💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › david-graeber-neoliberalism.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 09:06:38. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: Neoliberalism
Author: David Graeber
Date: 2009
Language: en
Topics: neoliberalism, bureaucracy
Source: Retrieved on 28th November 2021 from https://davidgraeber.org/articles/neoveralism-or-the-beuracratizatiom-of-the-world/
Notes: Chapter 4 of The Insecure American: How We Got Here and What We Should Do about It, edited by Hugh Gusterson and Catherine Besteman, University of California Press, 2009.

David Graeber

Neoliberalism

Americans often find it difficult to talk about politics with people

from other parts of the world. Consider three quotes culled, more or

less at random, from world newswires around the end of December 2005. In

Bolivia, newly elected president Evo Morales declared that in his

victory “the people have defeated the neoliberals.” “We want to change

the neoliberal model,” he added. In Germany, Lothar Bisky announced the

creation of a new political party that, he hoped, would “contribute to

creating a democratic alternative to oppose the damage caused by

neoliberalism to social cohesion.” Around the same time, a pan-African

Web journal announced a special issue whose articles “reflect a growing

debate on economic alternatives to neoliberalism from countries as far

afield as Mauritius, Swaziland and Mali.”[1]

These are just three: I could easily have chosen dozens of them. Across

most of the planet, neoliberalismis a household word. Arguments about

neoliberalism form the stuff of everyday political conversation.

Politicians are accused of being neoliberals or pursuing neoliberal

agendas; opposition candidates get elected by running against

neoliberalism (then, often as not, are accused by their former

supporters of caving in to it). Neoliberalism is seen as the dominant

ideological force in the world, an attempt by the United States, as the

world’s sole remaining superpower, to extend its own social and economic

model to the rest of the world. Some say it is inevitable, even

desirable; others organize against it. But almost everyone has an

opinion on the matter.

In the United States, few have ever heard of it. Mention the word to

almost anyone but an academic or international affairs correspondent,

and you are likely to be met with empty stares. If you want to talk

about the same issues, in fact, you are forced to rely on obvious

propaganda terms like free trade, free-market reforms, or globalization.

The bias in the first two is pretty obvious. You don’t put the word free

in front of a name if you’re trying to be neutral about it.

Globalization is only slightly more subtle. When you call something

“neoliberalism” you are saying that this is a set of ideas, simply one

theory among many about the best way to organize an economy.

“Globalization,” in contrast, is always treated as something inevitable.

There’s not much point in having an opinion about whether the sun will

rise tomorrow, argues Thomas Friedman, probably the most prominent

American advocate of neoliberalism (which of course he never refers to

by name): one simply accepts it as reality and tries to make the best of

it.[2] Globalization just somehow happened. No one is really

responsible. Perhaps it had something to do with the Internet. At any

rate, now we all have no choice but to adapt.

From the point of view of those who feel neoliberalism is simply a

matter of the United States imposing its own model on the rest of the

world, all of this is exactly what one would expect. To be fair, though,

there are many more innocent reasons why most Americans would find the

term neoliberalism confusing. In the United States, political language

has developed very differently than it has in the rest of the world. For

example, in the nineteenth century, the word liberal was applied to

people who believed in individual liberty, which they saw as founded on

private property rights. These “classical liberals,” as they are

sometimes called, tended to reject government interference in the

economy as much as in personal affairs. This is still what

liberalimplies in most of the world. But in the United States, over the

course of the twentieth century, the term was adopted by the moderate

Left until it came to mean something like “social democrat.” Starting in

the 1980s the Right responded by turning the word liberalinto a term of

opprobrium: liberalbecame, in the minds of many working-class Americans,

a designator for latte-sipping cultural elitists, “tax-andspend”

politicians, proponents of gay marriage, and similar bĂŞte noires.

Meanwhile, free-market enthusiasts—the sort of people who elsewhere in

the world are referred to as “liberals”—began casting about for a new

name. The one they ended up fixing on was libertarian—a term they

borrowed from the Left. The result is that it is even more difficult for

Americans to talk to anyone else about politics, since, in the rest of

the world, libertarian still largely retains its traditional meaning as

a synonym for anarchist. In Europe or South America, it is perfectly

unremarkable to talk about “libertarian communism”—referring by this to

the idea that states should be dismantled and control over economic life

placed in the hands of democratically organized communities. Use a term

like that in front of the average U.S. citizen, and he will assume that

you are one of those annoying people who like to confuse others with

intentional oxymorons—or perhaps that you are insane.

It is never a good thing when people cannot talk to each other, and it

seems particularly unfortunate right now, when so many Americans seem

confused about the widespread anger about their role in the world. In

the press, opposition to neoliberalism—particularly in Latin America—is

often referred to as “anti-Americanism,” as if neoliberalism really were

simply identical to the American way of life. In fact it is nothing of

the kind. Indeed, a case could well be made that the majority of

Americans reject its core ideas and institutions and that Americans have

actually been the first historic victims of neoliberal

“reforms”—policies that are the ultimate cause of many of the

insecurities described in this volume. Certainly, Americans have also

played a prominent role in the growing global movement against

neoliberalism.

As the above suggests, I am not making any claim to neutrality here. I

think it is fair to say that anyone speaking of the roots of global

poverty or the nature of capitalism who claims to be providing an

“objective” or “scientific” account is either extraordinarily naive or

trying to sell you something. It seems more honest to simply reveal

one’s biases and let the reader take it from there. For over six years I

have been deeply involved in a global movement against neoliberalism,

whose overall effects, I feel, have been an unmitigated catastrophe.

What follows, then, are a series of efforts to conceptualize the present

historical situation, at a time when, across the world, thoughtful

people are increasingly trying to imagine a way out.

THE ROOTS OF NEOLIBERALISM

Neoliberalism as an economic and political theory is based on a few

relatively simple assumptions. A minimal sketch might run like this:

are not competent to run large industrial and commercial enterprises; in

fact, private firms operating in pursuit of profit in a market

environment can always be expected to do a better job providing public

services than public institutions. Government should therefore restrict

itself to providing a legal environment in which it is easy for private

firms to do this and maintaining necessary infrastructure.

protectionist policies need to be abandoned; rather than trying to

develop autonomously, each nation should pursue its particular

“competitive advantage” (whatever this may be: cheap labor, an educated

workforce, natural resources) in a single global marketplace.

supports for basic foodstuffs, provision of free medical services, or

guaranteed pension funds, are ultimately They should be pared back or

eliminated, since they distort the workings of the market. Instead, if

governments limit spending so as to maintain balanced budgets to

guarantee the stability of their currency, they will create a market

environment favorable to foreign investment, and the market itself will

provide better solutions to these problems.

Since 1980, almost every country in the world has adopted some version

of neoliberal reforms. Only exceptionally, however, did they do so

because politicians got elected by promising to do so. Arguably the

first neoliberal experiment was carried out in the mid-1970s by General

Augusto Pinochet in Chile after he had overthrown an elected government

in a military coup. Most reforms, however, were carried out not by force

of arms but by what might be termed fiscal coercion.

The real paradigm here, as David Harvey notes, was New York City’s

financial crisis that began in 1975.[3] It is worth considering in some

detail. The crisis began with the city teetering on the edge of fiscal

default. After the federal government refused to provide a bailout and

investment bankers refused to roll over the debt, New York was driven to

technical bankruptcy. Creditors then proceeded to form what they called

the Municipal Assistance Corporation, an entity independent of the city

government and hence unaccountable to voters, that as a condition of

rescuing the city began to remake its political landscape. One must bear

in mind that at the time New York was a kind of enclave of social

democracy in America. It had not only the most extensive rent control in

the country but America’s most unionized workforce and most extensive

public services and even maintained its only free public university. In

the name of balancing the budget, the MAC broke the power of the

municipal unions, slashed services, rolled back pensions and job

security, offered enormous tax cuts to business and developers, and

began to restructure the very shape of city government.

Gone first of all was any pretense that city government existed equally

for all its citizens. Rather, the city was a product to be marketed.

Logos and jingles were invented (the Big Apple; I Love New York). As the

city center was rebuilt as a glittering advertisement for itself, the

poor were to be pushed out of sight of potential tourists and investors.

The calculated withdrawal of fire crews allowed peripheral neighborhoods

like the South Bronx and East New York to descend into burnt-out

wastelands; infrastructure like subways, crucial to the working class in

the outer boroughs, was allowed to crumble; CUNY was compelled to charge

tuition; at the same time, city government poured money into supporting

gentrification campaigns and the creation of a new telecommunications

infrastructure in the city center aimed at creating a better “business

climate” for investors.

New York in the late 1970s and early 1980s normally evokes images of

hedonistic yuppies sniffing cocaine at Studio 54, or, alternately,

images of urban decay: graffiti, crack houses, the epidemic of

homelessness that at the time inspired comparisons with Calcutta or

Bombay. The increasing divisions between rich and poor that made these

images possible were not, as apologists often claimed, the inevitable

results of deindustrialization and the growth of the communications or

service industry. They were the product of policy decisions that New

Yorkers as a whole had not and would never have collectively chosen,

that were, effectively, imposed on them by financiers philosophically

opposed to the very idea of public goods. The gradual result, however,

was the emergence of what might be called a neoliberal ethic:

simultaneous emphases on personal self-realization for the affluent and

“personal responsibility” for the poor. Both seemed to rely on the

rejection of any notion that democracy implies some common dedication to

a community (let alone that community members should therefore be

guaranteed access to those minimal needs, food, shelter, and free time,

that would allow them to participate in a community’s democratic life).

Margaret Thatcher, who was one of the few politicians to state it

explicitly, put it most succinctly: “There is no such thing,” she said,

“as society.” There are individuals, and families, and the outcome of

their independent self-interested decisions isdemocratic choice. If

community was to be evoked, it was—as in the “I Love New York”

campaign—just another sales gimmick, since, after all, in the neoliberal

universe, reality itself is simply whatever you can sell. The same sense

of fragmented individuals left with nothing but their own capacities for

self-marketing echoed on every level of the emerging culture of the

time, from the savvy postmodernism of New York’s art scene to the

endless subdivision of consumer identities identified and targeted by

its advertising agencies.

Not only does the history of New York show that politicians can rarely

get elected running against community;[4] it also shows that, once the

process of social triage is already accepted as a fait accompli,

politicians can often quite readily win elections on law-and-order

tickets, promising to protect middleand working-class citizens from the

chaos and violence that such policies invariably unleash. In New York,

the election of Rudy Giuliani in the 1990s was only the culmination of a

long degeneration of politics into an obsession with violence and

crime—essentially, with cleaning up the mess made in the 1970s. The

pattern was to be reproduced worldwide, again and again, in city after

city.

In the 1980s, the Third World debt crisis allowed the Reagan regime to

begin applying the same model on a global scale. The origins of that

debt crisis go back to the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting

Countries (OPEC) oil embargo of the late 1970s. Essentially, what

happened was that with the spike in oil prices OPEC countries were

suddenly awash in so much money that Western banks (in which they

invested it) soon ran out of anyone willing to borrow it. The result was

a period of “go-go banking,” with bank representatives jet-setting about

the world aggressively trying to convince Third World leaders to accept

high-interest loans based on wild projections of the economic bonanzas

that would follow. A large amount of this money was simply stolen; much

of the rest was invested in ill-conceived grandiose projects (such as

the enormous dams the World Bank became so famous for) that were later

used to showcase the foolishness of the very idea of governmentsponsored

development. Needless to say, within a few years many of the poorer

nations themselves teetered on the brink of default. It was at this

point that the U.S. Treasury, working closely with the International

Monetary Fund (IMF), fixed on a policy that under no circumstances were

such debts to be written off.[5] This was, I should note, a major

departure from previous economic orthodoxy, which took it for granted

that those who lend money are assuming a certain risk. It showcases, in

fact, a crucial element of neoliberalism: that, while the poor are to be

held accountable for poor economic decisions (real or imagined), the

rich must never be. In practical effect, it meant that even if a banker

were to lend a hundred million dollars to a corrupt dictator, knowing

full well that he was likely to place the sum directly in his personal

Swiss bank account, and even if that dictator were to be subsequently

ousted by a popular uprising, he could rest assured that the full

apparatus of world government and financial institutions would lock into

step to insist the money could still be recovered—at generous rates of

interest—from the dictator’s former victims. If thousands therefore had

to starve, so be it.

The innovation was not just insisting on the inviolability of debt but,

as in New York, using it as a political instrument.[6] Loans soon became

unpayable; the terms had to be refinanced. Before the IMF was willing to

do so, however, governments had to agree to undergo what were called

“structural adjustment programs” designed by neoliberal economists.

Their first priority was always to balance the budget, ostensibly so as

to create a stable currency and a favorable climate for investment. This

was to be done primarily by slashing social services, most dramatically

by the removal of price supports on fuel or basic foodstuffs, or the

imposition of “users’ fees” for previously free services like health

clinics and primary education. This was to be accompanied by selling off

public resources and fully opening the local market to foreign trade and

investment. As one might imagine, these policies inspired constant

rebellions on the part of the urban poor, but governments were able to

say they had no choice. They were right. On the few occasions when

leaders of poor countries outright refused to sign an IMF agreement— for

instance, Madagascar’s President Albert Zafy in the early 1990s—they

soon discovered that in the absence of one all other countries would

shut off foreign aid; without aid, private capital pulled out; without

insurance credits, it was not even possible to export products. The

effects were—at least in terms of purely economic devastation—roughly

comparable to what might have been achieved by a minor nuclear

attack.[7]

The 1980s and 1990s were, of course, the very period when, in much of

Europe, Africa, and the Americas, dictatorships were being replaced by

elected governments. Voters quickly discovered, however, that their

choices had next to no effect on economic policy, since the levers of

economic decision were simultaneously being removed from the hands of

governments and passed to unelected, and unaccountable, neoliberal

technocrats. This did not happen just through debt. Another leitmotif of

the era has been the passing of jurisdiction over economic matters to

bodies meant to enforce trade agreements: the signing of the North

American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), in 1994, for instance, committed

Mexico to make major constitutional changes—notably, abolishing all

forms of communal land tenure, including the collective ejidosthat were

one of the main legacies of the revolution— without the matter ever

coming up before the electorate.[8] In Europe, European Union agreements

played a similar role, forcing governments to eliminate social

protections and institute “flexible” labor regimes in the name of

balancing the budget, so as to maintain the stability of Europe’s new

common currency. This was soon followed by the expansion of similar

trade agreements—the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), then

the World Trade Organization (WTO)— worldwide. In each case appointed

bodies of bureaucrats were empowered to strike down laws that were

deemed overly protectionist, including laws designed to protect working

conditions or the environment.

Perhaps the most dramatic case, though, was that of Eastern and Central

Europe. Surveys taken immediately after the fall of communism in 1989

and 1991 revealed that in pretty much every case most citizens preferred

to see the creation of some kind of Scandinavian-style social welfare

state, with substantial minorities in favor of the maintenance of

socialism and almost no one in favor of instituting a pure free-market

model. Yet as soon as elected governments were in place, they uniformly

began administering “shock therapy” programs designed abroad to

institute exactly that, as quickly as possible. It was all the more

striking since these states were not, for the most part, burdened with

substantial debt. By that time, it had apparently become impossible to

fully integrate with the world economy on any other terms.[9]

In fact, by the 1990s one can genuinely speak of a system of global

governance operating on neoliberal lines. Imagine it as consisting in a

series of tiers. On the top are the money traders. One of the great

innovations of recent decades is the enormous efflorescence of finance

capital: at this point, over 90 percent of economic transactions in what

is called the global marketplace no longer have any immediate connection

with manufacturing or trading commodities of any kind but consist simply

of currency trading and other forms of financial speculation. This acts

as an enormous disciplining mechanism, since the “electronic herd,” as

Thomas Friedman likes to call them, can instantly pull money out of

“emerging markets” seen as betraying neoliberal orthodoxy. The effects

of such a currency run can be, again, near-nuclear in their

implications. Next are transnational corporations, whose incomes are

often far larger than the GDPs of most actual countries. During the

1980s and 1990s, thousands of formerly independent enterprises—from

newspapers to department stores to construction companies—have been

absorbed into gigantic conglomerates organized on bureaucratic lines.

Next are the various trade bureaucracies—the IMF, the WTO, the EU, the

Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN), NAFTA, the various

Reserve Banks, and so on, whose economists regularly evoke the threat of

the financiers to insist on policies amenable to the transnationals.

Finally, one has the endless elaboration of nongovernmental

organizations (NGOs), which have come to provide services—from childhood

inoculations to the provision of agricultural credits—previously

considered the work of national governments.

All of these tiers—including the huge brokerage houses and hedge funds

that conduct most of the world’s financial trading—together constitute a

single huge, de facto, administrative system. It is the first

administrative system in human history that actually has the power to

enforce decisions on a planetary scale, since, after all, no empire has

ever spanned the entire world, and the UN, the first genuinely global

institution, never had more than moral authority. There is of course a

word for large, hierarchically organized administrative systems. They

are called bureaucracies. Certainly, most of those operating within this

new administrative system do not like to think of themselves as

bureaucrats. And certainly, these organizations tend to operate in a far

more decentralized and flexible style than the government bureaucracies

they aimed to (largely) supersede.[10] But it is only to be expected

that a planetwide trade bureaucracy would be organized differently than

those with which we are most familiar. The remarkable thing is that it

has been so effective in imposing its dictates that most of those

inhabiting the richer countries are effectively unaware of its

existence.

THE BALANCE BOOK

Supporters of neoliberal reforms were usually perfectly willing to admit

that their prescriptions were, as they often put it, “harsh medicine” or

that the effects would, at least initially, be “painful.” The

justification was—it was Margaret Thatcher again who put it most

succinctly—that “there is no alternative.” Socialist solutions having

failed, and global competition being what it was, there was simply no

other way. “Capitalism” (by implication, neoliberal capitalism) had been

proven “the only thing that works.” The phrase itself is significant,

since it shows how thoroughly we have come to see states and societies

as business enterprises; it rarely seemed to occur to anyone to ask,

“Works to do what?” Nevertheless, even if neoliberalism is judged in its

own terms—in which success is measured almost exclusively by economic

growth—it has proved, on a global scale, remarkably unsuccessful.

Remember here that “free-market reforms” were supposed to be a reaction

to the shortcomings of the state-sponsored development strategies of the

1960s and 1970s. Here numbers are available. In the 1960s and 1970s,

global growth rates averaged 3.5 percent and 2.4 percent per year,

respectively. During the period of neoliberal reforms in the1980s that

number fell to 1.4 percent, and during the neoliberal “Washington

consensus” of the 1990s it fell to 1.1 percent.[11] The effects were

even more dramatic in the countries of the developing world, which were

supposed to be the greatest beneficiaries of “free trade.” If one

excludes China,[12] the first two decades saw an overall 3.2 percent per

year per capita growth in real domestic product in the global

South—higher, in fact, than the global average at that time. During the

neoliberal era (1981–99) this fell to 0.7 percent.[13] Many economies

actually shrank. What’s more, low rates of growth were almost invariably

accompanied by increasingly unequal distribution. As national elites

established themselves in the glittering metropolises of global cities

or locked themselves away in Ethernet-wired gated communities,

governments abandoned any commitment to policies once meant to ensure a

minimal degree of social protection to all their citizens. The effect

was, as in New York, a kind of social triage, with government’s role

largely to sweep the poor or newly impoverished away and keep them out

of sight, while international NGOs attempted to limit the damage. Taken

on a world scale, overall social indicators like literacy rates and life

expectancy declined dramatically.[14]

If this is not general knowledge, it is partly because proponents of

neoliberalism never talk about the big picture. It is in the nature of

the global market that there are winners and losers, they say; then they

try to demonstrate that the winners are those that followed their advice

most closely. Hence Lithuania is doing better than Russia, Uganda than

Angola, Chile than Brazil. Even this usually requires a fair amount of

cooking the books. In the 1980s, for example, reformers liked to point

to the success of the “Asian Tigers” like South Korea and Taiwan. This

required soft-pedaling the fact that both had actually relied on heavy

tariffs, massive government investment in public education, and even

government-directed industrial five-year plans—basically, exactly the

opposite of what neoliberals were recommending. In Europe, Great

Britain, easily the most assiduous in carrying out freemarket reforms,

now has living standards lower than Ireland’s, while Finland, which of

all European countries has the largest share of its economy dedicated to

social welfare programs, has, according to the World Economic Forum, now

replaced the United States as the most economically competitive nation

on earth.[15] At the same time, the two great winners in the world

economy during the last decade, the United States and the People’s

Republic of China, are those in a position to most systematically ignore

the advice of the IMF. It is little known in the United States, for

example, that every year the IMF chastises the U.S. government for its

massive budget deficits and demands the slashing of tariffs and farm

subsidies. The government simply ignores it, since in the United States

the IMF lacks any means of enforcement.[16] China, as the United States’

largest creditor, has also managed to avoid almost all of the

“discipline” applied to other developing countries: if it were in the

same position as, say, Brazil, it would never have been allowed to

maintain policies like extending endless credit for the building of

industrial infrastructure, let alone systematically ignoring foreign

patents and copyrights—policies that have been, arguably, the keystones

of China’s spectacular economic success.

IMF economists are of course aware of the disastrous effects that so

often seem to follow when countries adopt their policy recommendations.

Their reaction is always the same: such countries had not gone far

enough. Even harsher medicine is required.

As the Filipino economist Walden Bello remarks, this is at the very

least somewhat puzzling. Most of these economists have worked

extensively with the private sector. They are aware that if a private

firm hires a consultant to recommend an economic strategy, and the

strategy recommended fails completely to reach its stated objectives,

that consultant can normally expect to be fired. At the very least he

will be expected to come up with a different strategy. When those same

economists insist that countries like Uruguay or Mali pursue the same

policies year after year for decades without seeing any significant

positive effects, one has to wonder if the best interests of Uruguay or

Mali are really foremost in their minds.[17] Certainly many in Uruguay

and Mali concluded from quite early on that this was not the case.

There has been a great deal of speculation on this account. David Harvey

has noted that neoliberalism, however ineffective as a strategy for

global prosperity, has proved remarkably effective in solidifying class

power—a power that had been widely threatened by revolutionary and

democratic movements in the 1970s. (To this I would add, the greatest

beneficiaries of neoliberal policies have been the staff of the emerging

administrative apparatus itself.) Bello himself makes a similar

argument, but in geopolitical terms. By the end of the 1970s, countries

like Brazil were indeed emerging as significant industrial powers, and

the general economic position of the South was advancing so quickly that

its political representatives in the nonaligned movement were beginning

to demand changes in the very structure of the global economy. The OPEC

oil embargo was only the most dramatic manifestation of this general

flexing of new economic muscles. If so, structural adjustment has proven

extremely effective in blunting the offensive and turning many countries

of the South into impoverished suppliants. This perspective, however,

raises the intriguing question of the degree to which the United States

was, through neoliberal policies, simply postponing the inevitable. This

is the view, in turn, of Immanuel Wallerstein, who points out that if

one peeks behind the virtual universe of finance capital one discovers

that American economic power relative to the rest of the world has been

declining continually since at least the 1960s. The main reason, he

argues, is low overall productivity. While the United States appears on

paper to have the most productive workforce in the world, this is

because statistics measure the productivity only of wage laborers—who in

the United States are squeezed more than almost anywhere—and never of

managers. To put it crudely: in the United States, it takes two or three

executives to do the work done by one in Europe or East Asia, and U.S.

executives demand to be paid five or six times more. One of the main

effects of U.S.-promoted neoliberal reforms around the world, according

to Wallerstein, has been to encourage the creation of a similarly

parasitical executive class in other countries, with the effect of at

least slowing down the rate at which the rest of the world is overtaking

it. The rapid rise of India and China suggest this game might soon be

up.[18]

NEOLIBERALISM AS PHILOSOPHY

We are left with a paradox. How did a philosophy of radical

individualism become the justification for creating the world’s first

global administrative bureaucracy? Here I think we have to return to the

nineteenth century. If old and new liberalism have anything in common,

it is first, that both saw human freedom largely as the ability to enjoy

one’s personal property, and second, that both nonetheless saw

themselves as progressive, even revolutionary forces in human history.

Let us consider briefly the political context of such claims. When,

during the Putney debates in 1647, radical factions in Cromwell’s army

argued that “every man by nature [is] a king, priest and prophet in his

own natural circuit and compass,” the sole proprietor of his own person

and possessions “on which none could trespass,” even the government,

this was a very radical claim.[19] Two hundred years later, it was

distinctly less so. By that time, workers’ movements were beginning to

level a fundamental challenge against the political power of private

wealth. Liberals, on the other hand, were that fraction of the Left most

likely to defend private wealth and particularly market economies.

This is not to say that nineteenth-century liberals were not, as they

generally claimed, radicals and even leftists. Most were honest

opponents of slavery and militarism, proponents of individual rights and

universal suffrage. Free-market enthusiasts, they also tended to follow

Adam Smith in seeing large chartered companies as government-imposed

monopolies and restraints on genuine economic competition. The liberal

ideal was of a world of autonomous individuals or small family firms

buying and selling their wares on a global market. If most looked with

favor on the British Empire of their day, it was because that empire

did, to a certain degree, put these ideals into practice. For example,

though it used force of arms to open markets, it refused all forms of

protectionism at home. Since chartered monopolies like the East India

Company had been dismantled at the beginning of the century, British

capitalism of that time actually was largely a matter of relatively

small family firms. Finally, for all the depredations of the industrial

revolution, liberals were able to see even wage labor as progress in the

direction of freedom when compared with the slavery, debt peonage, and

forced and bonded labor on which capitalists had largely depended up to

that point, and on which, globally, to some degree they always have

depended and still do depend.

American capitalism began even closer to the liberal ideal than British,

but by the 1870s and 1880s it had begun to take a very different

direction. Its key innovation was the creation of the modern joint-stock

corporation. Corporate charters— which potentially allowed joint-stock

companies with thousands of employees to be treated, for legal purposes,

as individual persons—had for most of the nineteenth century been

considered privileges granted by local governments to local businessmen

in a position to afford them some specific public service, such as

building a canal or railroad. By the 1880s and 1890s, corporations not

only had attained permanent status but had come to dominate the national

economy. In the twentieth century, America led the way in creating

transnational corporations that effectively spanned the world. As

Giovanni Arrighi notes, when the United States replaced Great Britain as

the dominant world power, it brought its own, bureaucratic, form of

capitalism.[20] The torch was formally passed after World War II, and

one of President Roosevelt’s first acts at the time was to create the

original framework for what I have called the emerging global

bureaucracy. These came to be known as the Bretton Woods institutions,

after the ski resort in New Hampshire where the conference was held at

which they were created: the IMF, the World Bank, and the GATT, ancestor

of the WTO. Technically under the legal umbrella of the newly created

United Nations, they soon came to overshadow it as an effective system

of global administration.[21] Arrighi also notes that unlike Great

Britain, the United States at its most powerful was never particularly

committed to free trade. It never opened its home markets in the way

that England had. Even today, roughly a third of all transactions

counted as “international trade” under the American aegis are not trade

at all but simply transfers between different branches of corporations

that, in their internal organization, are often barely distinguishable

from enterprises in the old Soviet Union.[22]

So how does the second wave of liberalism fit in? It seems to me it can

be understood only in the light of what Wallerstein calls “the world

revolution of 1968.” The riots, uprisings, and campus revolts that shook

the industrialized world in the late 1960s were rebellions against

capitalism but equally against the welfare states with which capitalists

were then allied. They also tended to declare a complete break with both

the “respectable” Marxist opposition and Leninist regimes of the day.

The rebels of May 1968 in Paris wanted nothing to do with the French

Communist Party; theirs was a revolt in the name of individual

liberation, pleasure, and self-expression against every sort of stifling

social convention and bureaucratic constraint. And the same was true of

the spirit of 1968 in America as well. It hardly seems coincidental that

neoliberalism became the dominant ideology at precisely the moment when

the generation that attended college in the late 1960s began to come to

institutional power. As an ideology, it appears designed to do exactly

what the liberalism of the nineteenth century had done: to recuperate

revolutionary energies, ideas, even revolutionary language, for

capitalism.

Probably the best example here is the history of the word capitalism

itself. A key element in neoliberal rhetoric has been the idea that

capitalism is, itself, a revolutionary force. This kind of language is

actually quite new—at least, coming from capitalists. Capitalists have

historically never used the word capitalism at all, preferring terms

like free enterprise, entrepreneurialism, private enterprise, or

economic freedom. Capitalismwas a term employed almost exclusively by

its critics to describe what they saw as a sordid economic reality, one

where productive wealth was controlled by the few for their own benefit.

“Socialism,” in turn, was the unrealized ideal of a world where

productive wealth would be administered democratically for the common

good. One of the most characteristic intellectual moves of the

neoliberal era was to flip this around. Capitalism became the unrealized

ideal: a utopian dream of a perfectly free, self-regulating market.

Socialism was the sordid reality of government regulation. All progress

in human happiness and freedom could therefore be attributed to

capitalism and everything bad to the lingering effects of socialism.

This was not traditional capitalist rhetoric. It was, rather, a kind of

Marxism in reverse. Tellingly, the language was first employed largely

by defectors from the other side: most notoriously Russian exile Ayn

Rand; her Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal, originally published in 1946,

was a powerful influence on the young Alan Greenspan, who, as head of

the American Federal Reserve between 1987 and 2006, was to become the

veritable high priest of neoliberal orthodoxy. What began as the

language of the hard Right was soon to be adopted almost everywhere. By

the 1980s, the revalidation of the word capitalism seems to have been

adopted as a special cause by the editors of the supposedly left-leaning

New York Times, which probably ran at least a hundred different

headlines and editorials during that period announcing that some

left-wing regime or party had been forced to embrace “capitalism.” After

the collapse of Marxist regimes, Timescolumnists had become so

intoxicated with the idea of capitalism as a radical force that there

was a lively debate in its pages on whether Che Guevera, were he alive

today, would have become a free-market reformer out of sheer

revolutionary enthusiasm.

Only in this context, I think, can we understand how a rhetoric of

absolute individualism could ever have become the basis for an emerging

bureaucracy. It arrived tumbled breathlessly together with the language

of revolution. The problem was that this was not just a language, and

the aspects of the revolutionary that it drew on were, mostly, the most

disastrous. The essence of the neoliberal position in fact bears

stunning similarity to Stalinism—that is, to the very arguments used by

Marxist revolutionaries in the 1920s and 1930s to justify the creation

of a bureaucratic state. One might summarize it like this: “Science has

shown that there is only one possible way forward, and it is the same

for any society on earth. There is a scientifically trained elite who

understand this and must be given the power to reengineer society

appropriately. The economic views of those not trained in this science

are irrelevant. So shut up and do what you’re told, because, even if in

the short run this may cause tremendous pain and dislocation, even

starvation and death, somewhere down the line (we’re not quite sure

when) it will all lead to a paradise of peace and prosperity.”

The same line touted by Soviet apparatchiks to Russian peasants in the

1930s is now being touted to just about everyone; the only significant

difference is that now historical materialism has been replaced by

Milton Friedman–style free-market economics. It is hardly surprising,

then, that since 1989 so many actual Stalinist apparatchiks, from Poland

to Vietnam, have found it so easy to simply switch from one orthodoxy to

the other. It didn’t really require much of a fundamental leap.

Obviously, neoliberal global bureaucracies are not nearly so directly

hands-on as old communist ones were in trying to impose their utopian

vision. But the ultimate ideal, to subject every aspect of life to the

logic of the market, is—as defectors like financier George Soros like to

point out—if anything just as totalitarian in its ambitions. What’s

more, many of the effects have been curiously similar. Under Soviet

regimes, political life—let alone ideological debate—was outlawed. All

political questions were deemed settled; all that remained was the

administration of economic affairs—supposedly aimed at eventually

creating a consumer paradise. As a result, the only way one could stake

a political claim on the center was by playing to some kind of ethnic or

cultural identity: for example, if the Khazaks get a nuclear power

plant, surely we Uzbeks deserve one too. Identity politics was the only

kind the bureaucratic apparatus found acceptable. One result was that

when these states dissolved, many instantly descended into ethnic

warfare. It is clear that something rather similar is now happening on a

global scale. The fall of communism in particular was taken to mean that

ideological—in effect, political—debate was over. The result was that

identity politics not only were seen as legitimate but were in a very

real sense the only sort of politics seen as entirely legitimate. In

some cases the link to global bureaucracies is quite clear.

Neoliberalism, as I have noted, seeks to eliminate all collective forms

of property—the only exception that seems to be allowable is for people

classified as “indigenous.” One result has been a worldwide outpouring

of attempts by groups to claim indigenous status, including many (such

as the pastoral Maasai in Kenya) that would never have dreamed of

describing themselves as such before. On a broader scale, Samuel

Huntington’s argument that, now that the age of ideological struggle is

over, a “war of civilizations” (i.e., religious and cultural identities)

is all that remains is a perfect expression of the logical results of

trying to declare an end to any other kind of history.

ALTERNATIVES, OR “ WORKS TO D O WHAT? ”

Without this Manichean framework, borrowed from the cruder varieties of

Marxism, it would be impossible to argue that, since “communism failed,”

there was no alternative but to strive toward some ideal of pure

free-market capitalism—one that has never actually existed anywhere.

Otherwise the argument would make about as much sense as the argument of

someone who, witnessing the collapse of the Catholic Church after a long

struggle with Episcopalianism, concluded that therefore we all had to

become Baptists (or maybe Jews). It seems to me that a more sober

assessment of history would rather have concluded that the most

effective way to win a cold war is through limited social welfare

programs combined with massive government military spending to stimulate

the economy; that the most effective way for poor countries to play

economic catch-up with rich capitalist ones is by combining market

forces, protection of key industries, strategic exports, and massive

government investment in education and infrastructure; and that if one’s

aim is to create the richest possible material life and greatest freedom

for about 10 percent of the world’s population while tossing the bottom

third to the wolves, neoliberalism is surely one’s best bet. It also

seems to me that none of this has any necessary bearing on other

questions, such as “What is the most effective way to bring about a

world in which ordinary people are secure in their basic needs, and thus

free to pursue the things that are most important to them?” or “How do

we ensure that the planet is not destroyed?”

Capitalism itself—industrial capitalism at least—has had a very brief

historical run. During a mere two hundred years, however, it has

nonetheless shown a remarkable ability to come up with threats to the

very existence of the species: first nuclear destruction, now global

climate change. There are good reasons to believe it is simply not a

viable long-term system: most obviously, because it is premised on the

need for continual growth, and economic growth cannot continue forever

on a planet with finite resources. Capitalism that was not based on the

need to continually expand production would simply not be capitalism;

its fundamental dynamics would change; it would become something else.

Whatever economic system predominates in fifty years, it is very likely

to be something other than capitalism. Of course, that something might

be even worse. This is why it seems to me this is precisely the wrong

time to give up on imagining alternatives to capitalism: that is, to

come up with ideas for what might actually be better.

This is why, for me, the movements of resistance against neoliberalism

have been so crucially important. These began almost immediately in the

1980s in most parts of the world, largely taking form around grassroots

campaigns in defense of one or another form of common property.[23] At

first they were largely unconnected. The Zapatista revolt in Chiapas in

1994 was a key moment; it was the Zapatistas, in fact, who sponsored the

first international meetings that eventually gave birth to what the

media came to call “the antiglobalization” movement—really, a global

movement, as the Zapatistas put it, “for humanity and against

neoliberalism.” The spectacular mass actions during the WTO meetings in

Seattle in November 1999, then afterwards in Washington and Prague

(versus the IMF), Quebec (versus the Free Trade Agreement of the

Americas [FTAA]), and Genoa (versus the Group of Eight), were all

intended first and foremost to reveal to the world the undemocratic

nature of the bodies that had come to control global economic policy.

They served, in other words, to point out the very existence of this new

global bureaucracy, on the assumption that most people in the world

would draw the obvious conclusions. In this they were strikingly

successful: within less than two years’ time most of the key tenets of

neoliberalism, treated as self-evident truths in the 1990s, had

everywhere begun to be called into question. Ambitious plans to expand

the WTO and create new trade pacts like the FTAA treaty stopped dead in

their tracks.

It is a bit ironic, in fact, that ever since the war on terror began

distracting U.S. activists and the U.S. public, no one seems to have

noticed that most of the original apparatus of neoliberalism has entered

into a crisis. The “Doha round” of the WTO was declared a failure in

2006, and the very existence of the institution is being called into

question. The IMF is if anything in even deeper crisis. After the

meltdown of the Argentine economy in 2002, and a veritable popular

uprising against the entire political class, the social democratic

president elected in 2003, Nestor Kirchner, had to make a dramatic move

to restore the legitimacy of the very idea of government. So he

defaulted on Argentina’s foreign debt. This is precisely what the IMF is

supposed to ensure never happens, and international bankers urged it to

step in and punish the country, but for once it was unable to do so.

This was for various reasons (partly the fact that the global movement

had rendered it a pariah, partly that everyone knew its disastrous

advice was largely responsible for the crisis in Argentina to begin

with), but as a result the entire edifice of power-throughdebt has begun

to crack. Argentina and Brazil paid off their entire IMF debt; soon,

with the help of Venezuela’s petrodollars, so had the rest of Latin

America. (Between 2003 and 2007, Latin America’s total debt to the IMF

declined by 98.4 percent. They basically owe nothing.) Russia, India,

China all followed suit and, along with countries like Korea, Thailand,

Malaysia, Indonesia, and the Philippines, now refuse to even talk about

new loans. As a result the IMF itself, reduced largely to lording it

over Africa, is rapidly itself going bankrupt. The World Bank holds on,

but its revenue is radically reduced.

All this seems to be happening under the radar of the U.S. public.

Meanwhile, in most of the rest of the world, lively arguments continue

on what a different, more humane world economy might actually look like.

In the United States, the movement has seen enormous debates between

reformist (“anticorporate”) and revolutionary (“anticapitalist”)

approaches. In much of the world, these arguments have come to turn more

on the potential role of the state: pitting those that wish to see the

creation of new forms of commons (the restoration of rights in land,

water, oil, as communal resources) through the aegis of national

governments against those that reject the state entirely and dream of a

world of what is sometimes called “true globalization,” without national

borders or government bureaucracies, built on confederations of free

communities managing their resources through direct democracy—in effect,

through some form of libertarian communism. It is far too early to tell

what will emerge from these conversations, whether new democratic forms

will actually emerge or whether we will just see a reshuffling of the

architecture of global bureaucracy. Neoliberalism is by no means dead:

similar reforms are being carried out on a massive scale within newly

emerging powers like India and China, where it is much harder to

mobilize international opposition. But we might do well to pay attention

to the arguments, because they may well prove critical to the future

history of humanity.

[1] The sources are, respectively, Alex Emery, “Bolivia’s Morales to

Challenge U.S. after Election” (Update 3), Bloomberg Wire Services,

December 19, 2005, www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=10000086&

sid=aEbMZeNviHPE; “Alternative Left Parties Sign Cooperation Agreement,”

Deutsche Welle, December 11, 2005,

www.dw-world.de/dw/article/0,2144,1811746,00.html; George Dor, ed.,

“Alternatives to Neo-Liberalism,” special issue, Pambazuka News, no. 234

(December 15, 2005), www.pambazuka.org/ en/issue/234.

[2] That was a paraphrase. The exact quote reads: “I feel about

globalization a lot like I feel about the Generally speaking, I think

it’s a good thing that the sun comes up every morning. It does more good

than harm But even if I didn’t much care for the dawn there isn’t much I

could do about it.” Thomas Friedman, The Lexus and the Olive Tree(New

York: Anchor Books, 2000), xxi–xxii.

[3] David Harvey, A Brief History of Neoliberalism(New York: Oxford

University Press, 2005).

[4] Thatcher was something of an exception in this regard, though it is

to be noted that even she never got more than about a third of the

popular vote.

[5] Or to be more accurate, interest would not be counted as principal.

By the mid-1980s most poor countries had in fact paid out much more than

they had ever borrowed. The interest rates, however, were set so high as

to make full repayment effectively impossible.

[6] The idea of tying debt relief to political reforms was the

brainchild of Reagan’s secretary of state James Baker and become known

as the Baker Plan.

[7] The case of Madagascar is all the more telling because Zafy, a

surgeon who was placed in power by a nonviolent revolution that replaced

former dictator Didier Ratsiraka, had the impertinence to demand that

the IMF provide one example of a poor country that had taken their

advice and was now rich. After he refused to sign, the economic

devastation was such that in the next election he was defeated by

Ratsiraka, who vowed to reverse the policy. Five years later Ratsiraka

was ousted by another popular uprising, but this time by a neoliberal

yogurt magnate.

[8] All the more so considering that the government that signed NAFTA

had not been honestly elected but had won by fraud.

[9] See Janine Wedel’s Collision and Collusion: The Strange Case of

Western Aid to Eastern Europe, 1989– 1998(New York: St. Martin’s Press,

1998). Wedel was the first anthropologist to tell this remarkable story.

[10] The relation of this larger system and national governments has

changed in significant ways over the course of the neoliberal period. At

first government itself was widely represented as the problem: its

simple removal was supposed to lead to the spontaneous emergence of

market mechanisms. Investors, however, soon discovered that the open

encouragement of greed and disparagement of the very idea of government

tended to foster extreme corruption, which got in the way of business,

all the more so after “shock therapy” in much of Eastern Europe led not

to free markets but to lawless “gangster capitalism.” Under Clinton, the

emphasis shifted to the idea of “good governance,” emphasizing

especially the need to maintain an honest legal climate conducive to

foreign investment.

[11] World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalization, A Fair

Globalization: Creating Opportunities for All (Geneva: International

Labour Office, 2004); UN Development Program, “Human Development

Report,” 1999, and “Human Development Report,” 2003.

[12] China is excluded for several reasons: in the first period, its

autarkic policies kept it to a certain degree outside the larger system;

in the second, its government dramatically flaunted major principles of

neoliberal policy, strategically deploying just the sort of planning,

protections, and easy credit arrangements that the rest of the

developing world was being forced to abandon.

[13] Robert Pollin,Contours of Descent: U.S. Economic Fractures and the

Landscape of Global Austerity(London: Verso, 2003).

[14] If statistics sometimes seem ambiguous, it is largely because many

of these figures improved in much of East Asia—usually, in precisely

those countries that resisted IMF pressure to pare back or privatize

health and education. The declines in Africa and Latin America, where

few countries were in a position to resist, were quite dramatic.

[15] It has held pride of place since 2004. In the World Economic

Forum’s 2004–5 rankings, Finland is followed by the United States, then

Sweden, Taiwan, Denmark, and Norway. Note that the top six do not

include a single country following neoliberal orthodoxy, since the

United States itself regularly defies most of the precepts it urges on

other governments. For the full report, see World Economic Forum,

“Global Competitiveness Report 2004–2005,” October 2004,

www.weforum.org/en/initiatives/gcp/Global%

20Competitiveness%20Report/PastReports/index.htm.

[16] One might consider this a perfect example of that hoary piece of

economic wisdom: “if you owe the bank a million dollars, the bank owns

you. If you owe the bank a hundred million, you own the bank.”

[17] Walden Bello, Future in the Balance: Essays on Globalization and

Resistance (Oakland, CA: Food First Books, 2001). See also Walden Bello,

Dark Victory: The United States, Structural Adjustment, and Global

Poverty(Oakland, CA: Institute for Food and Development Policy, 1994).

[18] Bello, Dark Victory;Harvey, Brief History of Neoliberalism;

Immanuel Wallerstein, The Decline of American Power: The U.S. in a

Chaotic World(New York: New Press, 2003).

[19] The line is from Richard Overton’s An Arrow against All Tyrants

(Exeter: Rota, 1976). The best discussion of the political theory of

possessive individualism is in C. B. MacPherson, The Political The- ory

of Possessive Individualism(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1962).

[20] Giovanni Arrighi, The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the

Origins of Our Times(London: Verso, 1994).

[21] The fact that the IMF operates under the UN umbrella is

particularly ironic when one considers that the UN’s Universal Charter

of Human Rights specifies that all human beings have a right to food and

shelter. It has never shown much ability to enforce such rights. The

IMF, however, has intervened quite systematically and effectively

against any country that has attempted to enact policies inspired by

such principles.

[22] The 1980s and 1990s certainly saw more market elements introduced

into some of these bureaucracies, particularly with outsourcing of

primary production, and new, Asian-inspired “just in time” production

strategies. On the other hand it also saw unprecedented concentration of

ownership. Few Americans are aware that almost all department stores in

the United States, for instance, are now owned by one company, Macy’s

Retail Holdings. So in effect corporate bureaucracies became more

flexible but far larger.

[23] The most incisive analysis on the importance of different sorts of

“commons” to capitalism has been made by the Midnight Notes Collective:

they were the first to emphasize that while capitalists preferred to see

a world in which all forms of common property administered by

communities for their own collective benefit would be privatized or

otherwise eliminated, they also promoted the creation of new forms of

commons for their own benefit: for instance, collective responsibilities

for research, transport, waste disposal, and new and elaborate security

functions. Struggles over the definition and management of collective

resources are thus the common theme of global resistance struggles that

might otherwise seem to have next to nothing to do with one another,

such as those of the Twenty-first Century Socialists in South America

and of Islamic movements in the Middle East. See “Midnight Notes

Collective,” last updated January 4, 2005,

www.midnightnotes.org/index2.htl, for the best introduction to this line

of thought.