Ămile Pouget, Direct action:
[83] Ămile Pouget, Direct action:
[84] Ămile Pouget, Sabotage:
[85] Ămile Pouget, Direct action:
[86] Ămile Pataud and Ămile Pouget, How we shall bring about the
revolution, p.18. Note the original French âsyndicatâ is translated here
simply as âunionâ as opposed to âtrade unionâ in the English printed
edition, since they are clearly talking about the revolutionary union
and not ordinary trade unions.
[87] Ămile Pataud and Ămile Pouget, How we shall bring about the
revolution, p.63.
[88] Ămile Pataud and Ămile Pouget, How we shall bring about the
revolution, p.134â5.
[89] The FORAâs founding pact of solidarity, quoted in Revolutionary
unionism in Latin America â the FORA in Argentina:
[90] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.82.
[91] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.103.
[92] Quoted in Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century,
p.102â103.
[93] See Revolutionary unionism in Latin America â the FORA in
Argentina:
[94] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.49.
[95] Hans Manfred Bock, Anarchosyndicalism in the German labour
movement: a distinctive minority tradition in Marcel van der Linden and
Wayne Thorpe (eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p.59.
[96] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.50.
[97] Hans Manfred Bock, Anarchosyndicalism in the German labour
movement: a distinctive minority tradition in Marcel van der Linden and
Wayne Thorpe (eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p. 72â73.
[98] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.50â51.
[99] Hans Manfred Bock, Anarchosyndicalism in the German labour
movement: a distinctive minority tradition in Marcel van der Linden and
Wayne Thorpe (eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p.63.
[100] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.68.
[101] Guy Debord, Society of the spectacle, thesis 94:
[102] This argument is often advanced by those influenced by council
communism, seemingly unaware that the council communist critique was
aimed at the German trade unions (Gewerkschaften), and not the various
revolutionary unions (anarcho-syndicalist FAUD, council communist AAUD,
AAUD-E...). For example, Anton Pannekoek dedicates a section of his book
âWorkersâ councilsâ to a scathing critique of trade unionism, and then
praises the North American IWW just a few pages later.
[103] Although we canât, of course, know how a more successful
revolution may have changed that course of history. Such counter factual
speculations are of limited value, but the point of the isolation of the
revolution stands.
[104] Gaston Leval, Collectives in the Spanish revolution:
[105] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.123.
[106] Quoted in Abel Paz, Durruti in the Spanish revolution, p.457.
[107] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.123.
[108] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.124.
[109] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.130.
[110] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.126.
[111] More precisely, âthe CNTâ didnât want this because it wasnât a
unitary whole. There were competing visions of what the CNT should be
and this was the de facto compromise between the competing tendencies.
Durruti commented that: âSome think the organisation is simply a vehicle
for defending their economic interests. Others see it as an organisation
that works with the anarchists for social transformation. Of course it
makes sense that itâs so difficult for the straight union activists and
anarchists to get along.â Indeed, Fransisco Ascaso, referring to the
âstraight union activistsâ of the Thirty, commented that âall
organisations tow a great deal of dead weight behind them, and that is
something the CNT cannot avoid.â Abel Paz, Durruti in the Spanish
revolution, p.381 and p.288 respectively.
[112] Abel Paz, Durruti in the Spanish revolution, p.342.
[113] Peiro âwas a member of a group affiliated to the FAIâ (Stuart
Christie, We, the anarchists! A study of the Iberian Anarchist
Federation, p.50). He was also one of the signatories to the âManifesto
of the Thirtyâ and thought conditions were not right for revolution,
arguing for a less radical approach.
[114] De SantilliĂĄn was not a straight reformist and argued vociferously
against conflating syndicalism with the labour movement in general (We,
the anarchists! A study of the Iberian Anarchist Federation, p.16). But
within the FAI he was one of the more reformist members in practice.
[115] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.116.
[116] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.126.
In de SantilliĂĄnâs defence, his argument was based on the impossibility
of libertarian communism in one country. However, class collaboration is
still not an anarcho-syndicalist solution.
[117] Vadim Damier, Anarcho-syndicalism in the 20^(th) century, p.138.
De SantilliĂĄn argued these reforms would lead to the kind of
socio-economic changes the CNT stood for, but nonetheless this was a
reformist position to take.
[118] It tends to call itself ârevolutionary syndicalismâ or even insist
it is also anarcho-syndicalist. It is typically labelled by its critics
âreformist syndicalismâ. Weâve avoided either term here to avoid
confusion.
[119] In Maurizio Antonioli (ed), The international anarchist congress
of Amsterdam (1907).
[120] These splits were acrimonious, destructive and sometimes violent.
But we cannot help thinking it was for the best, since revolutionary and
reformist unionism cannot easily coexist in the same organisation
outside of very specific conditions which bind them together.
[121] Pierre Besnard, Anarcho-syndicalism and anarchism:
[122] Vladimir Illych Lenin, Political report of the central committee
to the extraordinary seventh congress of the Russian Communist Party
(Bolshevik):
[123] Quoted in Solidarity Federation, Anarcho-syndicalism in Puerto
Real: from shipyard resistance to community control:
[124] Marcel van der Linden, Second thoughts on revolutionary
syndicalism:
[125] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[126] CNT, CGT y SO llaman a la huelga general el 29 de marzo:
[127] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[128] Ămile Pataud and Ămile Pouget, How we shall bring about the
revolution, p.63.
[129] Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe, The rise and fall of
revolutionary syndicalism, in Marcel van der Linden and Wayne Thorpe
(eds), Revolutionary syndicalism, p.1.
[130] James Heartfield, World war as class war:
[131] Quoted in Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Why did the West
extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality and growth in historical
perspective:
[132] Quoted in Ed Goddard, Red flags torn:
[133] See Joe Jacobs, Sorting out the postal strike, 1971:
[134] Quotes and chronology from Endangered Phoenix et al, 1926â1985: So
near â so far â a selective history of the British miners:
[135] Endangered Phoenix et al, 1926â1985: So near â so far â a
selective history of the British miners:
[136] Michael Mann, Ruling class strategies and citizenship:
[137] Andre Hoyles, General strike: France 1968 â a factory by factory
account:
[138] Strikes in India today dwarf France 1968, e.g. see:
, although as a percentage of the workforce France 1968 was probably
bigger (around 66%, 10m out of 15m workers).
[139] Mouvement Communiste, May-June 1968 â a situation lacking in
workersâ autonomy:
[140] Mouvement Communiste, May-June 1968 â a situation lacking in
workersâ autonomy:
[141] Andre Hoyles, General strike: France 1968 â a factory by factory
account:
[142] Situationist International, Enragés and Situationists in the
occupations movement:
[143] Mouvement Communiste, May-June 1968 â a situation lacking in
workersâ autonomy:
[144] Mouvement Communiste, May-June 1968 â a situation lacking in
workersâ autonomy:
[145] Unknown Fiat worker, Organising at Fiat, 1969:
[146] Unknown Fiat worker, Organising at Fiat, 1969:
[147] Robert Lumley, Institutionalization from below: The unions and
social movements â 1970s Italy:
[148] Robert Lumley, Institutionalization from below: The unions and
social movements â 1970s Italy:
[149] Mario Tronti, The strategy of refusal:
[150] Steve Wright, Storming heaven:
[151] Unknown Fiat worker, Organising at Fiat, 1969:
[152] Mario Tronti, The strategy of refusal:
[153] Andre Hoyles, General strike: France 1968 â a factory by factory
account:
[154] Joe Hicks and Grahame Allen, A century of change: trends in UK
statistics since 1900:
p.22.
[155] Adam Smith, Lectures on jurisprudence, p.208.
[156] Michel Foucault, Security, terror, population, p.47.
[157] Gareth Morrell, Sara Scott, Di McNeish and Stephen Webster, The
August riots in England: understanding the involvement of young people:
p.34.
[158] The Donovan Report, referenced in DAM, Winning the class war:
[159] See Beverly Silver, Forces of labour:
[160] Mental Health Foundation, Mental health statistics:
[161] E.g. see David Gunnell, Nicos Middleton, Elise Whitley, Daniel
Dorling and Stephen Frank, Why are suicide rates rising in young men but
falling in the elderly? â a time-series analysis of trends in England
and Wales 1950â1998:
and Alfonso Ceccherini-Nelli and Stefan Priebe, Economic factors and
suicide rates: associations over time in four countries:
[162] Helena Smith, Greek woes drive up suicide rate:
[163] Mark Fisher, Capitalist realism:
p.19.
[164] âFairness means giving people what they deserveâ (Conservatives);
âA future fair for allâ (Labour); âWe will build a fairer Britainâ
(Liberal Democrats); âFair is worth fighting forâ (Greens).
[165] Brian Wheeler, Can UK political parties be saved from extinction?:
[166] The Economist, Unrest in peace:
[167] Aufheben, The housing question:
[168] Aufheben, The return of the crisis â part 1:
and part 2:
[169] Escalate Collective, Salt:
[170] Sam Lowry, 1978â1979: Winter of discontent:
[171] Anton Pannekoek, Workersâ councils, p.62.
[172] This quote, and indeed much of this section, is taken from DAMâs
Winning the class war:
[173] Ămile Pataud and Ămile Pouget, How we shall bring about the
revolution, p.63.
[174] The cases of Workmates and Puerto Real form pamphlets #1 and #2 in
our Theory and Practice series:
[175] Rudolf Rocker, Anarcho-syndicalism:
[176] As the revolutionary union develops the capacity to organise more
effective struggles and begins to attract the attention of the state,
the importance of Locals undertaking anti-militarist agitation amongst
the troops increases. Particularly in garrison towns, fraternisation
with the troops could be pursued, as could organising around ex-service
personnel, military housing, or the workplace and other grievances of
the families of troops. The exact content of effective anti-militarist
activity will need to be worked out in practice, but it will increase in
importance as the class struggle heats up.
[177] The storming of the Bastille on the morning of the 14^(th) July
1789 symbolises the outbreak of the French Revolution, where the rising
capitalist class seized power from the monarchy. The Communist Party
attempted a similar mythologising of the storming of the Winter Palace,
staging a mass spectacle with over 100,000 spectators in 1920. These
iconic events stand in for much messier and contradictory revolutionary
and counter revolutionary processes.