đŸ’Ÿ Archived View for library.inu.red â€ș file â€ș marie-isidine-the-issues-of-tomorrow.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 12:43:30. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

âžĄïž Next capture (2024-07-09)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: The Issues of Tomorrow
Author: Marie Isidine
Date: July 1919
Language: en
Topics: class struggle, dictatorship of the proletariat, Marxism, maximalism, Russian revolution, syndicalism
Source: Retrieved on 10th September 2021 from https://forgottenanarchism.wordpress.com/2015/03/23/the-issues-of-tomorrow-marie-isidine/
Notes: Published in Les Temps Nouveaux.

Marie Isidine

The Issues of Tomorrow

Part 1: The reasons for our “maximalism”

The old issue of maximalism and minimalism takes on nowadays a

completely different aspect than the one it had a few years ago. Partly

because of a lack of faith in the realisation of the socialist ideal in

a conceivable future, partly for tactical reasons, the socialist parties

had then elaborated minimum programmes, and had finally made them the

only real content of their everyday action. The anarchists rose up

against this reformism and this possibilism, convinced that nothing

could replace action towards the whole ideal and that any breaking down

of this action could only be harmful. And the conflict between those two

views filled the whole history of the socialist movement, from the

International to our time.

But now the situation has dramatically changed, because of the

revolutions which have broken out in European countries which, only a

few years ago, were the most backward. The distinctly social character

of these revolutions indicates that the fall of bourgeois domination is

no longer a subject of theoretical propaganda or historical predictions:

it it tomorrow’s reality. In Russia, Austria, and Germany, the movement

drags the great masses; it already makes the bourgeoisie shiver in

countries which have not yet been contaminated. Once again, the issue of

maximalism and minimalism is raised. Among the militants of the

socialist and syndicalist movements, some welcome with joy any attempts

at economic emancipation and work to make them spread; others stop,

hesitatingly, in front of the hugeness of the task at hand and wonder

whether they will be equal to the task; they would like to avoid this

responsibility, or even choose a favourable time for the mass movement.

They think the masses are not ready, and they would like to gain time,

if only a couple of years more, to prepare them, and in order to do so,

they need to give the movement a quieter course, to give it as an

objective some perfecting of workers’ rights or simple corporatist

demands.

In order to choose between these two opposite views, it is not enough to

let ourselves be guided by our revolutionary sentiment, or even by our

devotion to our ideal. We must look for the teachings from history, we

must rein in our feelings by critique, we must reach back to the

fundamental principles of our doctrine.

As we start publishing Les Temps Nouveaux again, in these completely new

conditions, we must, from the start, from our first issue, give a clear

answer to this vital question. On this answer depends our attitude

towards future events.

Let’s remind ourselves of our conception of the march of great social

movements, a conception which is entirely different from the one which

inspires the parties which divide their objectives between a final goal

and immediate goals.

How did the great emancipatory movement unfurl in the past? The fight

against the existing class order first only starts among a small

minority whose circumstances made them feel both their oppression and

the hope to put an end to it – more than among the great masses. Among

the masses, oppression is too heavy for the number of them who manage to

free themselves mentally to be, at first, consequent. But the

revolutionary minority fights at its own risks, without wondering about

whether others are following. Little by little, it starts to grow; it

can be seen, if not in facts, at least in spirit. The brave struggle of

some diminishes the fear of others; the spirit of revolt grows. We don’t

always understand clearly what is the goal of people in revolt, but we

understand against what they are fighting, and this elicits sympathy for

them. Then the moment arrives at last when an event, sometimes

insignificant in itself, a flagrant act of violence or arbitrary power,

sparks the revolutionary explosion. Events are precipitated, new

experience is had every day, among the intense agitation of minds, ideas

develop in leaps and bounds among the masses. The gap between the mass

and the revolutionary minority shrinks.

After the revolutionary period – whether the revolution be victorious or

crushed – the general mentality has reached such a level which had never

been reached by long years of patient propaganda efforts. The

revolutionary minority’s ideal is not fully realised, but what is

realised (either in facts or in people’s minds) is getting closer, the

more conviction and the less compromise this minority had expressed in

its action. What has been realised is part of its programme; what is

left will be the inheritance of the new generation, the watchword of the

new era opened by the revolution. Because a revolution is not only the

conclusion of a preceding evolution, it is also the starting point of

the following evolution which will precisely be concerned with the

realisation of the ideas which, during the revolution, have not found a

wide enough resonance.

Even when a revolution is vanquished, the principles it has put forward

never die. Every revolution in the 19^(th) century has been defeated,

but each one of them has been a step closer to victory. The 1848

revolution, which betrayed workers’ hopes, definitely dug, in the Days

of June, an abyss between workers and the republican bourgeoisie; it

also took away the mystical and religious character of socialism and

linked it to the actual social movement. The Paris Commune, drowned in

blood, blew away the cult of state centralisation and proclaimed the

principles of autonomy and federalism. What about the Russian

revolution? Whatever the future holds, it will have proclaimed the fall

of capitalist domination and the rights of labour; in a country where

the oppression on the masses was more revolting than anywhere else, it

proclaimed that it is those masses who must now be master of their

lives. And whatever the future, nothing will take away this idea from

future struggles: the reign of the owning classes has virtually ended.

These general considerations will dictate the answer to the question: do

we meet the conditions for social revolution? Every discussion about

knowing whether the mass is “ready” or “not yet ready” is always

misguided, whether it is pessimistic or optimistic. We have no way to

evaluate every factor which determines that a social group is ready.

What do we call “being ready”? Would we wait for most people to have

become socialists? But we fully know that is impossible in our present

condition. If we could create a radical transformation of concepts,

feelings and of the whole mentality among the masses by propaganda and

education alone, why want a violent revolution, with all its suffering?

At any given time, the mass is never “ready” for the future and will

never be: a revolutionary uprising will have happened sooner.

Revolutionaries don’t have the power to choose their time, to prepare

everything and spark the revolution at will, like lighting fireworks.

People who always consider large movements premature usually use the

grid of the realisation of some “objective historical conditions”: the

degree of capitalist development, state of the industry, development of

the productive forces, etc. But they do not see these dogmas crumble

before their eyes – just like their minimum programmes crumbled – under

the pressure of life. The most confident Marxists have to admit that the

social revolution started not in a country where capitalism was

advanced, but in a mostly agrarian country where it was poorly

developed, and that, consequently, there are other factors at stake than

the development of productive forces. And if they had wished to study

this issue further, they could have drawn this conclusion from Marxism

itself, turning it into its opposite: into a theory of active progress,

realised by the efforts of individuals. There is, in Marx, a precious

quote: “Mankind always sets itself only such tasks as it can solve”1 In

other words, if an ideal is conceived among a community, it is that the

necessary conditions to its realisation are there. Following this idea,

we will say that from that moment on, from the moment an ideal is

formulated by the vanguard minority, its realisation is only a question

of a balance of strength between present forces: the past, which has had

its time, and an inescapable future. Gradually, at the cost of hard

struggle and innumerable sacrifices, the balance tilts towards the

future. At present, after a century-old struggle for economic equality,

after a century of socialist propaganda, we are witnessing a large-scale

attempt at its realisation. It will still know some setbacks,

backtracking, both in its fight against is enemies and in its internal

development, and we shouldn’t believe that we will find ourselves

tomorrow in the anarchist society we wish for. But we can only reach a

better life if we try to get it; experiment is the only way which leads

to it, and there is no other. Instead of asking: are the conditions

ripe? Are the masses ready? We should ask: are we ready? What can we

offer as concrete, practical measures “the day after our victory, in

order to achieve our socialism, communism, by organising outside and

against any state? What are the measures to elaborate, the conditions to

study beforehand?” This is where our main preoccupation must lie; what

we must do is not be overwhelmed by events, but actively prepare

ourselves now, always remembering that an ideal is realisable only

insofar as people believe in its realisation and put their energy to it.

Part 2: The Dictatorship of the Proletariat

The realisation of socialism has left the realm of dreams and

theoretical propaganda; it has approached, and has even become an urgent

matter. And if it is important to answer the question of what methods

lead to this realisation, and are the most likely to gain victory, it is

even more important to get a clear picture of what we need to do after

the victory for the revolution to bring the greatest increase in

happiness, with the least suffering possible.

The “dictatorship of the proletariat” seems attractive to many people

these days. It seems to mean that workers would now be masters of social

life, masters of their own destiny, without exploiters, nor oppressors

above them. It seems to be the direct and immediate realisation of

socialism. In France, especially, where the workers’ movement has not

been penetrated by Marxist theory and terminology, this phrase is the

cause of misunderstandings. It holds in itself a contradiction: a

dictatorship “is always the unlimited power” of one or of a small group;

what could be the dictatorship of a whole class? It is obvious that a

class can only hold power through its representatives, by someone who it

delegated or who, more simply, believes they can act in its name. In the

end, a new power is being established, the power of the socialist party

or of its most influential faction, and this power takes charge of

managing the fate of the working class. And this is not an abuse or a

sophistication of the idea of the “dictatorship of the proletariat”, it

is its essence itself. It follows from Marxist theory, from the way this

theory conceives the evolution of societies. Let’s remind ourselves how

it goes.

By definition, political power is in every period in the hands of the

economically dominant class. The bourgeoisie, after it replaced feudal

powers in the economy, also replaced them politically, at least in the

most advanced countries in Europe and America. Since then the entire

political activity of the bourgeois class aims to safeguard its

interests and strengthen its domination. But then during the economic

development, proletariat takes the place of the bourgeoisie as the class

most apt to develop productive forces; therefore, political power must

also be its. The new state, the proletarian state, will then only be

preoccupied with the interests of that class, which becomes the dominant

class. That is the dictatorship of the proletariat. A natural objection

appears: a dominant class supposes a dominated class; however, economic

exploitation being abolished by the crowning of the most exploited

class, the existence of classes itself becomes impossible. This

contradiction is resolved thanks to the Marxist concept of how a

transformation towards socialism can be operated. It starts with the

socialist party seizing power; what can the socialist government do

then?

Marxist literature is not plentiful when it comes to projections into

the future: social-democrats have too much of a phobia of utopia for

these. But the few things we know about it are enough to let us know

that socialism will have to be realised gradually, over a whole

historical period. During this period, classes will not have ceased to

exist, and capitalist exploitation will not have ended: it will only

have been softened, attenuated in favour of the proletariat. It is now

the class which is protected by the state, while the situation for the

bourgeoisie is made harder and harder. This is how, at the dawn of

Marxism, Marx, in the Communist manifesto, listed the gradual measures

that the socialist government should adopt: (
)

Putting this programme into effect will be done peacefully or violently,

according to the circumstances, and, in any case, thanks to a strong

political power. As it defines political power as “the organised power

of a class towards the oppression of another”, Marxism therefore

envisions, as an ultimate goal, a society which is only a “human

association”, without power. It is a path to anarchy cutting through its

opposite: an all-powerful state.

50 years later, Kautzky2, in the “Social Revolution”, claims that “the

conquest of political power by a class oppressed until then, that is, a

political revolution, constitutes the essential aspect of the social

revolution.”; he then indicates as series of legislative measures aimed

at operating gradually, with or without compensation, the “expropriation

of expropriators”: progressive taxes on income and property,

anti-unemployment measures, nationalisation of transport and of large

estates, etc. What is the possible regime of this “dictatorship of the

proletariat”? A stronger state than ever, since it holds in its hands

the entire economy of the country; it is master of food distribution and

can literally take away bread from any citizen any time it wants. As a

way to stifle any opposition, it is very efficient. Workers are

employees of this state; it is by the state that they must have their

rights recognized. The fight against this gigantic boss becomes very

difficult; strikes become political crimes. Maybe some workers’ control

can be put in place, but it will only work insofar as the boss-state

accepts it. It is possible that workers enjoy, in exchange, other

advantages, political ones, such as exclusive voting rights, for

example, or privileges in product distribution. But, if we think about

it, these advantages are hardly progress, since they bring in their

social life no justice, and only serve to feed some hatreds. Instead of

abolishing the bourgeoisie as a class and placing each bourgeois in a

situation where they could work usefully, they are allowed (be it

‘temporarily’) to live off of others’ work, but they are punished for it

by taking away some things they have a right to as human beings.

The bourgeoisie must be put in a situation where they are unable to hurt

anyone; it must be deprived of its armed forces and everything which

constitutes its economic domination. Repressive measures against

individual bourgeois are unnecessary vengeance. It is also a slippery

slope: you believe you are doing revolutionary work, while you’re not

bringing anything to building a new life. More than that: this civil war

against the interior enemy, as an evil which had been removed, leaving

the root, makes the prestige of the military grow, of the military group

leaders of any kind who are fighting on any side. The fight become

solely an issue of military force. Very naturally, the building of

tomorrow’s society is pushed back to quieter days. But the moment is

gone, the people are tired and the danger of the reaction grows


That is why, to the method of decrees, we oppose, in order to make

socialism a reality, a different method.

The opposition between these two views dates back once again from the

International, from the battle between Marx and Bakunin. It is Bakunin

who, first, proclaimed in his “Policy of the International” that real

socialism differs from “bourgeois socialism” since the first claims that

the revolution must be “a direct and immediate application of full

social liquidation”, while the latter claims that “political

transformation most precede economic transformation”. The faction which

followed the tradition of the federalist International – our faction –

developed and detailed in the following years this idea of direct

economic revolution. In Le Révolté first, then in La Révolte, Kropotkin

showed through historical examples that human progress is achieved

through the spontaneous action of the people and not through the action

of the state; at the same time, he developed a programme for a free

communism, since the principle of “to each according to their needs” was

alone compatible with a society managing itself without a state. He also

showed that the economic revolution cannot be realised little by little

and partially, that this only leads to disorganising the economy without

allowing it to be rebuilt on a new basis; that communist distribution

must be, in the interest of the revolution, started straight after

victory. He opposed the “conquest of bread” to the “conquest of power”

and showed the necessity, for socialists, to find new ways outside of

the old forms.

The whole anarchist movement was inspired by these fundamental ideas.

Their field of action mostly spread from the moment when the workers’

movement in France, which had slowed down after the fall of the Commune,

started getting a revolutionary spirit. Under the influence of F.

Pelloutier first, then of many anarchists who had joined unions, this

great revolutionary syndicalist movement was born which, in the early

20^(th) century, carried within it all the hopes of workers’

emancipation. Syndicalism appropriated the idea of immediately taking

control of production, and it developed it: the organs which are called

to implement it already exist: the trade unions. The general strike,

prelude to expropriation, became the final goal of the CGT. Let’s remind

ourselves that its preparation seemed at some point such an important

and urgent task that La Voix du Peuple opened (around 1902, if I am not

mistaken) a column in which unions were invited to write what each one

would do after the victory in order to ensure continuous production in

their domain, how they would link up with other unions and consumers

etc. This initiative, which didn’t get enough feedback, was of great

importance; it would be even more important to pick it up again now that

we are closer to practical achievements.

That was, from that time until the war, the fundamental character of

revolutionary syndicalism. From France, it reached other countries,

other workers’ movements. Anarcho-syndicalist ideas reached to the

writings of sociologists, lawyers, economists; scientists outside the

workers’ movement started to realise that the renewal of economic life

based on a free association of producers was maybe not simply a utopia,

that it could be the way to overthrow capitalism and inaugurate a new

form of political existence, without the state.

The war put an end to this evolution, and changed the course of events.

The state was suddenly strengthened, its reach extended; workers’

organisations, on the other hand, were slowed in their action or

directed it, because of practical difficulties, towards more immediate

achievements. The reformist element became most important.

The revolutionary spirit reappeared throughout the world with the

Russian revolution, but under a different form: the form of statist

socialism.

The time has not yet come to draw definitive conclusions from the

experiment attempted in Russia; there are many things we don’t know and

it would be hard to evaluate the role of different factors in successes

and failures. But we can say this: what we do know cannot change our

fundamental ideas. We do not intend to develop here all the arguments

which make us think that the government apparatus is inapt to realise a

social revolution, which can only be done by workers’ groups, once they

have become producers’ groups. This demonstration has often been made in

our literature. However, we deem it useful to repeat their general

conclusions.

We believe, as we have always believed, that peasants’ and workers’

organisations taking control of the land and means of production and

managing economic life is more likely to ensure the material well-being

of society than decrees from the government.

We believe that this mode of transformation is better equipped to disarm

conflicts and avoid civil war (because it allows for more freedom and

more variety in forms of organisation) than introducing by authority one

reform across the board.

We believe that the direct participation of the people in building the

new economic forms makes the victories of the revolution more stable and

ensures better their defence.

We believe, finally, that this allows us to prepare, on top of economic

and political victories, a higher stage of civilisation, both

intellectually and morally.

French workers’ communities have inherited enough ideas and experience

of struggles to follow the path which leads more directly to complete

emancipation. To proclaim the fall of capitalism and the reign of

socialism is a great thing, and for that we can thank the Russian

socialist government. But we also wish for socialism to be put in

practice, for a new era for humankind to dawn and for no weapon to be

offered the reaction by the socialists’ faults. For that, we who work on

French soil, we must use effectively the time we have to study what

workers’ organisations can and should do directly after the revolution.

We consider as something of the greatest importance to have the most

serious and most complete discussion possible about the issues of the

economy once the workers have conquered it. This is not a debate, or

propaganda, but a study. We can no longer just say that something is

desirable, nor even try to prove it: we must show practical measures

which can be immediately put into practice with the means we have at our

disposal.

This is the task we call for our comrades to accomplish.

Part 3: Some milestones in economy

The forms which production and distribution will take are at the front

of all our visions of the future: on them will depend the entire

character of the society which replaces the capitalist regime. The

question is not new, but the answer becomes urgent; also, the experience

of the Russian revolution gives us precious information confirming or

contradicting concepts formulated previously in a purely theoretical

fashion.

To resolve these issues concretely, that is, to organise an economic

organisation plan for “the day after”, to indicate the frameworks and

the institutions which must be created to put it into practise, is a

task which goes way beyond the abilities not only of the author of this

article, but in general of such a publication as Les Temps Nouveaux. It

is the work of specialists: workers, technicians of all trades, directly

preoccupied by production; only their professional organisations and

groups can discuss what measures to take, now and in the future,

intelligently. But any socialist, any group of propagandists can and

should establish for themselves and their comrades a general view, to

think about the experience happening in front of their eyes, and to draw

some general lines along which they would want to see the more competent

thoughts of specialists work. Such considerations make up this article.

Among current ideas on the mode of production and organisation of a

socialist society, nationalisation is the most common and accessible.

The society’s take-over of the means of production is conceived in the

programmes of all the state socialist parties as the state taking over,

since society is, by definition, represented by the state. Whatever

forms the state takes, be it parliamentarian, soviet, or other: it is

always the organisation holding political power which is also the owner

of natural resources, means of production and organs of product

distribution.

We can see how much the state is strengthened. As well as political

power, it holds every source of life. The dependence of its subjects

reaches its maximum. The boss-state is a very authoritarian boss, as

they all are. He wants to be master in his own business and does not

tolerate workers’ meddling if he can avoid it. Where the economy is

concerned, the state does not even want to be a constitutional monarch:

it always tends to be an autocrat. Jaurùs’s3 idea: gradual

democratisation, through the state, of the economy, comparable to the

political democratisation operated in the past, appears to be only a

utopia now more than ever. Under capitalism, state employees and workers

are the most dependent of all, and at the other end of the spectrum of

social organisation, in the bolsheviks’ collectivist regime, it is still

the case: workers gradually lose both their rights of control and their

factory committees, even their best means of struggle: their right to

strike. And, on top of all that, they are submitted to mobilisation at

work, to workers’ “armies” ruled with military discipline. And this is a

fatal flaw: no power restricts itself if nothing forces it to, and when

people in power follow an idea, when they are convinced it can only be

realised through coercion, they will behave even more unflinchingly,

even more absolutely in their right to dispose of the citizens’ lives.

It is generally through the need to increase production that suppressing

all workers’ individual and collective rights is justified. This is how

the bolshevik power explains the compulsory work armies. However,

outside any judgement on principle, the issue of the expediture, in

labour and in money, demanded by a large bureaucracy – a necessary

condition for the extension of state power – shows that this calculation

is misguided. In Russia, bureaucratic management of the factories

absorbs most of their revenue, not counting the number of people it

keeps away from useful work. And the results they wished for is far from

being obtained. The boss-state is ill equipped to fight this decrease in

productivity in labour which necessarily follows great catastrophes such

as war, starvation, lack of resources, etc. Also, the socialist

government of the bolsheviks has not found any other solutions to fight

these problems than well-known measures, which have long been fought by

socialists and workers of all countries: piecework, bonus pay system,

Taylorism, etc. This is how across the board, hourly wages become

piecework, 12-hour days replace 8-hour days, the age of compulsory work

has decreased from 16 to 14. And, lastly, this mobilisation of labour (a

measure which, a few years ago, we would have thought any socialist

party incapable of) which reminds us of the time of serfdom.

If socialists, who certainly do not aim to degrade workers and only take

such measures with a heavy heart, find themselves forced to go so far

against all their ideas, it is because in their field of action, which

is exclusively framed by the state and can only use the state, there are

no other solutions. And yet here is a fact, a small fact in itself, but

meaningful. During the harsh struggle led by the soviet government

against disorder in the industry, only one measure was taken which was

efficient. It was voluntary work on Saturdays.

“The Communist Party made it compulsory for its members to join the

Saturday voluntary work scheme
 Every Saturday, in different regions of

the Soviet republic, barks and carriages of fuel are unloaded, rail

tracks repaired, wheat, fuel and other commodities destined to the

people and to the front are loaded, carriages and locomotives are

repaired, etc. Slowly the great mass of workers starts to join the

“Saturday workers”, to help the Soviet government, to contribute through

voluntary work to fight the cold, hunger and general economic

disorder.”4 From other sources we learnt that productivity in voluntary

work far exceeds the productivity of paid work in factories. There is no

need to point out how instructive this example is. Among all the

measures by which workers where either attracted by high wages,

according to the principles of classic capitalism, or submitted to

military discipline, only one proved efficient: the call for free and

conscious work of people who know they are doing something useful. This

is a striking example of the truth that the most “utopian” solutions are

also the most practical, and that if we want to obtain “results”

nowadays, the surest way is still to start from the final goal.

But these considerations proceed from a state of mind foreign to the

idea of the state and of compulsory work in its service.

Here is another formula, at first sight more attractive. It is the

companies being taken over by their workers or their corresponding

industrial organisations. It is the system which, in France, is

expressed by the phrase “the mine to the miners”. During the first year

of the Russian revolution, before even the bolsheviks gained power,

there were a number of examples of this take-over of factories by

workers. It was easy, since the bosses, at that time, wanted nothing

better than leave their companies. Later, bolsheviks introduced

“workers’ control” in every factory, but this control was only a half

measure without practical effect: where the workers were weak and badly

organised, it didn’t have any effect; where they were conscious of their

rights, they claimed – very logically – that they had no need to leave

them to their former owners. And they took them over, claiming them as

property of the people working there. But it was still the ownership of

a group of people replacing the ownership of a single bourgeois person.

This could lead, at most, to a cooperative of production. The collective

owner was only preoccupied – like the bourgeois owner used to be – about

their own interests; like the other, they tried to get orders from the

state, etc. Selfishness and greed, although they were now shared among a

group, were still no less strong.

Another consideration, a practical one this time, makes impossible the

extension of such a system to the entire society. There are some

companies which make a lot of profit: those which produce widely

consumed goods, or transport companies; the workers there who become

owners are, in this sense, privileged. But there are many others which

make no profit at all, although they demand continuous spending:

schools, hospitals, road repairs, street cleaning, etc. What would be

the situation of people employed in those branches? What would they live

off if those companies became their property? What means would they use

to keep them working and who would pay their wages? Obviously, the

principle of workers’ ownership must be modified for them. We can

imagine, it’s true, that consumers would pay; but this would be a step

back instead of progress, since one of the best results of economic

development is the fact that some conquests of civilisation are free:

hospitals, schools, bridges, water pipes, wells, and a few other things.

Making them a paid-for service would be adding a few new privileges to

the owners and taking away from the non-owners ways to fulfil most

essential needs.

All the considerations – and a few others – make such a system not very

desirable. In the Russian practice – to which we must always look as the

only socialist experiment made at present – the disadvantages of this

system, introduced from the start of the bolshevik era, pushed the

soviet government to adopt, as the only solution, nationalisation.

A third way should have been sought, by going along a very different

path; but bolsheviks were too infused with social-democratic and statist

ideas for that, which only pointed to the well-known system of

nationalisation. And this is what they chose.

Let’s try, for our part, to look for this third way: a regime which

would give the workers the management of economic life, but without the

disadvantages of industrial ownership. And, first of all, let’s get back

to our fundamental principle: our communism, real communism and not this

1848 communism, already outdated, which bolsheviks recently rediscovered

and which they adopted as a name for their party to dispose of the name

“social-democrat”, which was too dishonoured by compromises. Let’s try,

in the light of this principle, to examine a bit more clearly the issues

at hand.

If we do not recognise the nationalisation in the hands of the state nor

the formula “the mine to the miners”, what form can this take-over of

the means of production by the workers’ organisations (unions, soviets,

factory committees or others) take?

First of all, the means of production cannot become the property of

these organisations: they must only have the use of them. The wind or

the water which make the blades or the wheel of a mill turn are no-one’s

property; they are only used for work. In the same way, land must be

no-one’s property; the people who cultivate it use it, but it belongs to

the collectivity, that is, no-one in particular. In the same way, work

instruments built by human hands: they are common property, or

collective wealth, used by those who use them at some given time. How,

this being accepted, can we envision first the organisation of

production, then the organisation of distribution?

Obviously, only the sum of concerned industrial organisations can manage

a branch of production; these professional organisations will group

indiscriminately the workers themselves and more knowledgeable

specialists – engineers, scientists, etc. Each branch of production is

closely linked on the one hand with the branches which give it raw

materials, and on the other with the organisations or the public who

consume its products. And, since, in these relationships, the most

important role is to know the needs and possibilities, there must be

some groups, committees who will concentrate the necessary statistical

teachings. Their role must be strictly limited to that of purveyors of

statistical data; the use which will then be made of this data does not

concern them. They cannot emit any decree; the decisions belong solely

to the professional organisations. The advice of these statistical

committees is no more coercive than the information given by an

architect, the advice of a dietician, a teacher, etc. As for the

different branches of production, the modes of organisation can be very

varied depending on the technical peculiarities of each one: some can

admit a complete autonomy of particular groups, others can demand a

perfectly coordinated action of all. All that is desired is that there

is, in each speciality, not just one central organisation managing

everything, but a large number of specialised organisations, with

clearly delimited tasks. We cannot, obviously, predict the different

modalities that this organisation of work might offer. Adapting it to

current needs might not be an exceedingly difficult task.

But there are more difficult questions, which demand continuous

innovation, since nothing similar has ever been attempted. Who would be

the owner of these means of production, which will be managed by the

workers’ organisations, and of the objects produced, that is, of all

collective wealth? If it is neither the state nor the industrial

branches, then who? What does the sentence “the means of production

belong to the collectivity” represent concretely? Who will represent

this collectivity? Who will dispose of the products and on what ground?

Who will gain profit from their sale? Who will pay wages?

This is when we must have our communist idea in mind, our great

principle “from each according to their ability, to each according to

their needs”, and draw all the conclusions from it.

“Who will dispose of the produce of labour?” These products must

constitute collective wealth offered for everyone to consume, if they

are immediately consumable goods, or offered for the workers’

organisation to use (if they are raw materials or tools). Individuals or

organisations will draw from these stocks as they need them, and, in

case of insufficient quantities, after an agreement with other consumers

and interested organisations. No-one truly owns these products, except

the workers in distribution who will try to satisfy orders.

In the same way, the question “who would get the profit from the sale?”

is answered. There will be no profit, because there would be no sale,

because products are not commodities, but only consumable goods, equally

accessible to all. Communism does not recognise the distinction between

consumable goods – private property – and the means of production –

collective property. It doesn’t even recognise between those any

difference in nature; coal, for example, which is it? It is an

indispensable element in production, and it also is one of the most

needed objects of individual consumption. The aim in communism is to

make everything free. Everyone will recognize that housing, food,

necessary clothes, heating, etc. must be available to all in the same

way as medical care or street lighting, which are even offered in

capitalist society. Any human being is entitled to these first necessity

objects by the mere fact of their existence, and no-one can deprive them

of those. The individual part in social consumption can be determined by

many individual and social factors: first, by the needs of each person

for everything that is abundant; alas! in modern Europe, instead of an

abundance of products, there are shortages, and this will have to be

noted. A necessary minimum (calculated as much as possible on average

consumption in normal times) will have to be established and rationing

put in place, of a common accord. Rations can and must be different

according to categories of people. These categories should be based in

the difference in needs; age would have to be taken into account, as

well as health, endurance, etc. Many considerations will have to be

envisioned, also, in the distribution of products: the needs of the

community, the need to make reserves for the future and to keep some for

exchanges with other communities, etc. There is only one factor we

refuse to take into account in these calculations: it is the amount of

work expended by each individual.

We can hear some protests. The spectacle of today’s society, where those

who produce less consume more, revolts our sense of justice and makes us

say first of all: everything to labour and to each proportionally to the

work done.

But, despite this natural tendency, we think that it is not along this

principle – as legitimate as it appears compared to the obvious

injustice of our time – that must be founded the future society.

Vengeance exercised by the people against their oppressors at the time

of the revolution is fair, too, but it is not on this vengeance that the

reign of the people can be based after the victory, but on human

solidarity. The same goes for issues of distribution. And let no-one

tell us that we first need to repress the bourgeoisie and that the

victory of the working class must first lead to a mode of distribution

which puts labour in the place it deserves. The class struggle ends with

the workers’ victory and the distinction between workers and parasites

no longer exists. The possibility of free work in a free society is

given to all, and the number of people who refuse it will be so small

that it will not be sufficient to create a new class of parasites under

the form of a large caste of bureaucrats, and in the next generation the

traces of the old parasitism will have disappeared.

To give to each proportionally to their work is, if you wish, a fair

principle; but it is a lower type of justice, like the idea of rewarding

merit or punishing vice. We won’t go into details about all the

philosophical reasons which make us reject this. What would we be adding

to the arguments which P. Kropotkin gave when he laid the foundation of

anarchist communism? Let’s just say that – for the comrades you wouldn’t

know this – at the other end of socialist thought, Marx accepted the

same views when he said that only when retribution for work will have

been replaced by distribution according to everyone’s needs “can the

narrow horizon of bourgeois right be crossed in its entirety”5. We

precisely want to go beyond bourgeois rights and bourgeois-inspired

justice. Every one is entitled to their existence simply in virtue of

being human. Then, and also because they are human, a living being

living in a society, they will apply themselves to do their share of

work for the common good. This is the only possible guarantee against a

new form of exploitation and endless conflicts.

We reject therefore the idea itself of a wage; we dissociate the two

issues of production and of consumption, leaving between them only the

link which results from the fact that the total quantity of produced

goods must be indexed on the consumption needs. This is the only order

of things compatible with a regime in which workers’ organisations

manage production without being the owners of the means of production.

It is also the only one compatible with a free society, freed from the

coercive power of a state.

We do not hope, obviously, that, as soon as the next day after the

revolution, everything will fall into place nicely without conflict,

without a mixture of bourgeois elements from the past. We know that it

is very unlikely that this communism, complete and pure, could be

realised in one fell swoop. But we also know that it is to the extent

that the builders of the future will be inspired by it that their work

will be fruitful. That is why it appears so important, so infinitely

desirable, that this is the spirit in which the milestones of the future

are laid.