💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 6214.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 04:42:38. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

🚧 View Differences

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

The pound and the fury - Brexit is making Britons poorer, and meaner

2016-10-11 11:13:33

Oct 11th 2016, 13:29 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

THESE are exciting times for Britain s currency, and not in a good way. On the

eve of the vote on whether to leave the European Union, back in June, a pound

bought you $1.48. Sterling has since declined by more than 16% against the

dollar, to $1.22. Nearly half of the drop has occurred in the last week or so,

as the Conservative government has outlined plans for a hard Brexit: one

which shoves Britain right out of the single market in exchange for the ability

to do more harm to itself by reducing migration.

In a piece for the Wall Street Journal, Greg Ip (a friend and former colleague

of this blogger) does a nice job explaining the links between Brexit and a

tumbling pound. Markets anticipate that it will become more costly for British

firms to sell goods and services to Europe. Europeans will consequently buy

fewer of them, and therefore fewer pounds, leading to a weaker currency. That

is, cheap sterling is part of the adjustment to a loss in British

competitiveness: the mechanism by which Britons come to spend less on foreign

goodies (now increasingly dear) as the price of its choice to leave the EU.

As Mr Ip notes, that s not all that s going on. Britain is also in a fortunate

position, able to produce valuable stores of wealth: British government bonds,

London property, and sterling itself. The ability to make such things, which

foreigners like to hold, is a bit like owning a gold mine or rich oil deposits.

Foreigners buy lots of those valuable things, pushing up sterling and making

Britons richer. The downside is a touch of Dutch disease; exports are more

expensive than they would otherwise be, and many industries therefore struggle

to compete. Brexit threatens the value of those magical assets, however, and

undoes the Dutch-disease effect. Brexit is a little like Saudi Arabia swearing

off the oil business, declaring it would rather work for an honest living even

if that makes its people poorer. That might sound noble, though it does make

one reflect on the lack of policy imagination that led voters to make

themselves poorer so that they could work harder for what they get.

Mr Ip closes with a very interesting set of thoughts:

Brexit is thus turning out to be a useful test case for deglobalization.

Raising barriers to the free flow of goods, services, capital and people need

not entail recession or panic. It may even redress some of the grievances

behind the anti-globalization backlash. If Britain exports fewer financial

services and more manufactured goods and tourism, the income gap between London

and the rest of the country should narrow.

In the end, Britons may be a bit poorer than if they d stayed, but more

self-reliant and more in control of their own borders. That s the tradeoff.

Two remarks on this. First, it is not obvious to me that manufacturing

industries will definitely be the big winners (such as it is) from Brexit.

Financial services are bound to be harmed, it is true. Yet British industry

might find it more difficult to pivot to new foreign markets than British

services. In the trade of goods, distance matters; gravity models of trade,

which reckon that trade intensity is negatively associated with distance, do a

surprisingly good job explaining actual trade patterns. Ironically, the digital

revolution has reinforced the importance of distance by enabling the growth of

supply-chain trade: the co-ordination of production across suppliers in lots of

different countries. If leaving the EU costs British firms their positions

within the supply chains of Factory Europe, those firms will find it difficult

to turn and embed themselves in the production chains of Asia or North America;

such places are simply too far away. This was always one of the great inanities

of Brexit. Leaving the EU does not change the fact that Britain is right next

door to a bunch of rich European countries and not especially close to anyone

else.

And second, let me draw your attention to one very important word in that

ultimate sentence: self-reliant. What is this self ? The typical Briton will

not become more self-reliant as a result of Brexit. The chap behind the bar at

the pub will not suddenly find himself cobbling his own shoes and milling his

own flour because of the vote to leave the EU. Mr Ip seems to intend the self,

in this case, to be Britain. That may have been what voters intended; the

assertion of the nation as the most important civic body is a disheartening

development if so. And that might be the outcome, in part, of Brexit; trade

volumes will probably fall a bit, and as Mr Ip notes Britons will spend less

holiday time in Provence and more in Blackpool. Yet it s also not quite right.

Whether Britain is selling gilts to foreigners or turnips, it is still reliant

on them.

The self at issue here is actually something different. It is a conservative

sort of Englishness, which entails the rejection of London as well as of

Brussels. And what is being purchased, it should be clear, is the ability to

shut particular people out of Britain: those that are not enough like the

community of selves on which the English intend to become more reliant. It is a

vote against cosmopolitanism and multiculturalism. Nothing in the decline in

sterling is going to make that adjustment less painful to those being shut out

of the circle of British life. Neither should it make us optimistic that

deglobalisation can occur without a great deal of accompanying ugliness.