💾 Archived View for library.inu.red › file › kevin-carson-selling-the-store.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 11:47:48. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
➡️ Next capture (2024-07-09)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Title: Selling the Store? Author: Kevin Carson Date: April 11, 2005 Language: en Topics: libertarianism, outreach, strategy Source: Retrieved on 4th September 2021 from https://mutualist.blogspot.com/2005/04/selling-store.html
Interesting exchange on libertarian outreach strategy between Brad
Spangler and Thomas L. Knapp.
Commenting on the formation of the Libertarian Reform Caucus, Brad
writes,
....it is perhaps no surprise that Libertarians have collectively failed
to recognize one of the most important things they can control to
improve the situation…
Recognizing that a political party makes a damned poor educational
organization and vice verse.
Call me Mr. Obvious, but does anybody think that maybe part of the
reason that the Libertarian Party (an ideologically oriented political
party) is not more successful might be that conscious public allegiance
to libertarian ideology isn’t more widespread? It takes serious, hard
educational efforts to produce something like that — and a political
party isn’t necessarily the best tool to achieve it.
The Libertarian Party will start kicking more butt when we’ve got —
gasp! — a whole buttload of libertarians (and not before).
That doesn’t seem like a difficult point to grasp. Yet Libertarians are
perpetually exhausted from trying to run a political party on a skeleton
crew. That’s not an effective way to build a Libertarian majority. The
situation calls for activists educating themselves more thoroughly and
then going out and educating a lot more people — even if it means they
have to let the party not be the focus of their libertarian activism for
awhile.
Tom responds:
[Brad] thinks that what’s needed is not a “softening” of approach, but
rather a concentration on creating more people who like the party’s
ideology.
What’s missing here?....
Both the LRC and Brad seem to think that the party is the product. It
isn’t. It’s the store.
The platform isn’t the product, either. It’s the store’s mission
statement....
The party is the store. The products on the shelves are candidates,
policy proposals and such.
You don’t sell the store. You sell the products.
You don’t sell the store’s mission statement. You sell the store’s
products....
One of the basics of sales doctrine is that you sell benefits, not
features....
Any approach that focuses on:
a) selling ideology (feature) instead of policy outcomes (benefits); and
b) selling the party (store) instead of its candidates and policies
(products)
... is doomed to fail....
I tend to agree with Tom that priority should be given to pointing out
the benefits of libertarian policy, from the standpoint of the general
public’s existing interests and concerns. In the case of libertarianism,
any educational effort aimed at getting people to prefer libertarian
principles (e.g., and especially, non-aggression) for their own sake
will likely be both very long-term and uphill. On the other hand, an
educational effort aimed at reaching people where they are now, and
selling libertarian policies in terms of the things they currently
value, could be quite effective.
But there’s a fine line between marketing and education. Consider:
As I understand it, Tom’s sales strategy involves 1) pointing out to the
public, in some area of policy, how the existing evils they object to,
what they see as pressing concerns, are a direct result of the state’s
policies; and 2) pointing out how a free market order would reduce those
evils.
In each case, the libertarian argument shows that the forms of
government intervention which the court intellectuals sell as limits on
the power of big business, were actually started at the behest of big
business. In each area of policy, the regulatory-welfare state is shown
to be a system of government intervention on behalf of the rich and
powerful; and all the assorted evils they object to in our society are
shown to be its side-effects. Pollution is a result of subsidies to
polluting corporations and legal protections against internalizing
pollution costs; sprawl results from subsidies to outlying real estate
developments (and to politically connected real estate developers);
outsourcing from subsidies to the export of capital; the energy shortage
from subsidies to transportation and energy consumption; etc., etc.
Such case-by-case argumentation could well have, cumulatively, an
educational side-effect (for many, at least). Point out enough
individual cases showing that a policy (which the public has been taught
from grade school to view as an enlightened, idealistic, and “common
sense” measure) actually benefits the rich and powerful at the expense
of everybody else, and some people may take the next step of inductive
reasoning: making the generalized observation that benefiting the
privileged rich and powerful at everybody else’s expense is what
government does.
It doesn’t necessarily mean that such a libertarian outreach program
will lead to a majority of people adopting the non-aggression principle
and becoming libertarian ideologues. It is likewise unlikely to lead
many people to adopt, as an article of faith, that government is always
the “political means,” or a “zero-sum game,” or any other catchphrase
you prefer. It might, however, lead many more people than at present to
accept, on the basis of experience, that this is often (or even usually)
what government does. It might lead to an increased skepticism of the
good intentions of the “progressive” state, and a willingness to look
for the man behind the curtain when they hear “progressive” rhetoric.
In short, each specific libertarian policy proposal should carry with it
a little lesson in what government really does, and who it really
serves. Enough such little lessons, cumulatively and perhaps
subliminally, might lead to a big lesson.