💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › emile-pouget-the-party-of-labour.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 09:45:55. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: The Party of Labour
Author: Émile Pouget
Date: Unknown
Language: en
Topics: anarcho-syndicalism, syndicalism, syndicalist, anarcho-syndicalist
Source: Retrieved on August 19, 2017 from https://libcom.org/library/party-labour-emile-pouget

Émile Pouget

The Party of Labour

The Party of Labour Defined

The Party of Labour is what it says it is, the banding together of the

workers into one homogeneous bloc; the autonomous organisation of the

working class into an aggregate operating on the terrain of the economy;

by virtue of its origins, its essence, it shuns all compromise with

bourgeois elements.

The grassroots cell of the Party of Labour is the trade union and it is

by the trade unions coming into contact with one another, through their

shows of solidarity that the Party of Labour reveals itself, shows

itself and acts.

On the one hand, the trade union is affiliated to the national

federation of its trade; on the other, to its Departmental Union. The

federal agencies of these two in turn federate with each other and out

of their union comes the agency that marshals the workers energies and

interests: the General Confederation of Labour.

This federalism of overlapping concentric circles is a marvellous

amplifier of workers; strength; its component parts reinforce one

another and the particular strength of each is magnified by the support

of all the rest. On its own, the trade union has no resources or

energies other than its own and could operate in a restricted way only;

whereas, through its affiliation to the Party of Labour, it can draw

upon the considerable powers afforded it, in a ripple effect, by

organised solidarity.

This enormous strength — which defies measurement in that it is forever

growing — is the result of association on economic terrain. That is the

only basis upon which such a thriving organism with nothing to fear from

the intrusion of any disorganising factor can be constructed.In fact,

since the construction of this coming-together is in the class interests

of the proletariat, any attenuation of its demands and revolutionary

power is pointless and every attempted deviation doomed in advance to

futility.

The Party of Labour is a party of interests. It takes no account of the

opinions of its component members: it acknowledges and co-ordinates only

the interests — be they material or moral or intellectual — of the

working class. Its ranks are open to all of the exploited regardless of

their political or religious views.

Yes, the Party of Labour ignores opinions, no matter what they may be!

On the other hand, it goes after the exploitation of human beings in

whatever form this may assume.

A worker with baroque philosophical or political views — who may be a

believer in some God or in the State — will have his place alongside his

comrades within the ranks of this party. But what comes in for criticism

within this party is the exploitation of theological, political or

philosophical creeds; what is reproached is the intrusion of priest or

politician, both of whom make a livelihood out of speculating with

peoples beliefs.

Within the party, there is a place for all of the exploited, even if

many of them (in todays society where there is nothing but absurdity and

crime) are obliged to buckle down to pointless or indeed harmful

undertakings.

The worker in the arms plant, the builder of warships, etc., are engaged

in noxious tasks: they are doubly the victims of bad social organisation

since they are not only exploited but must also do their bit towards

malfeasant activity. However, their place is still inside the Party of

Labour.

By contrast, anyone who is, by virtue of his personal function, a

bringer of harm — the informer, say — is to be shunned. Such a person is

a parasite of the most revolting type: sprung from the working class, he

has debased himself with the vilest of undertakings: as a result, only

in the bourgeoisies ranks is there any place for him.

Thus the Party of Labour stands apart from all other parties by virtue

of this essential fact: that in banding together those who work against

those who live from exploitation of human beings, it marshals interests

and not opinions. Thus, of necessity, there is a unity of outlook in its

ranks. Among the personnel making up the more or less moderate, more or

less revolutionary schools of thought, such a unity of outlook is

feasible (and exists!); but such differences on the detail neither

invalidate nor breach the syndicalist unity that arises from identity of

interests. This power to absorb individual differences, under the

umbrella of the agreement that necessarily springs from a community of

interest, gives the Party of Labour an edge in terms of vitality and

action and affords it an immunity from the blights afflicting the

political parties.

Inside every party — the Party of Labour excepted — the over-riding

objective is “policy”, and on the basis of a similarity of opinions, men

of divergent interests — exploiters and exploited (and one must be

either one or the other!), are thrown into one anothers company. This is

a characteristic of all democratic parties. They are, all of them, a

motley collection of men whose interests run counter to one another.

Not that this anomaly is peculiar to the bourgeois democratic parties.

It also disfigures socialist parties which, once having set foot upon

the slippery slopes of parliamentarism, come to jettison the specific

characteristics of socialism and become nothing more than democratic

parties, albeit of a more accentuated variety.

More and more capitalists, bosses, etc. are being won over to socialism

and these reconcile their parasitical existence as best they can with

the acting out of their beliefs. One of the things that attracts

recruits from the enemy camp is the deviation in the direction of

parliamentarism. Whereas they have not quite completely been eliminated,

then at least the fact that the theory of taking government power has

relegated revolutionary concerns to the background, has whetted some

appetites. And these defectors from the bourgeoisie have calculated the

benefits of turning socialist and cherish the hope of gaining the upper

hand in that way. So much so that there are those who become socialists

the way that others become lawyers or publicans. It is regarded as a

career move — an excellent way of getting ahead?

The Party of Labour need have no fear of such dangers. By virtue of the

very fact that it is constructed upon the class interests of the

proletariat and that its action takes place in the sphere on economics,

there is no way that individuals can rely upon it or invoke it in the

satisfaction of their selfish interests. The contradiction there is

formal and insurmountable. Indeed, since the gratification of personal

ambition is feasible only in the realm of politics, any who attempt any

such chicanery and pursue a selfish private interest within the Party of

Labour can accomplish but one thing: their own self-exclusion from the

labour camp.

The same phenomenon can be seen when a working man becomes an employer:

even though the parvenu may still be motivated by good intentions and

cling to his revolutionary aspirations, as a rule he is excluded from

collective groupings — his class interests having changed.

The same thing goes for the parvenu in politics: he quickly drops out of

trade union activism and, in most cases, once he has achieved his

purposes, and risen to the desired elevation, he willingly steps aside

and refrains from all activity within the economic organisation.

Now, if individual deviations are incompatible with the organisational

make-up of the Party of Labour, it is all the more firmly to be excluded

as a possibility that that body as a whole should succumb to a deviation

that would be nothing short of its very negation. By virtue of the very

fact that it is constituted upon the class interests of the proletariat,

it cannot at any time or in any fashion be a breeding ground for the

ambitious.

It cannot turn into a party of politicians. Apart from the fact that

that would be lapsing back into past errors which exhausted the working

class in futile struggles and in efforts that brought it no benefit

(albeit that they were not futile and without benefit for those keen to

speed their progress up the ladder!), such a comprehensive deviation

would be tantamount to an affirmation that the proletariat, deserting

the prey for its shadow, would disdain to win economic and social

improvements and be wholly consumed instead by the pursuit of political

illusions.

So just as it is unthinkable that the working class should lay aside its

interests, it is also unthinkable that the Party of Labour should turn

into a democratic party.

Its necessity

The Party of Labour is a direct by-product of capitalist society: it is

the concert of proletariat forces, for which the working class logically

strives from the moment it wakes up to its interests.

The current society is made up of two classes whose interests run

counter to each other: the working class and the bourgeois class:

consequently, it is only natural that each of these should rally around

its own social pole — the workers around one, the exploiters around the

opposite social pole.

The coming-together of the working class makes up the Party of Labour:

it, therefore, is the aggregation suited to the form of exploitation,

which is why it emerges spontaneously with no preconceived notion

governing its co-ordination.

It would be a waste of time for us to dwell upon demonstrating the

existence within society of two antagonistic social classes which, far

from amalgamating into one homogeneous unit, merely accentuate their

differences. That is a fact so patently obvious that we need not labour

the point.

This irreconcilable antagonism is the result of the seizure by the

ruling class of all of the assets of society — its instruments of

labour, property and resources of all sorts. From which it follows that

the lower class is obliged, in order to survive, to submit to the

conditions foisted upon it by these grasping types.

Such deference to the capitalist by the proletarian who, in return for

his labour, receives a wage considerably less than the value of the

labour forthcoming from him, the wage-slave, is, the bourgeoisie

contends, a natural phenomenon. They even venture to argue that the wage

is not subject to change — and are none too bothered in their

contentions by the successive disappearances of slavery and serfdom,

which ought to caution them against the absurdity of arguing that

property (as held by them) alone is the exception to the laws of life

which are movement and change. However, even as they contend that the

waged — as a class — are doomed to eternal exploitation, they see fit to

blind them with the chimera of individual emancipation, dazzling their

victims with the possibility of escaping wage slavery and taking their

place in the ranks of the capitalist class.

Aside from the fact that as far as the bourgeoisie is concerned such

hopes have the merit of inducing the exploited to bear their misfortune

with patience, they neutralise or at any rate slow down the growth of

class consciousness among the proletariat.

The education and training bestowed upon younger generations have no

other purpose: those generations are subjected to a method of

intellectual castration based upon rehearsal of prejudices, peppered

with preaching about resignation, as well as incitements to unrestrained

self-seeking.

The argument is that in the present society, everyone has the bed he has

made for himself and the place he deserves: that, if one is to make it

one has to be an honest, sober, intelligent worker and so on. What is

not said, although it is implied, is that to these qualities, one more

must be added: one must be devoid of scruples and elbow ones way ahead

without regard to ones fellows.

In the bourgeois view, life is an ongoing struggle of human against

human; society is an arena where each is the enemy of all.

Distracted by such sophistry, the proletarian at first dreams of

individually breaking free of wage slavery. Since work underpins

everything and since wealth is there for the taking for those who

display order and perseverance, he will make his fortune! Moreover, in

his view, wealth is only the achievement of independence and freedom and

the assurance of well-being. But alas! He must discard his dreams.

Reality requires it and he has to admit that it is materially impossible

for the workers to attain the yearned for relief. Before he could

achieve individual emancipation, he would have to own his instruments of

labour and the wherewithal to set them in motion. Now, modern

production, being formidably industrialised, requires such considerable

capital outlay that a worker would have to be mad to imagine that he

might set aside, out of his wages, the capital he requires to acquire a

factory.

To be sure, some proletarians do step out from their class: thanks to

exceptionally favourable circumstances, some powerful personalities

without scruples as to choice of method do manage to inch their way into

the bourgeoisie.There are even some cases of men who started out as

workers (Carnegie, Rockefeller, etc,) turning into the kings of wealth.

The bourgeoisie has taken these upstarts to its bosom. It is all the

more pleased to welcome them aboard because, by introducing an injection

of new blood, they consolidate its privileges: moreover, it parades them

by way of unanswerable arguments to show that it is easy for

parsimonious working men to become bourgeois.

It would be naive of the workers to let themselves be tempted by this

bait and to content themselves with hopes of just such an eventuality.

That would be tantamount to letting themselves be lulled by the same

song as the shepherdesses of legend who dreamed of a Prince Charming

showing up to ask for their hand in marriage.

And then what? Even if it were true that the most gifted members of the

proletariat can make their fortune, the situation of the mass of them

would not have altered: the workers would carry on slaving for their

exploiters, grazing materially and spiritually, with no prospect to look

forward to but the repose of the grave.

Thus the individuals escape from wage slavery, which anyway means that

those who make it are obliged to exploit their class brothers, offers no

remedy to the social ills afflicting the proletariat. Such escapes can

only occur on a small scale and all that they imply is a few adjustments

to a few individual situations, having no impact upon the fate of the

workers as a whole, who carry on slaving for the benefit of the masters

and rulers.

Furthermore, even were the numbers achieving comparative ease, indeed

wealth, larger, that would do nothing to erase the antagonism that pits

the producer class against the parasite class. For as long as social

relations remain as they are — the relation of employer to wage slave,

of ruler to ruled — the problem will remain and class struggle will be

an inevitable phenomenon.

Even if we were to suppose that the moans of the masses crushed and

broken on the social battle-field were to trouble the peace of mind of

the smug and those who, out of a spirit of charity or guile, may deign

to cater for the material lives of the exploited, amalgamation of the

classes would not be the outcome of such intervention and society would

not be pacified by that remedy.

It has often been said: “Man does not live by bread alone!” Which is why

the social question is not just a material problem. For us to be happy

and content, it is not enough that we should be assured of our “crust”:

we also want to be free of all impediment and all domination: we want to

be free, to be beholden to none and to have no relations with our

neighbours other than those founded on equality, regardless of the

differences in our abilities, expertise and functions.

The point therefore is to work a change in the structure of society so

that henceforth there is only one category, one class possible: that of

the producers. Such essential change can only be wrought on the basis of

communism — communism alone being able to guarantee that every

individual enjoys complete autonomy and unfettered scope for

development.

Once upon a time, before big industry drove the artisan from his tiny

workshop — and stripped him off the instrument of his labours — the

working man had some prospect of carving out a rough, but independent

existence for himself. Today, in industry, such a dream is feasible only

in exceptional cases.

Even now in the countryside the peasant can hope to carve out a

comparatively free existence upon a tract of land. However, such

liberation is tending to become more and more fraught with difficulties

(and in most cases very precarious) because of the confiscation of the

land by the rich, because of the escalating taxes and the rapaciousness

of the middlemen. And anyway, the peasants liberation is accompanied by

such worries! He lives in constant terror of the tax collector, the

money-lender and leads a joyless, crushingly bleak existence slaving

like an ox.

Such autonomy of peasant and artisan, gained at huge effort, is a

particularly illusory emancipation in that both are beholden to

capitalism and their earnings are modest, in comparison with the amount

of toil required of them. They are societys hybrids who do not quite fit

the description bourgeois, nor are they wage-slaves: they are a

hang-over from the artisanate and the peasantry: although not readily

classifiable, their interests and those of the working class are the

very same. At present, though, they can be taken to task for preferring

their own fate to that of the wage slave: except that they ought to be

saying to themselves that their living conditions are a hang-over from

the past and that it is in their interest to lend a hand in the coming

social change: indeed, they have much to gain from offering no

resistance to the Revolution, and instead playing a part in its success

and adapting to the new modes of production and distribution.

So we can see how illusory is the bait of individual emancipation held

out by the bourgeoisie: of the several methods of personal escape from

wage slavery hypothetically on offer, none is liable to be widely taken

up and thus cannot be embraced by the workers at large as a remedy to

their sad lot, for none is likely to provide for a free and comfortable

existence for all.

So, if this dream of individual escape from wage slavery has been

peddled by the bourgeoisie, it is because the bourgeoisie has seen it as

a siding that can stop the working class from attaining class

consciousness. By stimulating appetites and over-stimulating selfish

ambitions, it has counted upon keeping the proletariat divided against

itself indefinitely so that with each individuals head filled with

thoughts of nothing but the scramble to get ahead, his only concern will

be with climbing on his comrades backs, which will act as a brake upon

the spirit of revolt and nullify innate tendencies towards solidarity.

But the human being could not resign himself fatalistically to perpetual

slavery: the seeds of discord and hatred which the bourgeoisie look

forward to seeing sprout from the Peoples hearts so that its own

security can be assured are a weed, the spread of which cannot forever

strangle the growth of instincts of sociability, for life through

agreement is every bit as crucial to the survival of human society as

the ferocious struggle to survive is dear to the exploiters.

Consequently, in spite of the sophistry and the falsehoods with which

its head is filled, it was inevitable that the proletariat should attain

consciousness of its class interests, especially as the merest

flickering glimmer of reason had to open its eyes to the fact that

societys afflictions are not inescapable.

Why these striking, revolting inequalities? How come there are wretches

who want for their daily bread when there are some who cannot think up

ways of squandering their surplus? How come men are paid only inadequate

wages for hellish toil when there are parasites wallowing in comfort and

luxury?

What is the reason for it all? Is agricultural and industrial output not

up to meeting everyones needs?

No! In the course of his active life, any man devoting himself to useful

toil produces more than he needs to match what he consumes (in food,

clothing, accommodation, etc.), and then some; over that time he

produces as well enough to reimburse the community for the advances it

has made to him to rear him to manhood and he also produces enough to

ensure that he has the wherewithal to live when, overtaken by old age,

he will not be able to work any longer.

Now, if the existence of every single person is not guaranteed, for the

present as well as for the future, out of this fund of intense personal

productivity, the reason is that this wealth is not being used to

guarantee the upkeep of those with a natural entitlement but is diverted

by the capitalist class away from its social destination and mainly

turned to its own benefit.

That the level of agricultural and industrial productivity is high

enough for everyones needs to be met is now incontrovertible.

In industrial terms, production potential is, thanks to the tremendous

improvement in tools, well nigh unlimited: so true is this that in spite

of the prudence of industrialists who each try to tailor their workers

output to the commercial demands of the market, there often is a glut in

the shape of over-production. Those hardest hit in such circumstances

are the workers: it is they who suffer the painful consequences of such

crises, because, in order to restore the balance, the exploiters cannot

think of any better solution than to slow down production, which leads

to unemployment and leads to even greater wretchedness for the working

class.

On the agricultural scene, the picture is equally sombre: the object of

farming is not to reap mammoth harvests and thereby create food in great

abundance: the object of farming is to sell at a profit. Now since sale

prices slump in years when the harvest has been good, whereas man-power

tends to become more expensive, farmers would rather a passable than an

abundant harvest, the former being more easily and more profitably

disposed of.

So here we have the general position: abundance of produce of all sorts

is dreaded rather than desired and there is a tendency to keep the

supply low so that it can be sold dear. The needs of the mass of

humanity never figure among the preoccupations of the capitalists who

preside over production: we have the monstrous spectacle of entire

peoples bereft of the means of survival — and all too often literally

perishing of hunger — when there is an adequate supply of food, clothing

and accommodation available.

Such a glaring iniquity is condemnation enough, without further

arguments being required, of the social organisation that engenders it.

It is utterly necessary that this monstrous system of distribution that

vests almost everything in an exploitative, parasitical ruling minority,

most of whom have little or no hand in wealth creation, should be

overthrown. Now, given the the extent of industrial and scientific

development, such a solution seems practicable only thanks to a

fundamental transformation: the system of exploitation that marshals

human resources in order to set them to producing for the benefit of the

confiscator of natural resources and instruments of labour must be

replaced by a system of solidarity taking natural resources and the

instruments of labour into common ownership and setting them to work for

the benefit of all.

This change is an ineluctable necessity and its advent is hastened as

the working class acquires a better understanding of its class

interests. But this task of reorganising society can only be carried out

and brought off in a context purged of all bourgeois contamination. This

function of acting as midwife to the new society thus falls legitimately

upon the shoulders of the Party of Labour, the sole agency which, by

virtue of its very make-up, excludes all of the dross of society from

its ranks.

Consequently, the marshalling of the working class into a bloc separate

from all the parties — and with appropriate tactics and methodologies of

its very own — is no flash in the pan; it is an inherent requirement of

the present context, for only in such a party — which implies perfect

homogeneity and utter identity of interests — can it feel utterly at

home.

Anywhere else, any other grouping is open to infiltration by elements of

the propertied class and the ambitions of individuals can have noxious

implications. Which is why none of them can boast the unity of outlook,

action and aim that are automatically attributes of the party of the

proletariat class: which is why none is so plainly qualified to

prosecute and accomplish the task of social revolution, expropriation

and reorganisation.

Its Aim

The Party of Labour is the party of the future. In the harmonious

society whose day is coming, there will be no place for anyone but

Labour: parasites of every sort will of necessity be eliminated from it.

So it is only natural that the Party of Labour, the crucible in which

the social combinations of yearned for tomorrows are made, stands

outside of all the existing parties. This is especially unremarkable

since it stands apart from them by virtue not only of its form of

cohesion, but also in terms of the aim it pursues and the methodologies

it advocates and practises.

Whilst other parties have as their objective the retention or removal of

the government line-up — according as they reckon that it is, or ought

to be favourable to their own appetites, their ambitions or quite simply

to their cronies — the Party of Labour ignores this outward and quite

superficial business and sets its cap at working an internal and

external change in the elements of society; it labours to change

mind-sets, forms of association and economic relationships.

The goal it pursues is thoroughgoing emancipation of the workers.

Espousing as its own the watchword of the International Working Mens

Association, of which it is the logical heir, it takes it as inevitable

that that emancipation will be the working classs own doing, without

meddling by outside or heterogeneous elements. It is obvious that, if it

is not to be a mirage, that emancipation will have to imply the

elimination of the bourgeois class and the utter demolition of its

privileges.

Which is to say that the Party of Labour aims at a radical

transformation of the social system.

Examination of economic phenomena demonstrates that that transformation

must be achieved through neutralisation of private property and the

burgeoning of a communist arrangement, so that the current relations

between individuals — the relations of wage-slave to capitalist, of led

to leader — may be turned into relations of equality and liberty.

In fact, there will be no thoroughgoing emancipation unless exploiters

and leaders disappear from the scene and tabula rasa made of all

capitalist and state institutions. Such an undertaking cannot be

effected peaceably, much less lawfully! History teaches that the

privileged have never surrendered their privileges without having been

compelled so to do and forced into it by their rebellious victims. It is

unlikely that the bourgeoisie is blessed with an exceptional greatness

of soul and will abdicate voluntarily...Recourse to force, which, as

Karl Marx has said, is “the mid-wife to societies”, will be required.

So the Party of Labour is a party of Revolution.

Except that it does not regard the Revolution as a future cataclysm for

which we must wait patiently to see emerging from the inevitable

working-out of events. Such pious awaiting of the final catastrophe

would be nothing more than transposition to and continuation upon

materialist ground, of the old millenarian dreams.

The Revolution is an undertaking for all times, for today as well as

tomorrow: it is continual action, a daily battling without let-up or

respite, against the forces of oppression and exploitation. A rebel

embarked upon a revolutionary act is one who, repudiating the legitimacy

of present society, works to undermine it.

It is to this unrelenting task of Revolution that the workers in their

trade unions are committed. They regard themselves as being in ongoing

insurrection against capitalist society and, within its bosom, they are

hatching and developing the embryo of the society wherein Labour will be

All.

However, in spite of this consistently subversive stance, they are prey

to the requirements of bourgeois rule: but, whilst deferring to the

needs of the present, they do not conform to the forms of legality and

do not bless it with their acquiescence, even when it decks itself out

with reforming colours. Their revolutionary efforts are designed to

wrest partial improvements from the bourgeoisie, improvements that they

never mistake for definitive. Thus, whatever the improvement they gain,

and however significant it may seem, they always declare it to be

inadequate and, as soon as they have the measure of their strength, they

waste no time before demanding more.

There is another advantage to these struggles which are forever being

relaunched in ongoing harrying of the exploiters, quite apart from the

fact that they undermine and dismantle capitalist institutions, and that

they blood and strengthen the working class.

It is this posture of ongoing insurrection against definitive conformity

with existing conditions that marks the revolutionary character of the

Party of Labour.

It is a mistake to imagine that violence is always characteristic of a

revolutionary act: such an act can also assume a very moderate shape

displaying nothing of the destructive brutality which our adversaries

point to as the essential feature of revolutionism.

Indeed, it should not be forgotten that in most circumstances the act in

itself has no definite character: it acquires one only as the motives

that prompted it are subjected to analysis. Which is why the same acts

can, according to the case in point, be declared good or bad, just of

unjust, revolutionary or reformist. For instance: killing a man on the

corner of the boulevard is a crime: killing him using a guillotine is,

from the bourgeois point of view, an act of justice: killing a despot is

an act glorified by some and despised by others.. And yet these various

acts are in fact the same: a human life is ended!

It follows therefore that the revolutionism of the working class can

manifest itself in very anodyne actions just as its reformist mentality

might be underlined by unduly violent acts. This, moreover, is what we

can see in the United States: strikes there are often marked by acts of

violence (renegades executed, dynamite outrages, etc.) which are not

indicative of a revolutionary frame of mind, in that the object the

strikers have in mind is restricted to improvements that pose no

challenge to the principle of exploitation: the current society looks

bearable to them and doing away with wage slavery does not enter their

minds.

As a result, the index of the Party of Labours revolutionary character

is that, without ever neglecting to fight for minor improvements, it

aims at the transformation of capitalist society into a harmonious

society.

Improvements, secured on a day to day basis, are thus merely stages

along the road to human emancipation: the immediate material advantages

they bring are matched by a considerable moral benefit: they bolster the

working classs ardour, stimulate its desire for betterment and prompt it

to press for more significant change.

The only thing is that it would be the most dangerous of illusions to

confine trade union action to the securing of partial improvements: that

would be to slide into a morbid reformism. Important though such

improvements may be, they are not enough: they are merely a partial

claw-back of the bourgeoisies privileges: as a result, they do not

tinker with the relations between Labour and Capital. No matter how

splendid these improvements might be imagined to be, they leave the

worker still under the rule of wage-slavery: he is just as dependent

upon his Master as ever! Now what the working class needs is complete

liberation: which means wholesale expropriation of the bourgeoisie.

That decisive act, the culmination of preceding struggles, implies utter

ruination for privilege, and, whereas the preceding struggles may have

been pursued peacefully, it is unimaginable that the ultimate clash will

come to pass without some revolutionary conflagration.

Historical Summary

The Party of Labour finds organisational expression in the General

Confederation of Labour (CGT) which was launched in Limoges at the trade

union congress held there in 1895. But if we wish to investigate its

gestation and lineage, we must look a lot further back in time: there is

a direct line showing the Party of Labour to be an emanation of the

International Working Mens Association, of which it is the historical

continuation.

Throughout the 19^(th) century, the workers fought with indefatigable

tenacity to break through the impediments imposed by the bourgeoisie

upon their wishes to band together: instinctively, they set up class

groupings (embryonic, naturally), under cover of mutual associations or

in the shape of resistance societies. When at last the International

Working Mens Association was established, a tremor of hope ran through

the proletariat: its aspirations, hitherto ill-defined, acquired

substance and the future struck it as a less bleak prospect.

In fact, in its “givens”, the International framed the programme of the

Party of Labour: it declared:

“That the emancipation of the workers must be the workers own doing

(...)”

“That the subjection of the worker to capital is the source of all

servitude: political, moral and material..”

“That, on that basis, economic emancipation is the great goal to which

all political movement must be SUBORDINATE.”

“That all efforts to date have failed, for want of solidarity between

the workers of various trades within each country and of a fraternal

union between the workers of various countries.”

There is a formal linkage of theory and tactics: the only

differentiation made is in the mode of association, which is henceforth

to be the interest group — the trade union — whilst within the

International, general agreement was established through the affinity

group — the branch — into which motley elements poured. It has to be

pointed out, though, that this difference in the mode of association was

something of a consequence of the conditions in which the social

struggle was conducted under the Second Empire: so it would be incorrect

to see it as a derogation from the principle of class struggle,

especially as the “givens” cited above are indicative of the importance

that the internationalists gave to trade association.

But it was not long before two camps emerged within the ranks of the

International: on one side, the centralists, the

authoritarians,including Karl Marx who, in accordance with the formula

devised by his disciple Eccarius, called for “the conquest of political

power in order to pass laws for the benefit of the workers”: and, on the

other, the federalists or autonomists loyal to the spirit of the

International who fought against this tendency “in the name of the

social revolution we espouse, whose programme is: emancipation of the

workers by the workers themselves, outside of any directing authority,

even should said authority be elected and agreed by the workers.”

And the autonomists went on to add: “The society of the future should be

nothing more than the Internationals universalisation. So we ought to

take care to match that organisation as closely as possible to our

ideals. How could one expect an egalitarian, free society to emerge from

an authoritarian organisation? That would be an impossibility. It

behoves the International, as the embryo of the human society of the

future, to be, from this moment forth, the faithful reflection of our

principles of freedom and federation and to cast out any principle

leaning towards authority and dictatorship.”

The Party of Labour espouses these principles of autonomy and federalism

as its own.

Trade union recovery

In the wake of the events of 1870–1871, following the ghastly massacres

that followed the crushing of the Commune, the bourgeoisie, drunk on the

bloodshed, reckoned that it had purged the working class for good of any

inclination to press its claims. It forgot that the spirit of revolt is

a by-product of a bad social milieu and not the result of subversive

preaching and that it would inevitably return as long as the context

remained likely to favour its development.

By the final years of the reign of Napoleon III, the trade unions had

grown so much that they dared to organise themselves into a Federation

and, although that rudimentary agency bound together only the Parisian

unions, its propaganda activity and solidarity activity reached out into

the provinces. These federated unions were simultaneously affiliated to

the International: they took a hand in uprisings and, after the storm

had passed, those which had not foundered utterly had to hold their

tongues.

In 1872, a fore-runner of yellow unionism, Barberet thought that the

time had come — with the revolutionaries crushed or scattered — to

federate what few unions were left and steer them along the paths of

righteousness. Twenty five unions answered his call, but the moral order

was in such a fright about workers organisations that it banned the

Cercle de lUnion syndicale. Whilst no direct measures were taken against

the unions, their isolation and weakness was a comfort to the

government: they carried on existing on the fringes of the Code, merely

tolerated.

Between then and 1876 trade union activity showed itself in delegations

to the Expositions in Vienne (1873) and Philadelphia (1876), which

delegations created temporary liaison between the various groups, but,

reactionary though it may have been, they could scarcely have caused the

government a second thought.

Growing bolder, the plan emerged for a labour congress: it met in Paris

in 1876 and delegates from 70 Parisian unions and from 37 towns (with

mandates from one or more trades associations) took part in it. The

figures give some clue as to the growing vigour of the trade union

movement: one year earlier, in 1875, figures rather higher than the real

ones placed the number of existing unions at 35 in Paris and provinces

alike, manifest proof that the workers did not wait for the licence

granted under the 1884 legislation before setting up their unions. The

1884 law merely registered a fait accompli: the bourgeoisie, unable to

thwart the rise of the trade unions, put a brave face on things by

granting them legal recognition.

At the first congress in 1874 Barberet had pontificated: however,

objections were voiced to his presence and from then on, it was made

plain that authentic labour organisations jealous of their dignity and

autonomy would never condescend to allow themselves to be tamed.

At that time, the demarcation lines between political organisations and

trades associations were blurred: social studies groups and trade unions

engaged in joint propaganda, took part in workers congresses, etc. and

did so all the more agreeably for political concerns being relegated to

the background. The movement was plainly anti-parliamentary: all of the

revolutionaries joined forces to see off the barberettiste menace.

That danger averted — it was warded off once and for all at the

Marseille congress (1879) and the Le Havre congress (1880) — a number of

schools of thought surfaced. For a start there was the division between

the anti-statists, steadfast advocates of anti-parliamentarism (the

anarchists) and those who, with the seal of approval, of Karl Marx after

he put his “Minimum Programme into circulation, laid claim to the

designation of collectivists and leapt into the parliamentary arena,

hypnotised by the hope of capturing power. There was a rational basis to

that first split, in that it arose from divergent outlooks. It became

apparent that personnel who made everything secondary to capturing

public office and those who still staked all their hopes upon

revolutionary action could no longer travel the same road.

But if that split was explicable in terms of a difference of principle,

the same cannot be said of the splits that came after: they were simply

the consequences of regrettable but inevitable electoral competition.

The desire quickly to capture a majority of votes cast led to a

watering-down of the programme: the diehards, faithful to the “Minimum

Programme”, were called Guesdists, after their leader Jules Guesde, and

they hung the label of Possibilists on those who were more inclined to

follow Paul Brousse and Joffrin.

It was the Saint-Etienne congress in 1882 that their paths separated:

the Guesdists found themselves outnumbered there and after some stormy

proceedings they withdrew to hold a congress in Roanne.

A few years on, in 1890, a further split added to the dispersion of

worker elements: this split hit the Possibilist ranks at the

Chatellerault congress: the moderates turned into followers of Brousse

(Broussists) whereas the revolutionaries whose sympathies lay with

Allemane were described as Allemanists.

These internecine squabbles had a particularly damaging effect because

the trade union groupings were an integral part of the various feuding

factions and, quite naturally, professed to belong to this faction or

the other, in line with the preferences if the militants by whom they

were headed. This state of affairs led to an understandable weakening of

the trade unions: the more or less conscious workers were too inclined

to keep them at arms length — as were those who looked to a faction

other than the one that held sway within their own trade association.

Trades organisations, neutered by political jockeying, were thus reduced

to having scarcely any more influence than the social studies groups

with whom they rubbed shoulders when workers congresses were held.

Towards autonomy

One can only be wrong-footed for a certain length of time. The trade

unions gained strength. Being the essential coming-together, they are

too necessary a thing for the political jockeying acted out within their

ranks to do any radical damage.

The unions grew and, as they grew, becoming conscious of their raison

detre and the mission that has fallen to them, they dreamed of wriggling

free of political tutelage. The first sign of this was the organisation

of a congress that met in Lyon in 1886. Participation was open only to

trade union delegates: the main issue posed was the creation of a

Federation to liaise between the unions.

The government believed that this distancing of the unions from irksome,

discordant political concerns was going to serve its own plans for

domesticating the workers and, in the hope of a resurgence of

barberettisme, it advanced subsidies for the congress.

How cruelly disappointed it was! Examination of the 1884 law on trades

unions was the touchstone issue at the congress. This law, only recently

implemented, was gone over with a fine-tooth comb. It was established

that the unions had not at all waited for its promulgation before

expanding and that its only justification was a capitalist desire for

self-preservation and an ulterior notion that the trades union movement

might prove susceptible to be channelled through it.

Then it was decided that a nationwide Federation of trade unions should

be launched to marshal trades bodies on a class struggle basis against

the powerful organisation of the bourgeoisie, for the purposes of

offence and defence.

But, considerable though they were, the ravages of politics were not

yet, in everyones mind, sufficiently plain for any thought to be given

to preventive action against their repetition. No prophylactic steps

were taken and so the trade union Party which tended to make its stand

outside of the various schools of socialism continued to come under fire

from that quarter and the trade unions remained in thrall to those

schools. However, in spite of the climate of the Federation of trade

unions being still heavy with the miasma of politics, the thinking

peculiar to syndicalism was hatching and gathering weight there. Thus,

at its third congress, held in Bordeaux in 1888, the principle of the

general strike was passed: another motion, also passed, committed “the

workers to separate from the politicians.. and to organise trades

councils on a firm footing (these) alone will make up the great army of

social demands.” Again the following congress (Calais, 1890) enjoined

the workers, as of 1 May 1891, to “report to the factory as normal and

then to walk out, after eight hours on the premises, whether the boss

likes it or not.”

These trends in economic action were to grow, in spite of the opposition

mounted by the socialist (Guesdist) school of thought which at that time

was in the majority in the trade union Federation: this can be seen

plainly at the congress of Marseilles in 1892: in spite of the pressure

from the Guesdists, the efficacity of the general strike was again

affirmed and the futility of seeking public position proclaimed.

One blemish — a product of the preeminence afforded by the trade union

Federation to political concerns — ruled out adaptation of that

organisation to the needs of syndicalism which were becoming plainer and

plainer. It was a body connecting the trade unions only singly, so that

they remained isolated within the umbrella group (which was a federation

in name only) and it neglected to establish between these single unions

the links that were essential at local level as well as within each

trade. Now, since “the function creates the agency”, it was inevitable

that a grouping suited to the unions needs would be launched.

The Bourses du travail were already in existence, coordinating the trade

union forces at local level: trades federations too were already in

existence, linking the unions within the same trade right across France.

But these agencies were, if not isolated from one another, then at least

without regular contact with one another.

In 1892 the establishment of the Federation of Bourses du Travail went

half-way to meeting the unions requirements: although it grouped only

the Bourses du Travail or Local General Trades Unions, it quickly gained

considerable influence. This was because it addressed the aspirations to

economic union and turned a blind eye to political opinions. These

trends towards economic cohesiveness surfaced at the trade union

congress sponsored by the Federation of Bourses and held in Paris in

July 1893. The resolution below which was adopted there posed once and

for all and with clarity the fundamental status of class agency that the

General Confederation of Labour (CGT) would turn out to be:

“All labour unions must, with all possible urgency:

1) Affiliate to their trade Federation or, should none exist, launch

one: band together into a Local Federation or Bourse du Travail,

whereupon these Federations and Bourses du Travail ought to set

themselves up as National Federations:

2) The National Trades Federations, once in place, will have to come to

some accommodation with the Federations abroad and establish

International Federations. ”

In an effort at conciliation, the congress expressed the wish that the

Federation of Bourses du Travail and the Federation of trade unions

might amalgamate into a single organisation. Such an amalgamation was to

be attempted at the Nantes congress in 1894: but instead of the

rapprochement that was aimed at, there was a definitive split. It could

scarcely have been otherwise: the outlook of the tendencies present made

the falling-out predicable. The issue of the general strike was the

touchstone: a wide-ranging debate proved the theoretical and tactical

irreconcilability between political-parliamentary action and economic

action: the vote that endorsed the latter gave the victory to those who

went on to become the syndicalists: 67 votes were cast in favour of the

general strike and 37 against.

That spelled the end for the trade union Federation and the congress

realised that, so much so that it decided that a National Labour Council

would be launched. It vegetated for a year, up until the Limoges

congress in 1895.

Economic take-off

The falling-out at the Nantes congress went considerably further than

merely severance from the political elements: it involved a final breach

with the capitalist regime. The working class was to create its own

autonomous agencies which, for the time being, would be combat

organisations and, in the future, would garner enough revolutionary

strength to stand up to the bourgeoisies political and administrative

institutions and to destroy them or take them over as the need might be.

At the Limoges congress the launching of the General Confederation of

Labour (CGT) did not proceed without some resistance. Article one of the

confederations charter laid down the principle that was to breathe life

into trade union associations: the personnel making up the Confederation

must stand outside of all schools of politics. This triggered heated

arguments. In spite of everything, it was passed by a huge majority: out

of 150 votes cast, 124 were in favour and only 14 opposed.

Those arguing for pride of place to be given to political actions moved

that only the Confederation as such was obliged to keep out of politics:

as for the component unions, it would be up to them to make their own

decision. This argument was rejected. In practice, though, all too

often, this was the principle that was adopted. The congress had laid

down guidelines, but no one could — and no one tried to — enforce

obedience through authority. This itself was an indication of the

consciousness of the workers.

The important thing was to affirm the necessity for organising on the

economic terrain and eliminating all preoccupation with politics. As for

the germination and development of this principle, that was left to the

passage of time and to the initiative of the militants.

Over the following five years, the CGT remained stalled at the embryonic

stage. Its activities were virtually nil and most of its time was spent

on underlining a regrettable antagonism that had developed between

itself and the Federation of Bourses du Travail. This latter

organisation, which was at that time autonomous, was a rallying point

for all of the revolutionary activity of the trade unions, whilst the

CGT (which by this point was only an umbrella for the trades

Federations) was in a state of vegetation.

Over this period of time, the Confederation took its lead and its

guidance from elements which have since tended to be labelled as

reformist. Since the politicians were unable to take the organisation

over, they looked down their noses at it: some of their disciples were

part of the majority within it, however, but, irritated by the congress

of Limogess decision, they were unable to engage in proper politicking

and, lacking any real belief in the value of economic action, they did

not to encourage development of the Confederation.

It was only following the trades congress held in Paris in 1900, when

the Confederations own mouthpiece (La Voix du peuple) was launched and

when revolutionary elements flooded into and gained the upper hand

within the Confederation, that under this dual stimulation, that body

graduated from its larval stage.

From then on, it never looked back. In 1900, at the opening of the Paris

congress, it embraced only 16 national federations and 5 different

organisations: by September 1904, and the opening of the Bourges

congress, it embraced 53 trades federations or national unions, plus

fifteen single unions. Moreover, under the sway of revolutionary

elements, a sort of moral unity was created between the Federation of

Bourses du Travail and the CGT, and this was vital for the struggle and

was a prelude to what has since been termed “labour unity”. The

Montpellier congress in 1902 proclaimed the need for just such unity and

made it a reality by knitting together the Federation of Bourses du

Travail and the Federation of national trades federations (which is what

the CGT had amounted to up until then).

And so, nine years on, the motion passed by the trade union congress

held in Paris in 1893 was fleshed out, organisationally.

Since the Montpellier congress, the General Confederation of Labour

(CGT), the organisational structure of which seems to have settled ..

with only a few minor adjustments, as the need arises — has expanded

normally: from then on it was a force with which bourgeois society had

to reckon: it made its stand against capital and the State, determined

not merely to render them less harmful but to lay the groundwork for and

encompass their final ruination.

In the brief historical survey above, we have seen trades associations

banding together to establish an organism genuinely free of all tutelage

and tailored to the revolutionary task at which they work. Such a

panoramic overview is more revealing about the power of the Party of

Labour than doctrinal affirmations and shows that the economic approach

of the unions is no fleeting phase but rather the logical outcome of the

development of worker consciousness.

The new partys programme is concise: article one of the Confederations

statutes offers a summary of them:

The CGT embraces — outside of all of the schools of politics — all

workers cognizant of the struggle to be waged for the elimination of

wage-slavery and the employer class. That brief statement of principle

encapsulates the entire essence of syndicalist doctrine: it is the very

definition of it. As for the other articles of the CGT statutes, they

mirror the moment and are thus subject to amendment just as they would

be in any living organism. They are not to be taken as a prerequisite

framework, but rather as the labouring masses form of cohesion, the form

best suited to the demands of the current struggle. The Party of Labour

does not owe its power to its statutory framework: its strength arises

from the individuals who are its component parts and from the intensity

of the spirit of rebellion by which they are driven.

What sets syndicalism apart from the various schools of socialism — and

makes it superior — is its doctrinal sobriety. Inside the unions, there

is little philosophising. They do better than that: they act! There, on

the no mans land of economic terrain, personnel who join, imbued with

the teachings of some (philosophical, political, religious, etc.) school

of thought or another, have their rough edges knocked off until they are

left only with the principles to which they all subscribe: the yearning

for improvement and comprehensive emancipation. Which is why — without

erecting any doctrinal barriers, and without formulating any credo —

syndicalism looms as the quintessential practice of the various social

doctrines.

For it is not in theory only that the Party of Labour has a profile of

its own: its tactics and methodology are peculiar to itself and, far

from drawing inspiration from the democratic idea, they are the negation

thereof. But tactics and methodology are so natural that the workers,

even those most imbued with democratism, once they enter the trades

organisations, are subjected to the influence of their surroundings and

act just like all their colleagues do, as syndicalists.

The modalities of syndicalist action are not the expression of the

consent of the majority manifesting itself through the empirical

procedures of universal suffrage: they draw their inspiration from the

means by which, in nature, life in its many forms and aspects manifests

itself and develops. Just the way that life appears first at one point,

in one cell: just as, with the passage of time, there is always one cell

that is the agent of ferment and change; so, in a syndicalist context,

the first move comes from the conscious minorities who, through their

example, their thrust rather than through authoritarian injunctions)

draw the most frigid masses into their orbit and sweep them into action.

This tactical approach is Direct Action in action! From it flow all of

the modes of trade union action. Strikes, boycotts, sabotage, etc., are

all merely translations of Direct Action.

Appendix

THE CONFEDERAL ORGANISM — The network of the confederal organisation

that binds the unions one to another is as straightforward as can be,

given the demands of propaganda and of the struggle with which they have

to contend.

The CGT is made up of two sections: that of the trades Federations and

that of the Bourses du Travail.

Through affiliation to the Bourse du Travail (or Local Union of trade

unions) the various trades unions gain a facility of propaganda within a

city or specific region: this is a task that they would find difficult,

if not impossible, to tackle if they were to slide into a pernicious

isolation. That mainly educational undertaking consists of establishing

new unions and of honing the consciousness of the unionised so as to

draw the largest possible numbers of workers into the trade union orbit.

To this end the Bourse sets up reading rooms and lays on classes, helps

with anti-militarist propaganda by welcoming young barracked troops

under its wing, offering legal advice, etc.

Affiliation to the national trade Federation addresses, rather, the need

for combativeness and resistance. These Federations are an umbrella for

the unions belonging to the same trade or industry and they encompass

the whole of France, which makes them energetic fighting associations:

should a dispute arise anywhere, the solidarity of the masses is

mobilised to defeat the employers. Thus, the strength of a given union

is magnified by moral and material backing from its federated unions

right across France.

The only thing was that if the Bourses du Travail remained isolated one

from another and if the trades Federations did likewise, the

cohesiveness of labour, stopping at the mid-way mark, could never attain

a generalised strength, given that the local bodies would not be able to

reach beyond the boundaries of their own regions and the national bodies

would not see any further than the boundaries of their own trades. In

order to attain to a greater power, these several bodies federated with

one another, in accordance with their natures: the trades Federations

with trades Federations and the Bourses du Travail with other Bourses du

Travail.

It was at this level of the trade union organism that the General

Confederation of Labour (CGT) arose: it comprises both sections — the

section made up of trades Federations and that made up of the Bourses du

Travail. Each of these federal wings is topped by a Committee made up of

delegates from each affiliated organisat ion: these delegates are

subject to recall at all times: as a result, they remain in ongoing

liaison with the association from which they receive their mandate,

which is at liberty to replace them at any time.

The Federations wing and the federated Bourses du Travail wing are each

autonomous bodies.

Finally, at the last level we have the National Confederal Council: it

is made up of a coming-together of the delegates from both wings, and

within its remit fall general propaganda matters of relevance to the

working class as a whole. Thus, to cite some examples of the tasks that

fall within its remit, we need only note that the campaign agitating

against the placement bureaux and the eight hour day agitation campaign

were taken in hand by special commissions appointed by it to do the

needful.

Such, in broad outline, is the confederal organism: it is not a

leadership body but a body that co-ordinates and amplifies the working

classs revolutionary activity: it is therefore the very opposite of the

democratic agencies which, by dint of their centralisation and

authoritarianism, stifle the vitality of their component parts. Inside

the CGT, there is cohesion but not leadership: federalism prevails

throughout: at every level, the various bodies — from the individual,

through the trade union, the Federation or the Bourse du Travail, up as

far as the confederal wings — are all autonomous. Herein lies the secret

of the CGT powers of projection: the initiative comes, not from the top

down, but from anywhere and the vibrations of it are passed on by means

of a ripple effect through the masses of the Confederation.

CONGRESSES. — Every two years, the CGT organises a national congress

with the participation only of delegates from its affiliated trade

unions. The Congress is the equivalent of what the general assembly

would be at the level of the trade union: thanks to these meetings,

trade union members are brought into contact with one another and a

useful fermentation follows: currents of opinion emerge and guide-lines

are defined.

International solidarity. — The activity of the Party of Labour is not

confined within artificial boundaries: most of the trades Federations

are affiliated to an international Federation linking the various

national organisations and with ramifications everywhere. Moreover, the

Confederation is affiliated to the International Trade Union Federation

based in Amsterdam, which keeps the “confederations” around the world in

contact with one another. Thus is established and developed a living

network which materialises the International Workers Association more

firmly than ever.

This quotation, like the next one, is lifted from the Circular issued by

the Jura Federation congress held in Sonvilier (Switzerland) on 12

November 1871. The signatories included one Jules Guesde who

subsequently ... In return for his attempts at domesticating the

workers, Barberet was appointed (sometime around 1880) the mutualist

great Manitou at the Interior ministry. At the Paris congress in 1918,

an overhaul of the statutes abolished the Federation of Bourses du

Travail which was replaced by a section made up of Departmental Unions,

as Article 2 of the CGT statutes attests:

Article 2 — The General Confederation of Labour (CGT) is made up of:

1. National industrial Federations

2. The Departmental Unions of the various trade unions

And the make-up of the Confederal Committee was amended as follows:

Article 9 — The National Committee is made up of a coming together of

delegates from the Federations and the Departmental Unions. It meets

thrice each year, in March, July and November, and, extra-ordinarily, at

the invitation of the Steering Commission and the Bureau.

It is the executor of decisions made by national congresses. It takes a

hand in every aspect of worker life and pronounces upon matters of a

general order.