πŸ’Ύ Archived View for library.inu.red β€Ί file β€Ί murray-bookchin-state-capitalism-in-russia.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 12:33:59. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➑️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: State Capitalism in Russia
Author: Murray Bookchin
Date: Autumn 1950
Language: en
Source: Retrieved on 2016-10-28 from http://marxists.architexturez.net/archive/bookchin/1950/state-capitalism.htm
Notes: Published: Contemporary Issues 7, Autumn 1950 (under pseudonym M. S. Shiloh) Digitalisation: Adam Buick HTML: Jonas Holmgren

Murray Bookchin

State Capitalism in Russia

The problems of the social system in Russia have often been compared

with those created by revolutionary France more than a century and a

half ago. An understanding of both, it is said, requires perspective.

Historians are reminded that the years have dissolved the acrimony

heaped on the events of the Great French Revolution β€” that more 'good'

than 'harm' was done. Much the same is implied for Russia. Supporters,

even mild critics, of the Stalin regime tell us that so 'new' a

phenomenon requires the test of many generations, that the judgement

nourished by immediate events, by 'passing' abuses, must be suspended

until lasting outlines appear. In place of the years and of abuses

engendered by 'expediency', a vast theoretical corpus has been brought

to the support of the Russian social system. We are invited to equate

the nationalization of industry to progress; economic planning to the

elimination of crises; mounting indices in steel, coal and petroleum

production to the well-being of the Russian people. In the meantime,

fact progressively contravenes theory. The nationalization of Russian

industry has not been marked by any sort of social progress. Russian

economic planning β€” such as it is β€” has sharpened crises known to the

capitalist world. And the mounting indices in heavy industry (little as

we are actually permitted to know about them) have been accompanied by

abject misery and worsening of conditions for the Russian people. To

anyone informed of Russian social life, the contradiction between theory

and reality has reached nightmarish proportions.

Moreover, just as theory has been used to distort the meaning of events,

so events have revenged themselves on theory. The most vulgar prattling

has been employed to override Russian reality from one aspect or

another, and with it, the means for social analysis itself. One has only

to examine the tortured ideas of Stalinism and its supporters on

economic theory, aesthetics, and, often enough, even science, to judge

the wholesale misapplication of thinking to all questions. The shoe is

invariably placed on the wrong foot and the adherent is invited to limp

through a host of broad economic, political, and cultural, as well as

specifically Russian, problems. It becomes a social responsibility in

every sense of the term to bring fact and theory into accord.

Although objective and systematic accounts have been available for some

time, there has been a marked failure to employ them adequately for the

purposes of generalization. By contrast, Stalinist theory was given the

semblance of a certain unity and comprehensiveness. The rather popular

notion that Russia is a 'managerial society' is unsatisfactory and

starts from the same premises as the Stalinist approach. Both assume

that Russia represents a historically-new social formation. The

'managerial theory', it is true, poses a significant issue: if the state

exercises full control over the economy, it is necessary to ask β€” 'Who

controls the state?' To this question, Stalinist apologists have no

reply; unless we are to give serious credence to the benign 'intentions'

of the Russian leaders or to the claim that Russia has the most

democratic constitution in the world. On the other hand, the 'managerial

theory' explains little of the energizing forces of the Russian economy:

of its dynamics and of Russian expansion abroad. From so purely negative

a definition, developed in reaction to the incredibility of the

Stalinist view rather than from a positive elucidation of the conditions

of Russian material life, it would be difficult to find serious points

of difference between a 'managerial society' and, for example, Ptolemaic

Egypt. The position fails to bring anything into relief β€” it lacks an

explanation of anything that is socially distinctive.

But if Russian society is not to be regarded as a 'new' historical

stage, what does it represent?

The contention made here is that Russia is integrally tied to capitalist

development, that its social system may be called state capitalism. Such

a judgement follows from two considerations. The first and most general

is the entire process of world capitalist development. The barbarization

of society, so graphically represented by Fascism and its Stalinist

predecessor, is anchored in the bourgeois mode of production. It

requires absolutely no departure from an analysis of capitalist

retrogression to explain all the phenomena of Stalinism. In point of

fact, Russia reflects this decline in every feature. The second and more

specific consideration is the backwardness of Russia. This

historically-retarded development, suffice to say for the present,

cannot be regarded as a bag of excuses for justifying 'contemporary

excesses' or, what amounts to the same thing, for keeping Russian

society in suspended animation β€” free from the compulsion of social law.

The 'intentions' or wishes of the Stalin leadership β€” whatever they may

be β€” may be disregarded. Under capitalism, backwardness has its own

laws, by which Russia, like Germany, Italy and Spain (each in a certain

sense) are relentlessly governed.

A discussion of Russia as a state capitalist system, therefore, presents

the challenge of large issues. At every point, the analysis lends itself

to homologous developments in England, America β€” indeed, in the entirety

of capitalist society. Concretely, there is almost no special starting

place. Developments in western Europe, among the 'democracies', suggest

the same problems that in Russia have achieved only greater poignancy.

Nationalization and the Background of Russian Capitalism

Russia to-day has a nationalized and, allegedly, planned economy. This

has, by common consent, been regarded as the unique characteristic of

Stalinist society; at once its point of departure from capitalism and

its most 'progressive' feature. Planning is, at most, a claim and may,

for the moment, be put aside. The nationalization of industry, however,

remains indisputable. The question at issue is: why is industrial

nationalization, per se, non-capitalist or progressive?

It is true that nationalization, at least juridically, precludes the

individual ownership of industrial enterprises. And such individual

ownership has been associated with capitalism and its consequences β€”

more generally, with private property in the means of production. But

many civilizations have been known where state ownership of the

productive forces, for one reason or another, became the dominant

economic institution without in any conceivable sense eliminating

problems engendered by individual property. Private property remained in

the real sense that the control of the productive forces yielded the

relatively autonomous decisions that characterize individual ownership.

The point to be made is that the apparent economic relationship of men

to the productive forces must be explained by the economic relationship

between men. At all times, of course, a certain technological level is

presupposed. Hunters, for example, cannot be expected to establish

feudal social relations. But to borrow again from the fruitful analogy

of the ancient world, the feudal social relations of Egypt dominated the

transitions from the centralized, state-owned lands of the Old Kingdom,

through the somewhat atomized Middle Kingdom, into the Empire and

completely centralized economy of the Hellenistic Age. Throughout, the

relationship between the broad mass of serfs and the ruling nobility and

priesthood remained same. Although these changes met many real needs,

feudal problems and relations persisted and dominated Egyptian society.

The point behind this analogy can be verified in the history of Russian

capitalist development.

If European capitalism of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries had

room for development, Russian capitalism, due to its belated appearance,

could find little sustenance in a precarious world market overcrowded by

superior rivals, and in an internal market inhibited by feudal

relations. True, Russian capitalism did not recapitulate the industrial

and political history of Europe. From the start, it was in possession of

a technically-advanced and highly concentrated plant. But from the

nature of the situation, this contained as many disadvantages as

advantages. Alongside the peasant, hungering for land of his own, was

added the ferment of the new labouring classes, to which the insecure,

restricted bourgeoisie was incapable of granting reforms. Fearing its

own masses, confined by world imperialism which clung desperately (as

the general situation worsened) to privileges acquired in an earlier

period, incapable as a result of its weakness of effectively forcing its

way into the perpetual race for markets, the Russian bourgeoisie was

compelled to cement many of its ties with the Czarist regime. More often

than not, this was a source of extreme frustration. The regime and

nobility had its own fish to fry, and the relationship often presented

the character of two dogs sharing a bone. But if the bourgeoisie

generally strives to secure itself by concentration and monopolistic

practices, the narrow margin of industrial survival imperatively

dictated the formation of great combines in Russia that increasingly

paralleled and merged with the state. The two acted upon each other: as

conditions worsened in the respective sphere of each, an

interpenetration tended to occur.[1]

These were the tendencies of pre-revolutionary capitalist development.

They must not be mistaken for a fait accompli. Quarrels, differences as

to ways and means, eternal exasperation with the inefficiency of Czarism

precipitated bitter and often violent controversies. Lurking behind

these differences lay the prospect of an internal market, free from

feudal restrictions. But lurking behind this market was the fear of a

Jacquerie and an urban uprising which variously β€” but, on the whole,

negatively β€” coloured the political activity of Russian capitalism.

The focus of all Russian political activity, of course, was the

countryside. Could the bourgeoisie 'imitate' its French brethren and

give the land to the peasants? In point of fact, the French bourgeoisie

had not liquidated the land problem. The breakdown of the feudal estates

was consummated by the Jacobins at the cost of bloody conflicts with the

capitalist class. Under the leadership of Robespierre, Danton and

HΓ©bert, the revolution had over-extended itself, gaining an

indispensable margin for the play of radical social forces. In so doing,

it managed to override the fears, rural interests and narrow

conservatism of the bourgeoisie. But afterward the revolution

retrenched, retreating to the only forms possible at the time.

This, it might be supposed, could also provide a model for the Russian

Revolution. The parties of the Russian 'sans-culottes' would endeavour

to establish a radical democracy, largely over and against the

reactionary summits of Russian capitalism. Land would be distributed

among the peasants and improved working conditions introduced in

industry. The bourgeoisie, no doubt, would fume and storm. It might

endeavour to raise another Lyons and the nobility, certainly, another

VendΓ©e. But the economic axis of such a revolution could only be the

full extension of capitalist relations to the countryside. Its most

obvious result: the creation of a firm peasantry at the expense of the

feudal elements.

Certain sharp differences, however, are evident. The French Revolution

occurred in 1789: the Russian Revolution, in 1917. The two were

separated by a century and a quarter of capitalist development. The

French Revolution coincided with the first upswing of the development;

the Russian Revolution with its decline and retrogression. Both aspects

of the cycle were planted in these events. In consequence, the Russian

Revolution might give an initial β€” perhaps not inconsiderable β€” impetus

to industrial activity. At worst, conditions would portend the

tug-of-war and instability following the overthrow of the Spanish

monarchy in 1931. But under bourgeois conditions, instability in Russia

was inevitable. The whole character of world economic conditions

nurtured the persistence and eventual growth of conditions that were

already clearly in focus during the last years of Czarism. In effect,

this meant increasing monopolization, state intervention to support

sagging industries and, finally, the nationalization of industry and

totalitarian policing of the standard of living.

This is essentially the gamut of Russian events after 1917. The

conditions of the war precipitated a long standing crisis, pushing the

feudal system into the abyss. They served to arouse hopes in the Lenin

group that the inevitable over-extension of the democratic revolution

would be consolidated economically by a different type of revolution in

Europe. The ebb of the European revolution, however, left the

Bolshevists with little more than what they had in any case: namely, a

capitalist economy rounded out by land seizures in the countryside. The

fact was clearly acknowledged by the New Economic Policy of 1921. An

open market was not only recognized, but there is every indication to

believe that a policy of tolerating small merchant and individual

peasant enterprises was calculated for a length of time greater than

permitted it by the Stalin regime.[2] The nationalization of industry,

while precipitately introduced on the strength of other, more radical

hopes β€” as well, it may be agreed, as many immediate expediencies

accelerated β€” an economic development which confronted Russian

capitalism in any case.

There can be no question that we are simplifying events which might have

at least retarded the depth of totalitarian development in Russia had a

different insight prevailed. In England, for example, we are witnessing

much the same line of development for industry. Left to itself, British

capitalism is apparently moving with less of an edge than did the

Stalinist reaction of 1925-7. The possibilities for intervention are

more pronounced than for Russia during those years. Further speculation

as to the course of the Russian Revolution, however, can be left to

those who are living with, rather than learning from, the past. It is

only necessary to stress, here, the full coincidence of industrial

nationalization with the entire background of Russian capitalist

development. The presence of capitalism in Russia depends not on

nationalization per se β€” which may reflect reaction and retrogression as

well as progress β€” but on other factors, which accordingly make for one

or the other.[3]

Capitalism in Russia

The burden of any discussion of Russia as a state capitalist society

devolves upon three issues: the existence and weight of competition, the

anarchy bred by the 'Plan', and the difficulties, disproportions and

crises in reproduction created by competition for sources of raw

material and skilled labour. The consequences of these problems, even if

considered only by themselves, are ramified through all channels of the

economy with growing intensity and reach their summit in 'factional'

struggles, disputes, liquidations and regroupings that β€” like the

incessant jockeying for power among capitalist groups in Europe and

America β€” have become characteristic of Russian life. The state,

supporting the economy as a whole, reflecting by its function the

weakness of the entire economic structure, becomes the arena in which

the maladjustments of the system take form. It is not so much a 'Plan'

that passes between the managers, supply agencies, Glavks (Glavks are

administrative boards directly below People's Commissariats). and

People's Commissariats, as antagonisms and rivalries between individual

capitalists and blocs of capitalists attempting to secure and advance

their positions.[4]

In theory, the Russian manager is supposed to have very little

independence. Dr. Marshak describes the position of the manager as

follows:

'The Soviet manager is unable to manipulate freely the size of his plant

or his inventories. Nor can he take advantage of market situations,

current or prospective, by bargaining with sources of supplies or with

customers for better prices, or by winning customers through low prices,

and sources of supplies through high ones. To be sure, with supply

chronically lagging behind demand, it would in any case be pointless for

a manager to reduce prices in order to win customers. On the other hand,

to win preference for a source of supplies by bidding up prices for raw

materials would not be pointless. β€” But it is forbidden.'[5]

Russian law, or the official administration of industry, suggests an

even more severe picture. Sales contracts, plant property, production

and labour efficiency norms, the number of workers to be employed,

average earnings and the annual payroll β€” in fact, nearly every detail

of the industrial process is supposed to require state approval. Where

this is not pure juridical fiction, it affords a restricted picture. It

would be surprising to conclude that all elements in Russian capitalism

reflect a homogeneous pattern of status and economic control. The

capitalists of Russia, like those elsewhere, maintain variegated

relationships among themselves. Many are subject to the crass authority

of higher elements. Others, probably managers of large, heavy industrial

enterprises, are relatively independent. Assuredly, the People's

Commissars, the Ministers and those who are so situated as seriously to

influence the power relationships between competing blocs, correspond to

the monopolists and commanding bourgeois elements of western capitalist

states. Different 'frames of reference', therefore, exhibit different

views. To a purely juridical mind, German and Russian economic

regulations seem to agree point by point. If we were not familiar with

the clearly capitalistic nature of the German economy under Hitler, Nazi

law would engender the belief that the German economy reflects some sort

of 'managerial society'. From the standpoint of lesser managers, or

those who have not ferreted out the possibilities inherent in any given

situation, the full burden of the totalitarian regulations descends on

their shoulders. To be sure, Stalinist society is more centralized than

elsewhere. But by the same token, influence, power, exploitation and

competition is more severe.

It would be absolutely unpardonable and superficial to discount the

influence of the plant manager as a member of the Party, his connections

in the government, and, above all, the countless tricks and manoeuvres

included in such relationships. But even according to juridical

arrangements, the manager is no mere automaton of the planning bodies

and state. Bienstock, discussing the growth and recognition of

managerial independence, writes: 'Most important, the manager became the

only person responsible for the operation of the plant in all its

subdivisions. The manager's authority within the plant has increased. He

rules the whole production process, bears responsibility for the

technological process, for quantitative fulfilment of the plan, and for

the quality of the goods produced. ... '[6] Since 1938, a sinking fund

is withdrawn from plant output β€” estimated at about 5 per cent. of

initial capital value β€” 40 to 60 per cent. of which is at the manager's

disposal for capital replacement as well as repairs. The manager, even

according to economic regulations, disposes of considerable resources at

any given plant level. It is obvious that the lure of a more commanding

position, in a country where disproportions in income are matched only

by the extremities of want, creates and even necessitates bitter

competition for further access to such resources.

The position of the Russian manager gains greater reality when the

authority he possesses is dynamized by the actual relationship of plant

production to the 'Plan'.

Planning in Russia has either been grossly exaggerated or totally

misunderstood. This has, in so many words, been admitted in the day to

day reports of the Russian press itself β€” all theoretical

pronunciamentos and considerations aside. 'Our planning is still to a

great extent clerical and statistical work', reports Meizenberg,

'absolutely divorced from economic practice.'[7] In this connection,

Bienstock observes: 'The practice of planning has gradually brought the

leaders of Soviet economy to the conclusion that tasks set by plan must

be adjusted in accordance with practice, that planning cannot be

confined to orders but requires continual checking in every phase of

production. In theory, these rules were formulated unequivocally, long

ago. As a matter of fact, principles were not applied until the outbreak

of war in the summer of 1941.'[8] The remark gains significance because

it is now known that, if anything, planning was considerably relaxed

during the war conditions. On an earlier page, the same writer notes

that 'Many plants have been given the initiative in working out their

own production programmes in line with directives of the previous years,

without waiting for new orders from above; they transmit their

programmes to the Glavk or directly to the People's Commissariat. The

Glavk checks and, if necessary changes plans, taking into account supply

possibilities unknown to the plant, the possibility of co-operation

between plants, financial resources, regional needs, etc.'[9]

The Russian manager must operate outside the 'Plan'. 'Commodity funds

(stocks) are often apportioned only five or six days before the

beginning of a quarter: "realization" (delivery) is sometimes greatly

delayed. Ordinarily, delivery is obtained only towards the end of a

quarter, say in its last three or four weeks. The amount of goods

apportioned for a quarter is almost below a plant's real needs, because

the People's Commissariat and Glavk usually fear that the manager's

application for goods, especially scarce materials, is exaggerated.'

(Bienstock β€” our emphasis, M.S.)[10] Again: 'To obtain goods, he (the

manager) must often send representatives to supplying factories or to

agencies of People's Commissariats and Glavks. Many plants have

permanent representatives in Moscow or other supply centres with the

special task of securing the timely supply of goods, of "pushing" orders

for materials, of arranging shipments, etc. And, of course, the plant

management must maintain a storage organization. A plant manager who

does not get needed goods in time is often compelled to break rules and

seek new ways to supply his plant. There is thus a contradiction between

theory and practice. Theory has, recently taken a few steps toward

practice, e.g., the direct agreements.'[11] The author cites several

examples to illustrate the magnitude of these problems (and, we may add,

operations). ' "During the first eight months of 1940, the Tractor Works

spent 200,000 roubles on telegrams and 250,000 roubles on travelling

expenses." The same story was told half a year later of another giant

plant, the Rostov Works for Agricultural Engineering. ...'[12] In the

course of several articles on Russia in the Herald Tribune, Newman cites

Izvestia to the effect that one third of the ten thousand daily arrivals

in Moscow by railway and plane were on 'unnecessary' government

business. Izvestia makes the accusation that these arrivals waste

millions of rubles in sprees and excursions.

An entire body of market relations underlies the reproductive mechanism

of Russian industry. According to Bienstock, the '... turn-over of many

supply organizations, particularly local offices, is so insignificant

that they are compelled to transgress their jurisdiction to justify

their existence. They buy materials and equipment not needed in their

own branch of industry and sell to plants of other branches. They

become, in a sense, ordinary dealers.'[13] The reports that consistently

appear in the Russian Press are only a surface picture of idle plants or

factories working far under capacity, while goods and raw materials

circulate throughout the country without any apparent destination ...

other, undoubtedly, than a profitable buyer. The incidents are

notorious, frequently embracing some of the most important industrial

projects of the Stalinist regime. An example cited by Bienstock is worth

quoting in full: 'On 3rd June, 1938, the Council of People's Commissars

issued a decree concentrating sale of ferrous metals in a new Board.

Some six months later, the head of this board, S. Volikov, complained

about "individualistic methods" of procuring metals. Metals were sent

from one end of the Union to the other without reason or plan. Often

large quantities were brought from the Urals or Krivoi Rog (Ukraine) to

Moscow as a storage and supply centre, only to retrace a portion of the

original route to get to a consumer.'[14] How often? How 'large' were

the quantities? Volikov, apparently, did not say. But like the daily

'sprees' to Moscow (and only to Moscow?) there is good reason to believe

that such 'infractions' are enormous; in our opinion, decisive. Harry

Schwartz, for example, recently reported in the N.Y. Times that

complaints in the Russian Press indicate one-third (another third) of

the secretaries of collective farms in the Ukraine were transgressing

the rights of collective farm members in 'violation' of the law. Newman,

again, reports charges in Pravda that 'heaps' of vegetables and fruits

were spoiling on railway platforms of the South Western, North

Caucasian, Moscow-Kiev, Tashkent, Askhabad and Turkestan-Siberian lines

in 1947. At the same time, it is indicated, the periodical Bolshevik

claimed that 20 per cent. of railway stock was idle and an even higher

proportion was the case for motor transport!

Throughout, profit reigns supreme. 'The government ...' writes Yugow,

'fixes the factory price for some item at 20 roubles, viz., 14 roubles

production costs, 2 roubles planned profit, and 4 roubles (20 per cent.)

turnover tax. If plant management reduces the cost from 14 to, say, 10

roubles, the profit becomes 6 roubles, of which 2 are planned profit and

4 "above the Plan".'[15] From this it follows: 'The desire to increase

profits has become a real incentive to more responsible, active, and

careful management.'[16] Yugow provides us with examples from heavy

industry: 'In coal mining, for each per cent. of reduction of real cost

of production below planned cost, the manager, assistant manager, chief

and assistant engineers get a bonus of 15 per cent. of monthly salary.

In iron and steel industry, the figure is 10 per cent. Furthermore, for

each per cent. of overfulfilment of planned output, the bonus for a

coal-mine manager and his immediate assistants is 4 per cent. of salary.

In iron and steel, bonuses for extra output are calculated

progressively. If pig-iron production exceeds Plan by 5 per cent., the

monthly salaries of a section head, assistant section head, engineer and

electrical engineer are raised 10 per cent., for each per cent. of

excess output. If the production excess is 10 per cent., the bonus for

each per cent. of excess output is 15 per cent. of monthly salary, etc.

... No less important is the effect of plant profits on managerial

influence, prestige and power.'[17]

The distinction between managers and capitalists or between bonuses and

profits seems to be blurred by the information at our disposal. Does it

mean, as the 'managerial theory' implies, that all capitalists become

managers; that profits, in the socially-significant sense of the term,

become mere bonuses?

Actually, this is only a pseudo-problem. Between the extremes of an

industrial manager in a small, circumscribed shoe-factory and a People's

Commissar, the distinction is quite clear. It is necessary that the

'spectrum' of Russian industrial authority be viewed under the aspect of

qualitative differences rather than similarities that blend one shade of

control into another. If the premises of competition, disproportions,

direct agreements, etc., are granted, we need only compare the

historical effect of Stalinist society with those produced in known

capitalist sectors of the world. Should they coincide, the ostensible

'chain' of authority that juridical fiction reduces to the common

denominator of 'manager' requires the assumption of differentiation

between managers and capitalists. The presence of specific social forces

and their effects summons, as it were, the ruling class and its

capitalistic character β€” concealed (at most only to economic

theoreticians) by the impersonality of the system and the anonymity of

the regime β€” into real life. Neither the propaganda of the apologists

nor the 'intentions' of their leaders can alter such indispensable

distinctions.

Russia and the Retrogression of Capitalism

At first glance, a comparison between Russia and trends in world

capitalism presents many divergencies. Among these, the most conspicuous

are:

First, the decline in the standard of living ,on an international scale.

Stalinist propaganda, on the other hand, celebrates a steady rise in the

well-being of the Russian masses. The comparison, we are reminded, must

be made between pre-revolutionary and contemporary Russia rather than

between Russia and advanced capitalist states. Once this criterion is

adopted, we are assured, there can be 'no doubt' that the material

conditions of the people have improved steadily.

Second, since imperialism is characterized by the export of capital,

Russia cannot be viewed as an imperialist state. This, once stated,

often seems to suffice. Russian expansion is ascribed to military

exigencies, the fear of war, the desire to spread 'communism', etc. β€”

but not to imperialism in the scientific sense of the term.

Finally, all accounts of Russia never cease to point to the continual,

'unprecedented' growth of industry at a time when the tendency elsewhere

has long been toward industrial contraction. The endless panegyrics, at

least, indicate mounting, swollen statistics in every field of

production. Each five year plan is completed in four years, and every

plan is made to mark a milestone over earlier conditions. This has even

impressed opponents of the regime β€” so we are told by friends of the

regime.

By separating crass fact from pure fiction and qualitative analysis from

the blinding storm of meaningless statistics, a second glance discloses

basic similarities between Russia and world capitalism.

1. The standard of living in Russia. Now on this question, there are

sound reasons for believing that if the material conditions of the

masses have shown a steady improvement, Russia is a striking exception

to the trends in world capitalism. In an economy based on competition,

only a cold-blooded selection by destruction operates. To exist, in

effect, means to survive; and to survive means to absorb rival capitals.

The 'ideal' of bourgeois 'enterprise' is full control over the

productive process and market. This alone, the system dictates, can

assure survival, and provide the security and stability which all

elements of the system continually endeavour to achieve. In time, the

elements of the system change their character. Numerous capitalists are

transformed into a handful of large capitalists, commanding whole

branches of industry, national monopolies and international cartels. The

growth of monopolies and cartels only serves to intensify the degree of

rivalry and instability. Huge masses of capital, formerly controlled by

many individuals, are now pitted against each other by a few

monopolists. The system must increase its demands upon all the means at

its disposal; demands, in turn, which are always insufficient to meet

the growing dimensions of the struggle. Reforms, permissible in an

earlier context, are withdrawn; exploitation is intensified; living

standards are depressed.

Oddly enough, the Stalinist regime has maintained a statistical

conspiracy against the apprehension of facts concerning the standard of

living in Russia. Despite much official propaganda, photography and

guided tours of pre-war vintage, we are aware of no official indices

tracing the material conditions of the people in any way comparable to

the information provided by most, if not all, capitalist countries. So

far as direct analysis admits, the economic position of the masses is

shrouded in mystery; cast in vague proportionate accounts and classified

into statistically-useless categories. The indirect analysis of Russian

data, however, is of remarkable interest. On the basis of Hubbard's data

comparing the average food consumption of Petrograd textile families

during Czarist days with later periods, Peter Meyer has demonstrated

that between 1929 and 1937 the average standard of living declined to 34

per cent. below pre-revolutionary days. The same analysis shows an

increase of 54 per cent. from the Revolution to 1929.[18]

Material in Colin Clark's studies of Russian statistics show a decrease

of around 20 per cent. in food consumption per head between 1913 and

1934.[19] Whatever the differences between both analyses, the depth of

the downward trend is unmistakable. To bring matters as much up to date

as is possible, Vera Micheles Dean observes β€” again, on the basis of an

indirect analysis of Russian nominal wages (!) β€” that 'if 1938 is taken

as a 100, the index of increase in nominal wages is 165 and 175,

depending on the categories of work. Owing to the continuance of high

prices, however, and to various curbs recently [1947 β€” M.S.] placed on

individual purchases real wages have actually undergone a sharp

decline.'[20]

Recent Press reports from Russia indicate that the regime has placed the

monetary policy on the Gold Standard, accompanied by 'drastic' price

reductions. We must confess that on the basis of previous 'price

reduction' policies, we view this latest 'achievement' with considerable

scepticism. On 16th September, 1945, for example, the price structure

was also overhauled. Miss Dean observes: 'The price of certain essential

rationed goods were sharply raised on an average of 180 per cent. over

previous prices β€” with the effect of further draining off money in

circulation. By contrast, prices of unrationed goods in commercial

government stores were reduced by 30 to 55 per cent. While the upward

revision of prices of rationed goods and the downward revision of

unrationed goods were intended to close the gap between the two sets of

prices [an incredible explanation by the regime! - M.S.] the gap remains

substantial."[21] It is reasonable to question if the gap is being

closed by lowering or raising the price of commodities within the

purchasing range of the masses. Thus, on 17th July, 1948, the Stalinist

government announced a 10 to 20 per cent. reduction of prices in state

stores. The reduction was confined to such items as bicycles,

phonographs, watches, caviar, Moskvich automobiles, hunting guns,

cameras, perfumes, cosmetics, stoves and ... beer and vodka.[22]

In the infamous currency 'reform' of December, 1947, prices remained

essentially the same as before except for bread and a few staple items.

W. Bedell Smith notes that the tremendous hardships imposed by the

production norms established for 1950 led to such demoralization that

the Government had to change 'its production plans to increase the

amount of consumer goods available for purchases. ... These measures

gradually improved the production situation to the point where the

Government finally felt able to act drastically to lower the purchasing

power of the Soviet people in order to reduce the general demand for

consumers' goods and relieve the pressure on light industry. The

currency reform undertaken in December, 1947, accomplished this. The

existing ruble currency was declared obsolete without warning and new

currency was issued that was exchanged at the rate of one new ruble for

ten old rubles. State bonds were devaluated by two thirds. Bank

deposits, however, were exchangeable at equal value, but only up to

3,000 rubles with a smaller return on larger amounts. Food rationing was

removed at the same time.

'The farmers were wiped out, as their money was not in banks but in

state bonds and currency. To pay taxes and meet current expenses, they

sold food, so that for a brief period immediately after the monetary

change there was a flood of food in city markets for the first time in

years. This lasted only a short time, and thereafter the industrial

workers found that an even more drastic form of rationing actually

existed, as only a limited quantity of each kind of food was sold to one

person.'[23] The same 'rationing' apparently did not apply, so far as we

know, in the commercial government stores catering to the Stalinist

millionaires, where white bread was easily obtainable at 7.5 times the

value of the same type of bread 'for sale' in regular stores. But is it

necessary to enter into the income differentials of an economy which

bountifully provides for the few who are privileged with truly

astronomical incomes?

2. Imperialism and the export of capital. In this connection, there has

been so much misunderstanding, that a number of general remarks are in

order.

The course of capitalist development evokes many contradictions that

shape and give it form. Since competition requires the steady

replacement of labour by machinery, at least two simultaneous effects

are evident. The rate of profit declines and millions are deprived of

employment. As the internal market contracts, the entire productive

process tends to follow in its wake.

Attempts to compensate for this contraction turn the bourgeoisie to the

international market particularly the super-profits of colonial trade

and industry. It is apparent, of course, that capitalism always

endeavoured to reap these imperial profits. The wealth derived from

colonial exploitation was a prerequisite for the primitive accumulation

that launched capitalist development in the modern era. The point to be

made, however, is that when the internal market contracts, imperialism

comes into its own as an imperative force, an absolute precondition for

the very life of the system. For a while, imperialism yields a spurt to

the economy, extending the limits of the internal market and providing

new bases for industrial expansion. But in time this engenders further

contradictions: the obstacle of new, rival imperialisms and of

entrenched predecessors; increasing exhaustion due to frequent

conflicts, etc.

In its 'classic' period, imperialism was characterized by the export of

capital.[24] This, perhaps, more than the paeans of Kipling, encouraged

many liberal economists to believe that the 'white man's burden' could

only mean the full industrial development of the colonial world.

Actually, capital export was invariably one-sided, calculated not to

develop a competitor but so to upset aboriginal social relations that

dependence, rather than independence, was emphasized. The effect of

imperialism, therefore, has always been to create so much misery and

discontent, that national uprisings (of one degree or another)

continually follow in its wake. As the contradictions of capitalist

imperialism converge into a general crisis, the export of capital is

subordinated entirely to the needs of colonial regimentation, policing

and control. A sort of Roman parasitism prevails. All the material and

spiritual sources of resistance are numbed by planned starvation and

terror. Masses of population created by the capitalist mode of

production are reduced, enslaved or exterminated. Industrial activity is

rendered more and more one-sided and dependent, or β€” in many cases β€”

comes to a virtual standstill.

Many colonies have long since travelled part of the road to this new

barbarism. Indeed, the prototype of contemporary enslavement and

exploitation was nurtured for generations on the continents of Asia,

Africa, South America and in the archipelagoes of the Orient. But the

colonial countries do not stand alone. Under the heightened conditions

of present-day rivalry and instability, even the industrially-advanced

nations of Europe face oppression and reduction to a colonial status.

Europe enjoys the 'special status' wherein her stabilization involves no

less than the physical destruction of much of her industry. Thus, the

'Iron Heel' German capitalism prepared for Europe now descends upon

Germany. Industries are destroyed, millions bombed out and permanently

uprooted. The country is dismembered and occupied by foreign imperialist

armies. The 'loser' of the last war, however, is only the harbinger of

conditions that await nearly all the 'victors' of to-day. Eastern Europe

already shares the fate of Germany; England, France, Belgium β€” all

progressively become the economic and political instruments of American

policy. The economic one-sidedness and dependency that are imposed on

the colonial world eventually face the earlier colonial oppressors

themselves. The international market, like the internal market,

contracts; all social existence threatens to shrivel and decline.[25]

It is in this milieu β€” that is, under the conditions and possibilities

created by the second World War β€” that Russia definitely embarked upon

an imperialist course. Initially, this took form in collaboration with

fascist Germany, If the seizure of territory from Finland, Poland and

Rumania is often excused by military 'expediency', further negotiations

with the Nazis concerning the hinterlands of Asia leave absolutely no

doubt as to the imperialist character of Russian expansion. Ribbentrop's

appreciation of Russian 'natural spheres of influence' is very concise:

'The focal points in the territorial aspiration of the Soviet Union

would presumably be centred south of the territory of the Soviet Union

in the direction of the Indian Ocean.'[26]

To-day, the imperialist activities of the Stalinist regime occur, as is

the case with the rest of Europe, under the shadow cast by the

polarized, concentrated power of the United States. Beside this

'American colossus', rivalry must generally find circuitous routes:

infiltrate into weak positions; operate in the crevices and around the

fringes of American control. The phenomenal privileges allocated to

Russia, however, are explicable only in terms of the political

limitations of the United States. The Stalinist regime largely holds

those positions where the need for the naked application of force places

the bourgeois-democracy of the United States at a current disadvantage.

To employ the more precise formulation of Ernst Zander: 'The secret of

the situation, as of America's weakness, consists in Russia having

become her most reliable and indispensable policeman in Europe and Asia.

It is predominantly from this that Russia derives her 'astounding'

strength in the haggling with other Powers β€” no other country can be

entrusted with the ruthless police function once the Stalin regime

collapses.'[27] In effect, the Stalinist regime complements and is, for

the present, indispensable to American imperialism. As in 1939,

Stalinism remains a precondition for world reaction and retrogression;

in the first case, precipitating World War II, and to-day, assuming the

functions of Hitler during the thirties.

In this context, where expansion goes hand-in-hand with total parasitism

dictated by rivalry and survival, where the dismemberment and

exploitation of advanced capitalist countries makes its appearance, the

export of excess capital resources becomes an ancillary feature of

imperialism.

3. The growth of Russian industry. If Russian industrial development

means anything, it refers first and foremost to armaments industries.

Much the same can be said for the entire capitalist world. The armament

industry is, to-day, the lubricant of the entire system and growingly

extends over consumer goods production precisely because it, alone, can

co-exist with a falling standard of living. Guns, tanks, aircraft β€”

weapons of all kind β€” explode in waste. They require only the

intervention of the state as a purchaser. The state, on the other hand,

becomes a buyer by virtue of the revenue it exacts from the system as a

whole; principally, by milking the masses dry in true publican fashion.

In the United States, this essentially takes the form of taxation; in

England, rationing and wage fixing; finally, in Russia and Germany,

naked police supervision over the living standards of the people. The

poverty of the masses is 'planned' β€” and this, by far, is the major

function of planning.

As greater recourse is had to direct measures, the more armaments are

required to keep the masses in subjugation. These operations occur on a

world scale: occupation armies, arms for docile elements abroad, etc. To

be sure, profits too require distribution (again: 'planning') to sustain

the state as the essential agent for, and market of, the system. In this

rule, the state frequently appears as the disciplinarian of contending

bourgeois blocs. Although by no means the most desirable situation for

elements accustomed to a laissez-faire economy, choices cease to exist.

The system must be sustained as a whole.

Despite the fact that the Stalinist regime came very close to defeat in

1941-42, it compared only with Germany as a producer of armaments during

pre-war years. Between 1934-39, Russian armament expenditure was twice

that of England. 'It seems likely,' writes Prof. A. J. Brown, '... that

the Soviet Union spent at least as much on military purposes in the five

years or so before she was attacked as Germany had spent in the

corresponding period leading up to her aggression against Poland.

Germany's two-year lead in this race, however, gave her a formidable

advantage; at the time of her attack on the USSR her military

expenditure was probably still at least twice that of Russia though not

all of it β€” perhaps little more than two thirds, could be applied on the

eastern front. ... Whatever the margin of error in the calculation, it

is clear that the real cost of military preparation to the Soviet Union

was, like the subsequent burden which it bore in battle casualties, the

heaviest carried by any nation.'[28]

By examination of mere surface facts, economists judge that expenditures

on armaments comprised 6 per cent. of Russian national income in 1934;

12 per cent. in 1937; 25 per cent. shortly before the German invasion;

and β€” according to recent estimates in Life magazine β€” 25 per cent.

to-day.[29] These assumptions are much too cordial. We submit that the

Russian economy, from the very logic of the system, is oriented as a

whole toward armament production; that proportions, estimates and

statistical juggling are entirely meaningless. This situation gestates

in capitalist development itself β€” even in such bastions of industry as

the United States. Armament production is the life fluid of the

bourgeois mode of production, the co-efficient of all industrial output,

the one dollar that keeps the other three, four, five or ten in motion.

In Russia, however, such determinations are already fruitless. Armaments

are the absolute foundation of the economy itself; the Moloch to which

all resources are delivered β€” the sacrificial altar of all industrial

development.

It becomes absurd, from this standpoint, to regard the index of Russian

production as any hopeful sign of progressive possibilities. Steel, in

Russia, means guns or the means for making guns. If supporters of the

Stalin regime hope that perhaps (and not without a revolution against

the regime) the Russian people can be induced to use bayonets for

buttering bread, then it may be supposed that they will dwell in cities

of tanks, wear the drab grey of the army uniform and use helmets for

toilet bowls. ...

The Slave State

During the depths of the economic crisis, almost two decades ago,

letters to the American Press opined that the unemployed should be

placed on unseaworthy rafts and set adrift. In principle, the suggestion

was not original. Although required by German fascism ten years later

(efficiency often dictating crematoria), it was long anticipated in the

slave labour camps of Stalinist Russia.[30] For more than a quarter

century, Russian capitalism has followed the relentless logic inherent

in contemporary world development. Through countless purges,

'liquidations' and 'collectivization' drives, it has literally

appropriated the bodies of millions of men, women and children whom the

contracting system can no longer support on the basis of anything

remotely resembling a free labour market. Like chained gangs on ancient

latifundia, they are placed to work in the bleak hells of Siberia, in

mines and on wastes where life is scarcely maintainable and quickly

passes out of existence. From the Caspian Sea to the Solovietsky Islands

on the White Sea, hopeless masses of human beings, living and dying

under unbearable conditions, are devoured by the camp system. Whole

areas like the gold-mining region of Kolyma, are entirely 'populated' by

chattel slaves, comprising every profession and vocation, occupying

camps on the dimensions of cities (Magadan, for example), serviced,

maintained and renewed by the system. The law of population under

moribund capitalism dictates that millions, pushed outside society by

the general contraction, must be worked to death.

But the individual merely perpetuates the species which, locust-like,

slowly consumes all before it. For each who perishes, two appear. Slave

workers recruit slave technicians; the technicians recruit slave

engineers; these, in turn, are followed by guards, factories and more

camps. The new mode of labour reproduces itself not only from the inner

crisis of capitalism, but from the division of labour in modern

industry. It recreates the entire juridical, political and economic

fabric β€” adapting all institutions to its needs and, by giving rise to

its own qualitative forms, threatens to negate the capitalist mode of

production itself.

Slave labour already germinates in every phase of the Russian economy.

The internal passport, the work-book, countless labour regulations

ranging from 'job lateness' to 'sabotage', compulsory vocational

training, etc., etc. β€” all reduce the industrial worker to a captive of

his specific job.[31] On the 'collective' farms, practically every

pretence is cast to the winds. Yugow makes the following significant

observation of the Russian kolkhoz system:

'Productive machinery, with the exception of small tools, belongs as

already mentioned to the government, which, by agreement, works the land

and harvests for the kolkhozes. Labour is furnished by the kolkhoz,

which, in addition, is obliged to assign a specified percentage of its

manpower to certain compulsory tasks (road work, transportation, felling

timber, etc.) and to work in urban factories.'[32]

Centuries ago, capitalism took form in mediaeval Europe. By developing

the instruments of production, the possibility was poised for a historic

solution to want and exploitation. With the first World War, the curve

of capitalist development took a downward turn; and here, history has

reached the heights of irony. Alongside the most remarkable

technological achievements, undreamed of advances in electronics,

servo-mechanisms, turbo-engines and nuclear physics (in a word, all the

means of lightening human labour) reappear the institutions, want, and

exploitation of the past, infinitely intensified. Literally: moribund

capitalism generates its own negation in the forms of a dark, barbaric

past, when the material bases of mankind lay at the threshold of

pre-history. The system converges toward stability on the shambles of

whole cultures. Industry, as it were, 'thrives' in laboratories

surrounded by a desert of human agony and hunger, only to achieve

florescence in ... armaments. All the ingenuity of mankind β€” from

science, communications and technology to the products of the printing

press and the paint-brush β€” conspire to suck every isolated or remote

community into the rising slave state. Indeed, as compared with the

Stalinist regime, which can be considered no more than a mirror of

relentless developments in Europe and America (if authentic democratic

forces fail to intervene), the particularness of past mediaevalism will

appear as a veritable haven for the human spirit.

23rd June, 1950.

[1] Although Czarist Russia ranked far behind the West industrially, the

concentration of Russian industry exceeded the United States' during

corresponding periods. In 1910 for example, enterprises employing 500

workers or more comprised 53 per cent. of the number of workers in

industry, as compared with 33 per cent. in the United States. During the

first decade of the century, such concerns increased from 46.7 per cent.

to 53.5 per cent., while factories employing up to 50 workers, and

others from 50 to 500, declined from 14.3 percent. to 11.6 per cent.,

and from 39 per cent. to 34 per cent. respectively. The specific weight

of larger enterprises showed greater gains between 1901 and 1910.

Enterprises employing over 500 workers jumped from 3.5 per cent. to 5

per cent. of Russian industry. Those ranging up to 50 workers dropped

from 70.5 per cent. to 65.7 per cent.

Monopolies definitely appeared in the career of Russian industry as

early as the 'eighties (the sugar industry), although precedents had

been established by life insurance companies about a decade earlier.

After the turn of the century, 70 to 75 per cent. of all sheet metal

works were in the hands of a metallurgical monopoly: 'Prodamet'. By 1908

'Prodamet' held a dozen of the major metallurgical plants in its grasp,

having expanded in the meantime into many metal products. Along with the

'Trubopradazha' syndicate (pipes) and the 'Prodarud' syndicate (ores),

nearly all of south Russian metallurgy was monopolized in less than ten

years.

Monopolies spread all over the country and to all branches of industry

and transport. The 'Committee of Ural Ore and Metal Plants' syndicated

80 per cent. of roofing iron. Farm machinery concerns combined in 1907

to regulate at least 72 per cent. of many agricultural implements.

Ninety-five per cent. of railway cars were produced by the 'Prodvagon'

syndicate in 1907, to be matched by 90 per cent. of locomotive

production from another syndicate. The 'Med' syndicate controlled 97

percent. of copper production (1913); 'Produgul' (1906) accounted for 75

per cent. of southern coal output; a petroleum syndicate encompassed 65

per cent oil production, etc. Monopolies appeared in light industry as

well as heavy industry; in commerce as well as transport.

Although many Russian syndicates were interlocked with, and often

controlled by, foreign capital, there can be no question that the

Czarist regime was the major support of industrial monopoly. Russian

petroleum combines leaned on, and were aided enormously by, the state in

competitive struggles with Standard Oil. In the person of Bunge,

Vyshnegradsky and Witte, the government consciously abetted the

development and concentration of industry. Heavy orders, for all

practical purposes, formed so many subsidies to every branch of

metallurgy. Correspondingly, direct intervention by the state formed a

conspicuous part of Russian economic operations. Alcoholic beverages

were a near-monopoly of the regime. The government owned and processed

the output of many mines in Siberia, the Altai and the Urals. State

activity was felt in communications (railway and telegraph), credit (the

major banking concerns were owned by the state), forestry, large-scale

agriculture, etc. By the time of the Revolution, the state and the

bourgeoisie were interlinked in every phase of industry.

[2] The remarks of Lenin, in this connection, are of interest: 'We are

no longer attempting to break up the old social economic order, with its

trade, its small scale economy and private initiative, its capitalism,

but we are now trying to revive trade, private enterprise and

capitalism, at the same time gradually and cautiously subjecting them to

state regulation just as far as they revive.' (Lenin, Pravda, 7th

November, 1921.)

[3] Naturally, this also applies to Britain, where the Labour Party

presents its nationalization programme as a step toward social progress.

This programme, there can be no question, abets the introduction of many

totalitarian features, first adopted in Russia.

[4] No less a figure than Stalin gives us a picture β€” rather on the

microscopic level β€” of the cliques and blocs formed by Russian

officials. Thus:

'Most frequently workers are selected not according to objective

criteria, but according to accidental, subjective, narrow and provincial

criteria. Most frequently so-called acquaintances are chosen, personal

friends, fellow townsmen, people who have personal devotion, masters of

eulogies to their patrons, irrespective of whether they are suitable

from a political and business-like standpoint. ... Take, for example,

Comrades Mirzoyan and Vainov. The former is secretary of the regional

Party organization in Kazakstan; the latter is secretary of the Yaroslav

regional Party organization. These people are not the most backward

workers in our midst. And how do they select workers?

'The former dragged along with him from Azerbaijan and the Urals, where

he formerly worked, in Kazakstan thirty or forty of his "own" people,

and placed them in responsible positions in Kazakstan.

'The latter dragged along with him from the Donbas, where he formerly

worked, to Yaroslav a dozen or so of his "own" people also, and also

placed them in responsible positions. Consequently, Comrade Mirozoyan

has his own crew. Comrade Vainov also has his.' (J. Stalin, Mastering

Bolshevism, 1946 edition, p. 38).

[5] Bienstock, Schwarz and Yugow, Management in Russian Industry and

Agriculture, ed. by Feiler and Marshak, Oxford University Press, N.Y.,

1944, p. XIX.

This work is one of the most complete, and certainly one of the most

objective, accounts of economic relations in Russia. The authors, at

least Mr. Schwarz, seem to tend toward a managerial theory of Russian

society. The material cited here, we believe, demonstrates that such a

theory is untenable. The difficulties that appear to present themselves

in the minds of the authors are a traditional laissez-faire conception

of capitalism and a disposition, particularly noticeable in Marshak's

introduction, to take Russian law at face value; viz., '... it is

forbidden'.

[6] Ibid., p. 15.

[7]

L. Meizenberg, On the Economic Plan, in Planned Economy, 1939, No.

10, p. 12. (Quoted from B., S., & Y., p. 56.)

[8] B., S., & Y., etc., p. 57.

[9] Ibid., p. 50.

[10] Ibid., p. 63-4.

[11] Ibid., p. 62.

[12] Ibid., p. 64. Under the headline, 'Supply Woes Cut Soviet

Production', Mr. Harry Schwartz (not to be confused with Solomon Schwarz

of the work cited in the foregoing) gives the following report:

'Leningradskaya Pravda recently printed an article by a factory director

in Leningrad complaining of the harm done to production by supply

difficulties. Needed materials often arrive late, forcing factories to

cease or partly curtail output. ... In Leningrad alone, the article

reports, hundreds of government officials employ thousands of persons

who are supposed to facilitate necessary transactions between different

enterprises. But these work so poorly and are of so little help that

many factories have to spend large sums foraging for themselves so that

their work can continue.

'The situation is so bad, the director writes, that to meet its needs

for electric lamps, motors, transformers, optical equipment and

forgings, his factory has had to institute production of these items

itself. At the same time, he says, Leningrad has large factories

producing all these items, factories that are by no means always working

at capacity.

'At the root of the situation, he declares, is the overly bureaucratic

organization of the Soviet industrial supply system. Factories adjacent

to each other are not allowed to make arrangements directly to supply

each other's needs if they belong to different ministries. These and

other restrictions on enterprise managers' initiative tie them hand and

foot, he complains, and must be removed if matters are to be improved.

'A similar situation exists in the local consumer goods industry in

Moscow, the newspaper Moscovskaya Pravda reports.

'The supply system for these enterprises is working so badly that it is

estimated that they will fail to receive about 600,000,000 rubles worth

of raw materials that they require, about one-third their total needs.

Because of the lack of materials, these enterprises will not be able to

achieve this year's output plans for such goods as furniture,

phonographs, children's bicycles, aluminium utensils and knitted goods.

'To get around supply difficulties, some factories in Moscow do not

produce articles for which they are best fitted, but only such goods for

which they are able to obtain materials.

'Another consequence of the materials shortage, Moskovskaya Pravda

reveals, has been the development of large scale illegal barter trade

between enterprises. Hundreds of middlemen β€” known colloquially as

"clever lads" or "tipsters" β€” swarm around enterprises and ministries to

find out what surpluses and deficits each has. They arrange trades

between factories so desperate for needed goods that they are willing to

pay any price.' (N.Y. Times, 11th June, 1950.)

[13] Ibid., p. 63. In 1940, Russian supply organizations numbered some

5,000 agencies, employing 126,000 workers and involving costs of service

equal to 11 per cent. of turnover.

[14] Ibid., p. 63.

[15] Ibid., p. 79.

[16] Ibid., p. 82.

[17] Ibid., pp. 94-5.

[18] Peter Meyer, 'USSR: A New Class Society', Politics, March, 1944.

Meyer establishes a table on the basis of Hubbard's data showing that if

the cost of one week's food for 1913, 1929 and 1937 is taken at 3.40,

5.90 and 49.60 rubles respectively (Hubbard's data is 3.42, 5.89 and

49.56 rubles); and if industrial wages are taken at R25, R66 and R245

(Hubbard's data for the same period are R25, R77 and R245 β€” Meyer claims

that Hubbard 'gives the monthly wages for 1929 as 77 rubles, but he has

made an error, having taken the figure for 1930.'), the conclusions are

quite obvious. The index of food prices will be 172 and 1,449 for 1929

and 1937, respectively (with 1913 taken as 100); and the index of real

wages will be 154 and 68 for 1929 and 1937, respectively (with 1913

taken as 100). Mr. Hubbard's conclusions, however, are not too clear. He

writes:

'On an average, the 1937 prices of essential clothing and foodstuffs

were at least five times the 1929 prices, while the average wage was

only slightly more than three times the 1929 level. In other words, the

purchasing power of the worker's income in 1937 was about 65 per cent.

of 1929. The retail price index for all consumers' goods in 1929 was

about 200 (1913, 100) and the wage index about 308. This would seem to

indicate that the 1929 wage purchased about half as much again as in

1913; but as the 1937 wage had only about two-thirds of the purchasing

power in 1929, it looks as though real wages in 1913 and 1937 were

pretty well at the same level.' L. E. Hubbard, Soviet Labour and

Industry, MacMillan, London, p. 165, 1942.)

[19] Colin Clark, Critique of Russian Statistics. MacMillan, London, pp.

25-6, 1939.

[20] Vera Micheles Dean, 'Russia's Internal Economic Problems', from

Foreign Policy Reports, 1st July, 1947.

[21] Ibid., p. 108. For a truly curious excuse: unemployment insurance

in Russia was abolished (1930) 'in view of the disappearance of mass

unemployment in the U.S.S.R.'. Decree of People's Commissariat of

Labour, 11th October, 1930. See our section on slave labour.

[22] According to the N.Y. Times, 18th July, 1948, a Russian worker must

work two and one-third hours to purchase a bottle of beer.

[23] N.Y. Times, 14th November, 1949.

[24] The emphasis placed on the export of capital, in discussions around

imperialism, has often been at the expense of other features of equal β€”

and, under present circumstances, greater β€” importance; viz., industrial

concentration, monopoly, the re-division of the world, etc.

[25] The process, to be sure, is uneven and combined. Repressions begun

in the colonies are taken up in Europe, only to extend from Russia and

the Balkans back to China, Indonesia and Africa,

[26] Memorandum of the Final Conversations Between Reich Foreign

Minister von Ribbentrop and Chairman of the Council of People's

Commissars of the U.S.S.R. and People’s Commissar for Foreign Affairs,

Herr Molotov, on 13th November, 1940, from Nazi-Soviet Relations,

1939-41 (German Archives) p. 25, U.S. Department of State.

[27] Contemporary Issues, Vol. 1, No. 1, 'Concerning Germany and World

Development', by Ernst Zander.

[28] A.J. Brown, Applied Economics, Rinehart and Co., 1948, pp. 31 and

36.

[29] Life, 27th February, 1950.

[30] Slave labour was undoubtedly intended as a permanent feature of

German fascism. It is not through regard for, but in disregard of, the

interests of German capitalism that the 'surplus' population of East

Germany is permitted to exist (at Allied sufferance) 'only' as ... a

starving mass of refugees. The destruction of 4,000,000 Jews comprises

no more than the form of selecting 4,000,000 human beings who had to

perish under capitalism. The list was later to include: Gypsies, Poles,

Russians, Ukrainians, etc.

[31] These features, of course, extend to areas under Russian

occupation. Mr. MacCormac of the N.Y. Times (19th June, 1950), for

example, reports offhandedly:

'Like Russia the satellites now are experimenting with prison labour as

a solution to their difficulties. New legal codes are being adopted

after the Soviet model to provide for the "reform" of certain classes of

prisoners by sentencing them to labour for one month to two years at

"reduced wages".'

[32] B., S., and Y., etc., p. 136.