💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › kevin-carson-the-left-rothbardians.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:48:54. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2024-06-20)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Title: The Left-Rothbardians
Author: Kevin Carson
Date: April 2008
Language: en
Topics: Murray Rothbard, the market, Left Libertarianism, c4ss
Source: Retrieved on 1st September 2021 from https://c4ss.org/content/12938][c4ss.org]] and [[https://c4ss.org/content/13213
Notes: This article was originally published on the blog The Art of the Possible.

Kevin Carson

The Left-Rothbardians

Part I: Rothbard

In “Libertarianism: What’s Going Right,” I mentioned Left-Rothbardianism

as one possible basis for finding areas of agreement between market

libertarians and the Left. I’d like to go into that in more depth now.

In 2004, I was extremely heartened by the “Era of Good Feelings” between

the Libertarian Party’s Michael Badnarik and the Green Party’s David

Cobb. It gave me some hope for the revival of an even more hopeful

project of some 30-odd years before.

During the late 1960s, Murray Rothbard attempted a strategic alliance of

the “isolationist” and comparatively anti-statist Old Right with the New

Left. That period is the subject of an article by John Payne, “

Rothbard’s Time on the Left.” Payne writes:

By the early 1960s, Rothbard saw the New Right, exemplified by National

Review, as perpetually wedded to the Cold War, which would quickly turn

exponentially hotter in Vietnam, and the state interventions that

accompanied it, so he set out looking for new allies. In the New Left,

Rothbard found a group of scholars who opposed the Cold War and

political centralization, and possessed a mass following with high

growth potential. For this opportunity, Rothbard was willing to set

economics somewhat to the side and settle on common ground, and, while

his cooperation with the New Left never altered or caused him to hide

any of his foundational beliefs, Rothbard’s rhetoric shifted distinctly

leftward during this period.

I would add one qualification, concerning what Payne said about Rothbard

setting economics to the side. In fact, as we will see below, Rothbard

shared some common economic ground with the New Left. At his leftmost

position, Rothbard’s Austrian critique of corporate-state capitalism was

quite radical.

In the late ’50s, according to Payne’s account, Rothbard found himself

at odds with W.F. Buckley and Frank Meyer at the National Review. His

submissions on foreign policy, in a period when he saw the “war-peace

question” as key to the libertarian agenda and referred to the “Verdamte

cold war,” were rejected. Finally, in 1961, Meyer publicly read him out

of the “conservative movement” (or at least out of National Review’s

fusionism).

From the early ’60s on, Rothbard found himself increasingly attracted to

the left-wing revisionist critique of 20^(th) century state capitalism

(or what the New Left called “corporate liberalism“). He was especially

struck by the thesis of Gabriel Kolko’s book The Triumph of

Conservatism, which came out in 1963.

Rothbard’s Misesian critique of the corporate state, which shared so

much common ground with the New Left, was a considerable departure from

Mises’ right-wing political affinities. For Mises, state interventionism

was motivated almost entirely by anti-capitalist sentiment: what Nixon

would have called the “filthy f**king hippies,” or Eric Cartman would

dismiss as “a bunch of G*ddamn tree-hugging hippie crap.”

Rothbard, on the other hand, applied Austrian principles largely from

the standpoint of Kolko’s critique, which saw state interventionism as

motivated mainly by the desire of corporate capitalists themselves to

protect their profits from the destructive force of market competition.

Kolko directly contradicted the orthodox historical account of the

regulatory state, as exemplified by the liberal Arthur Schlesinger, Jr.

Specificially, he denied that the Progressive Era legislative agenda was

formulated primarily as a populist restraint on big business, or that

government had intervened in the economy in the 20^(th) century as a

“countervailing force” against big business. Rather, the regulatory

state was an attempt by big business to achieve, acting directly though

the state, what it had been unable to achieve through voluntary

combinations and trusts carried out entirely in the private sector: the

cartelization of the economy, and the creation of stable oligopoly

markets characterized by administered pricing. Payne quotes this summary

statement from Kolko’s book:

Despite the large number of mergers, and the growth in the absolute size

of many corporations, the dominant tendency in the American economy at

the beginning of this [the twentieth] century was toward growing

competition. Competition was unacceptable to many key business and

financial interests.... As new competitors sprang up, and as economic

power was diffused throughout an expanding nation, it became apparent to

many important businessmen that only the national government could

rationalize the economy. Although specific conditions varied from

industry to industry, internal problems that could be solved only by

political means were the common denominator in those industries whose

leaders advocated greater federal regulation. Ironically, contrary to

the consensus of historians, it was not the existence of monopoly that

caused the federal government to intervene in the economy, but the lack

of it.

The purpose of state action was, first of all, to help overbuilt

industry simultaneously to operate at full capacity and to dispose of

the surplus product it couldn’t sell at cartel prices. Second, as an

alternative, it was to enable cartelized industry to operate with high

costs and idle capacity and still remain profitable by selling its

product at cost-plus markup through monopoly pricing. (This might as

well have been the mission statement of FDR’s National Industrial

Recovery Administration, by the way.)

This initial perception by Rothbard, that New Left revisionist

historiography was useful for a free market critique of twentieth

century corporate capitalism, led to a considerable amount of

cooperation with New Left scholars.

Rothbard participated in Studies on the Left, a project of New Left

historians James Weinstein and William Appleman Williams. It was

Weinstein, in The Corporate Ideal in the Liberal State, who coined the

term “corporate liberalism.” And Williams devised the thesis of “Open

Door Imperialism” to describe American foreign policy. Some of

Rothbard’s contributions to Studies on the Left were included in a

paperback collection of articles resulting from the group’s efforts

through 1967: For a New America.

Rothbard retained friendly ties to the scholarly New Left long after his

disillusionment with the radical student movement. His second venture in

collaborative scholarship (at the comparatively late date of 1972) was A

New History of Leviathan, a collection of critical essays on New Deal

corporatism coedited by Rothbard and the libertarian socialist Ronald

Radosh.

He contributed one article (“Confessions of a Right-Wing Liberal“), in

1968, to Ramparts. (Both David Horowitz and Ronald Radosh, who both

later became two of the most odious members of a neoconservative

movement characterized by its odiousness, were associated with this

leading periodical of the New Left.)

Rothbard founded the journal Left and Right in 1965 as a vehicle for

this academically oriented Left-Right alliance. If you’re at all

interested in this kind of things, browsing the archives there will well

repay your effort.

From his initial scholarly collaboration with New Left academics,

Rothbard moved on to attempt a mass movement in alliance with student

radicals.

The high point of this alliance occurred in 1969. The radical

libertarian/anarchist caucus of the Young Americans for Freedom walked

out of the YAF convention in St. Louis (mainly over the Vietnam War and

the draft). The roots of the contemporary libertarian movement, and most

of its founding personnel, can be traced to this act of secession. Not

long afterwards, Rothbard (along with Karl Hess, a former Goldwater

speechwriter who coined the phrase “extremism in defense of liberty,”

and subsequently moved considerably to the left) organized a mass

meeting of the YAF’s libertarian dissidents with similar libertarian

socialist secessionists from the SDS. During that event, Hess addressed

a combined audience of YAF and SDS insurgents wearing combat fatigues

and a Wobbly pin.

Rothbard’s journal The Libertarian Forum was founded in 1969, at a time

when Rothbard was becoming increasingly disenchanted with the New Left,

and the New Left itself (and specifically the SDS, under onslaught from

the Maoist Kool-Aid drinkers in Progressive Labor and the nihilist

nutcases in the Weather Underground) was disintegrating. Although

Rothbard could get along pretty well with New Left academics, he

apparently suffered considerable culture shock in 1969 at finding out

just how radical the student radicals really were (their blanket

denunciations of academic economists and the wearing of neckties were a

particular affront to Rothbard, who was guilty on both counts).

Nevertheless the first volume of Libertarian Forum was packed with heady

commentary on the New Left alliance.

Take, for example, this quote from the May 1, 1969 issue:

[The students] see that, apart from other tie-ins, corporations have

been using the government schools and colleges as institutions that

train their future workers and executives at the expense of others, i.e.

the taxpayers. This is but one way that our corporate state uses the

coercive taxing power either to accumulate corporate capital or to lower

corporate costs. Whatever that process may be called, it is not “free

enterprise,” except in the most ironic sense.

Consider also this statement by Hess:

The truth… is that libertarianism wants to advance principles of

property but that it in no way wishes to defend, willy nilly, all

property which now is called private.

Much of that property is stolen. Much is of dubious title. All of it is

deeply intertwined with an immoral, coercive state system which has

condoned, built on, and profited from slavery; has expanded through and

exploited a brutal and aggressive imperial and colonial foreign policy,

and continues to hold the people in a roughly serf-master relationship

to political-economic power concentrations.

Libertarians are concerned, first and foremost, with that most valuable

of properties, the life of each individual…. Property rights pertaining

to material objects are seen by libertarians as stemming from and…

secondary to the right to own, direct, and enjoy one’s own life and

those appurtenances thereto which may be acquired without coercion….

This is a far cry from sharing common ground with those who want to

create a society in which super-capitalists are free to amass vast

holdings and who say that that is ultimately the most important purpose

of freedom….

Libertarianism is a people’s movement and a liberation movement. It

seeks the sort of open, non-coercive society in which the people, the

living, free, distinct people may voluntarily associate, dis-associate,

and, as they see fit, participate in the decisions affecting their

lives…. It means people free collectively to organize the resources of

their immediate community or individualistically to organize them; it

means the freedom to have a community-based and supported judiciary

where wanted, none where not, or private arbitration services where that

is seen as most desirable. The same with police. The same with schools,

hospitals, factories, farms, laboratories, parks, and pensions. Liberty

means the right to shape your own institutions. It opposes the right of

those institutions to shape you simply because of accreted power or

gerontological status.

In another article in the same issue, “Confiscation and the Homestead

Principle,” Rothbard proposed a model of privatization far removed from

the kind of corporate looting of state assets you commonly find

advocated in mainstream libertarian venues these days.

What most people ordinarily identify as the stereotypical “libertarian”

privatization proposal, unfortunately, goes something like this: sell it

to a giant corporation on terms that are most advantageous to the

corporation. Rothbard proposed, instead, was to treat state property as

unowned, and allowing it to be homesteaded by those actually occupying

it and mixing their labor with it. This would mean transforming

government utilities, schools and other services into consumer

cooperatives and placing them under the direct control of their present

clientele. It would mean handing over state industry to workers’

syndicates and transforming it into worker-owned cooperatives.

But if this was the appropriate way of dealing with state property,

Rothbard asked, then what about nominally private industry which is in

fact a branch of the state? That is, what about “private” industry that

gets the majority of its profits from taxpayer subsidies?

But if Columbia University, what of General Dynamics? What of the myriad

of corporations which are integral parts of the military-industrial

complex, which not only get over half or sometimes virtually all their

revenue from the government but also participate in mass murder? What

are their credentials to “private” property? Surely less than zero. As

eager lobbyists for these contracts and subsidies, as co-founders of the

garrison stare, they deserve confiscation and reversion of their

property to the genuine private sector as rapidly as possible. To say

that their “private” property must be respected is to say that the

property stolen by the horsethief and the murderer must be “respected.”

Such factories should be taken over by “homesteading workers,” he said.

But he went further, and suggested that a libertarian movement, having

captured the commanding heights of the state and proceeding to dismantle

the apparatus of state capitalism, might actually nationalize such

state-subsidized industry as the immediate prelude to handing it over to

the workers. He went so far as to say that even if a non-libertarian

regime nationalized state capitalist industry with the intention of

hanging onto it, it wasn’t anything for libertarians to get particularly

bent out of shape about. The subsidized industry was no more the “good

guys,” and no less a part of the state, as the formal state apparatus

itself. “…[I]t would only mean that one gang of thieves–the

government–would be confiscating property from another previously

cooperating gang, the corporation that has lived off the government.”

I’d go Rothbard one further. Why is the criterion for de facto

government status the amount of profits directly subsidized from state

revenue? What about corporations that function within a web of state

regulatory protections, and artificial property rights like Bill Gates’

“intellectual property,” without which they couldn’t operate in black

ink for a single day. Anyone who’s read much of my work for any length

of time knows that I consider the entire Fortune 500 a pretty good proxy

for such de facto branches of the state. As I already argued in an

earlier post, the largest corporations are so intertwined with the state

that the very distinction between “public” and “private” becomes

meaningless.

To reinforce that impression, bear in mind that (as Hess’s remarks above

on property suggest) Rothbard considered all land titles not traceable

to a legitimate act of appropriation by human labor to be utterly null

and void. That meant that titles to vacant and unimproved land were

void, and all such land in the United States should be open to immediate

homesteading. It meant all the real estate in Southern California

currently held as real estate investments by the railroads, pursuant to

the land grants of the nineteenth century, should immediately become the

absolute freehold of those currently making rent or mortgage payments on

it. It meant that all the land in the Third World currently “owned” by

quasi-feudal landed oligarchies should immediately become the property

of the peasants working it; and land currently being used by corporate

agribusiness and other cash crop operations, in collusion with those

same landlords, should be returned to the peasants who were evicted from

it.

In short, Rothbard didn’t exactly fit the “pot-smoking Republican”

stereotype you see the commenters over at Kos regurgitating. This is

getting way, way long. I originally intended to fit all the

Left-Rothbardian material into one post. But I’ll save the material on

Rothbard’s left-libertarian successors (Sam Konkin, Joseph Stromberg,

and the rest) for another post.

Part II: After Rothbard

This post starts where the first half left off: Rothbard’s disillusion

with (and abandonment of) his New Left alliance. Now I want to look at

some of the people who continued the left-Rothbardian tradition.

Karl Hess was just getting into his full left-wing swing when Rothbard

gave up the New Left as a lost cause. Even during Rothbard’s most

enthusiastic attempts at collaboration with the Left, Hess was already

to the left of Rothbard. As I mentioned in Part I, at one point he was a

Wobbly. He continued to move leftward into the 1970s, in 1975 writing

the libertarian socialist tinged Dear America.

As the 1970s wore on, his leftism took on more of a “Small is Beautiful”

coloring, with an emphasis on human scale technology and neighborhood

democracy. In this period he wrote the highly recommended book Community

Technology, and coauthored Neighborhood Power with David Morris.

By around 1980 or so, Hess also started drifting back to the right,

although he never went as far in that direction as Rothbard did in his

last years. His autobiography Mostly on the Edge, written after his

shift back to the right, still retained much of the generally

decentralist and anti-bigness spirit of his earlier years.

In considering the career of Samuel Edward Konkin III, I rely among

other things on his own account of the history of the Movement of the

Libertarian Left. If you want the full, complicated history of all the

organizations he built, go to Konkin’s account (along with obits by Jeff

Riggenbach and Phil Osborn) and you’ll get all the organizational

details and humanizing anecdotes you can handle. I’m skipping over a lot

here, because my main focus is on his ideas and the people today who

were influenced by them.

Konkin (aka SEK3), a native Albertan and a social crediter in his callow

youth, was an associate of Rothbard dating back to the days of the YAF

schism (he was a Wisconsin delegate at the St. Louis convention where it

took place). His Movement of the Libertarian Left continued to develop

Rothbard’s thought in the leftward direction that Rothbard himself had

abandoned.

Despite Rothbard’s disillusion with the libertarian-left alliance, the

collaboration of 1969 between YAF and SDS dissidents had a certain

momentum of its own. For example, according to SEK3’s history of the

Movement of the Libertarian Left, Libertarian Alliances formed on a

number of college campuses through the 1970s. The phenomenon was kicked

off in February 1970, when the California Libertarian Alliance organized

a Left-Right Festival of Mind Liberation. Speakers included Karl Hess;

the free market libertarian Robert LeFevre; Carl Oglesby; Dana

Rohrahacher (yeah, him), who was known as the “Johnny Grass-seed” of the

YAF radicals back when he was good for something; and Sam Konkin.

Starting from the University of Wisconsin-Madison Libertarian Alliance,

and drawing associates involved with the mushrooming Libertarian

Alliances all over New York and the West Coast, Konkin organized many of

his fellow travellers into a left-Rothbardian movement that took on the

name New Libertarian Alliance in 1974. Konkin created the NLA as an

underground organization, for promoting his stategy of Counter-Economics

and his ideology of Agorism. In 1978, he founded the Movement of the

Libertarian Left as an above-ground counterpart to the NLA. The Agorist

Institute popped up at some point thereafter, if you’re still keeping

track. (I’m not blind to the humor in this mad proliferation of

organizations, believe me – more about which below.)

Konkin’s chief strategic focus, in keeping with his doctrinaire

anti-political stance, was what he called “Counter-Economics” or

“Agorism.” The idea was outlined in Konkin’s New Libertarian Manifesto:

to build a black market counter-economy, and drain resources from the

corporate state nexus, until the free market counter-economy finally

supplanted the state capitalist system altogether.

Konkin’s ideas on counter-economics dovetail to a considerable extent

with the left-wing ideas of dual power and prefigurative politics. I

discussed a counter-economic strategy based on those concepts, from a

libertarian socialist perspective considerably to the left of Konkin’s,

in “Building the Structure of the New Society Within the Shell of the

Old“:

Economic counter-institutions, unfortunately, work within the framework

of a larger corporate capitalist economy. They compete in markets in

which the institutional culture of the dominant firms is top-down and

hierarchical, and are in great danger of absorbing this institutional

culture themselves. That’s why you have a non-profit and cooperative

sector whose management is indistinguishable from its capitalist

counterparts: prestige salaries, middle management featherbedding,

bureaucratic irrationality, and slavish adherence to the latest

motivational/management theory dogma. The problem is exacerbated by a

capitalist financial system, which extends positive reinforcement (in

the form of credit) to firms following an orthodox organizational model

(even when bottom-up organization is far more efficient)….

The solution is to promote as much consolidation as possible within the

counter-economy. We need to get back to the job of “building the

structure of the new society within the shell of the old.” A great deal

of production and consumption already takes place within the social or

gift economy, self-employment, barter, etc. The linkages need to be

increased and strengthened between those involved in consumers’ and

producers’ co-ops, self-employment, LETS systems, home gardening and

other household production, informal barter, etc. What economic

counter-institutions already exist need to start functioning as a

cohesive counter-economy.

Konkin’s other major innovation was his development of libertarian class

theory. The roots of Rothbard’s and Konkin’s class theory lie in the

French thinkers Saint-Simon, Comte, and Dunoyer, and in the radical wing

of English classical liberalism. They identified the ruling class as

those interests that obtained their wealth by acting through the state.

The classic thinker in this tradition was the English free market

radical Thomas Hodgskin, who made the distinction between “natural” and

“artificial” rights of property. The former, he said, followed naturally

from possession and served to secure the individual’s ownership of his

labor product. Artificial property rights, on the other hand, were

creations of the state which enabled the holder to collect tribute from

the product of labor. Holders of artificial property rights included the

great landlords with their feudal rents, the politically connected

mercantile capitalists, and the recipients of assorted other privileges

and immunities.

The ideas of the French positivists and of Hodgskin were taken up in

Franz Oppenheimer’s distinction between “natural appropriation” and

“political appropriation” of the land, and between the “economic means”

and “political means” to wealth. Political appropriation of land was the

chief political means to wealth.

The classical political economists had acknowledged that most people

will enter wage employment only when all the land is appropriated and

they no longer have direct access to self-employment on their own land.

This was a commonplace observation made by Smith, Ricardo, and Malthus.

Oppenheimer’s radical contribution was to observe that although the land

was indeed all appropriated, it had never been naturally appropriated;

it had, rather, been politically appropriated by the great landlords

acting through the state. The great landlords used their artificial

property rights in the land to control access to it and charge tribute

to those working it, and in many cases to hold vast tracts of it out of

use altogether. Only under these circumstances, in which the means of

direct subsistence were made inaccessible to labor, could labor be

forced to sell its services on disadvantageous terms (the British ruling

class literature at the time of the Enclosures was full of frank

admissions that the only way to get people to work hard enough, for a

low enough wage, was to steal their land). Privilege was the political

means to wealth, and the state was the organized political means.

Rothbard made this the centerpiece of his class theory, treating

collusion with the state as the political means to wealth, and the

ruling class as those who attached themselves to the state and used its

subsidies, privileges and special protections as a source of profit.

Rothbard stated these principles, among other places, in “The Anatomy of

the State.”

Konkin took this basic insight and ran with it, applying it in detail to

the concrete conditions of American state capitalism. The ruling class

was not only state functionaries, but the central banks and associated

large financial interests, and the commanding heights of the corporate

economy most closely tied to the statist finance system. Agorism was the

revolutionary movement of those engaged in the economic means,

attempting to take as much economic activity as possible out of the

control of the ruling class. Konkin’s agorist class theory was set forth

in the first chapter of his unfinished work Agorism Contra Marxism. That

chapter is appended to Wally Conger’s excellent Agorist Class Theory,

which itself is based on the chapter and surving scraps of Konkin’s work

in the area. An in-depth class analysis of the financial system and its

industrial satellites, based on the same version of libertarian class

theory, is set forth in an article by Walter Grinder and John Hagel:

“Toward a Theory of State Capitalism.”

As Konkin said, Agorist and Marxist class theories pretty much agree

when it comes to those at the top and bottom of their respective class

systems. “The differences arise as one moves to the middle of the social

pyramid.” The main difference regarding the middle is that Agorist class

theory is a lot closer to the “petty bourgeois producerism” of the

nineteenth century populists. Agorists don’t have any problem with

entrepreneurship or entrepreneurial profit. What they have a problem

with is the rentier classes, deriving absentee incomes from huge

fortunes with the help of the state. Those at the top of the pyramid

generally act through the state to make sure they don’t have to engage

in entrepreneurship. Rather, the state protects them from risk and

competition, and thereby enables them to collect secure long-term rents

(see, for example, here and here – please do!).

In 1999, Konkin founded the LeftLibertarian yahoogroup, the venue

through which I first came into contact with him, his ideas, and his

wide circle of friends. I had several years of stiulating discussion

there that influenced my development to no end. In 2007, three years

after Konkin’s death, the list imploded over a political dispute between

J. Neil Schulman and just about everybody else, and most of the

important figures in Konkin’s circle migrated to the Left-Libertarian2

group. Konkin’s old yahoogroup is pretty much an empty shell, although

Neil Schulman and Kent Hastings stayed with it (and the archives are

well worth digging into). Because of a similar dispute with Neil over

the rights to the name “Movement of the Libertarian Left”, several

members of LeftLibertarian2 collaborated to form a successor

organization, the Alliance of the Libertarian Left. Again, just about

all the leading figures in the old MLL migrated to the ALL and left the

old body as an empty shell owned by Schulman.

I know, I know. I’m the first to acknowledge how comical Konkin’s

alphabet soup of organizations must seem to anyone on the outside. To

beat you to the joke, it’s like one man founded the Judean People’s

Front, the Popular Front of Judea, and all those other “splitter”

organizations at the same time. Sam’s personality reminds me a bit of

Bakunin’s. With his childlike enthusiasm for founding endless

organizations (with cool acronyms, of course) and publications, issuing

name cards, and forming conspiratorial undergounds, it’s hard to keep

track of it all without a score card.

But his ideas deserve to be taken seriously in their own right, and his

work had a serious effect that belies the snicker factor in all the

organizational mitosis described above. His theoretical ideas in the New

Libertarian Manifesto, and in his unfinished work on agorist class

theory, are both monumental contributions to libertarian thought. His

ideas inspired a large circle of prominent libertarians who are

influential in a wide range of organizations and publications today, and

their ripple effects continue to spread outward.

The most important association of Konkin’s left-Rothbardian followers

today is the Alliance of the Libertarian Left. There’s nothing remotely

“Judean People’s Front” or splinterish about it. If anything, it’s a

textbook example of how an affinity group should be organized in an era

of networked politics. It is a large, vibrant community of

left-Rothbardians and other left-wing allies (like me). It’s an umbrella

organization something like an Agorist International.

In a sense, the Alliance of the Libertarian Left is an improvement on

its MLL predecessor. The old MLL was almost entirely made up of Konkin’s

Agorist fellow-thinkers. Although it was descended from Rothbard’s

attempt at a New Left alliance, it included only one side–the market

libertarian side–of the alliance. There weren’t any New Leftists or

libertarian socialists in sight. The closest they came to dialogue with

the genuine left was when some anarcho-commies or Georgists stopped by

the LeftLibertarian list for a while and then moved on. Although the

nucleus of the new ALL is made up of Konkin’s old associates, it

includes a much larger accretion of left-wing movements. Several

Tuckerites and mutualists of my general stripe (who stress the socialist

as much as the market aspect of individualist anarchism), and quite an

assortment of geolibertarians. In addition to the old core of Agorists,

there are a good many small-a agorist fellow-travellers. Chuck Munson

(Chuck0) of Infoshop even has friendly ties with several members of the

ALL. In a sense, the Alliance of the Libertarian Left is exactly the

kind of left-right alliance Rothbard tried and failed to achieve almost

forty years ago.

So despite Sam’s seeming silliness with all his organizations, in the

end he built something important that lasted. He impressed his thought

on a wide range of people, and brought them together, and most of them

are still together and building on his and each other’s. His influence

continues to leaven the broader libertarian movement in ways we may

never fully realize the importance of in our lifetimes.

Just by looking at the links on the Alliance of the Libertarian Left

site, or clicking the movement’s associated blog ring, the Blogosphere

of the Libertarian Left, you can find a wide range of sites hosted by

Konkin’s old fightin’ comrades from the St. Louis days, more recent

disciples of left-Rothbardianism and Counter-economics, and some even

newer left-wing friends like me, who–despite never having considered

ourselves followers of Rothbard or Konkin–have been strongly influenced

by their thought.

Brad Spangler’s site, Agorism.Info, reproduces the NLM along with many

of Konkin’s other pamphlets.

The Agorist Action Alliance (A3) was created by Spangler as an activist

organization for coordinating agorist propaganda and counter-economic

organization.

KoPubCo, a publishing outfit owned by old Konkin associate Victor Koman,

has reprints of much of the MLL’s literature, including reprints of New

Libertarian Notes and Strategy of the Libertarian Left.

The Rothbard-founded scholarly journal, Journal of Libertarian Studies

has since December 2004 had a left-Rothbardian editor, Roderick T. Long.

Another member of the Alliance of the Libertarian Left, Sheldon Richman,

is (sic) editor of Leonard Read’s long-lived periodical The Freeman; he

has in recent years moved its editorial stance in a decidely

left-libertarian direction and been a vocal critic of state capitalism.

Joseph Stromberg – although completely unaffiliated with the Alliance of

the Libertarian Left–is nevertheless something of a Left-Rothbardian

eminence. He has himself rejected as artificial attempts to divide

Rothbard’s career into left- and right-leaning phases. But the division

is quite useful in my opinion, and Stromberg clearly falls into the

left-Rothbardian category when it comes to his analysis of the role of

interests in U.S. foreign and domestic policy.

Probably the two centerpieces of his body of work are:

“The Political Economy of Liberal Corporatism,” and

Beard, W.A. Williams, and the neo-Marxists) of monopoly capital and

imperialism into an Austrian theoretical framework, in “The Role of

State Monopoly Capitalism in the American Empire.” This article I cannot

recommend highly enough.

In addition, it’s worthwhile to browse his archives at LewRockwell.Com

and Antiwar.Com. Although Mises.Org… doesn’t maintain an author archive,

his work can be found by a Google search of their site. Probably his

single greatest work, aside from the two articles mentioned above, is

his lengthy annotated bibliography of revisionist literature on war and

foreign policy: “War, Peace, and the State.”