💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 895.gmi captured on 2023-01-29 at 08:24:54. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-05)

➡️ Next capture (2024-05-10)

🚧 View Differences

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Herd behavior

2008-12-16 06:34:16

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Herd behaviour describes how individuals in a group can act together without

planned direction. The term pertains to the behaviour of animals in herds,

flocks, and schools, and to human conduct during activities such as stock

market bubbles and crashes, street demonstrations, sporting events, episodes of

mob violence and even everyday decision making, judgment and opinion forming.

Herd behaviour in animals

A group of animals fleeing a predator shows the nature of herd behavior. In

1971, in the often cited article "Geometry For The Selfish Herd," evolutionary

biologist W. D. Hamilton asserted that each individual group member reduces the

danger to itself by moving as close as possible to the center of the fleeing

group. Thus the herd appears to act as a unit in moving together, but its

function emerges from the uncoordinated behavior of self-seeking individuals.

[1]

Symmetry breaking in herding behavior

Asymmetric aggregation of animals under panic conditions has been observed in

many species, including humans, mice, and ants. Theoretical models have

demonstrated symmetry breaking similar to observations in empirical studies.

For example when panicked individuals confined to a room with two equal and

equidistant exits, a majority will favor one exit while the minority will favor

the other.

Possible mechanisms:

feedback

Escape Panic Characteristics

Herd behaviour in human societies

Psychological and economic research has identified herd behavior in humans to

explain the phenomena of large numbers of people acting in the same way at the

same time. The British surgeon Wilfred Trotter popularized the "herd behavior"

phrase in his book, Instincts of the Herd in Peace and War (1914). In The

Theory of the Leisure Class, Thorstein Veblen explained economic behavior in

terms of social influences such as "emulation," where some members of a group

mimic other members of higher status. In "The Metropolis and Mental Life"

(1903), early sociologist George Simmel referred to the "impulse to sociability

in man", and sought to describe "the forms of association by which a mere sum

of separate individuals are made into a 'society' ". Other social scientists

explored behaviors related to herding, such as Freud (crowd psychology), Carl

Jung (collective unconscious), and Gustave Le Bon (the popular mind). Swarm

theory observed in non-human societies is a related concept and is being

explored as it occurs in human society.

[edit] Stock market bubbles

Large stock market trends often begin and end with periods of frenzied buying

(bubbles) or selling (crashes). Many observers cite these episodes as clear

examples of herding behavior that is irrational and driven by emotion -- greed

in the bubbles, fear in the crashes. Individual investors join the crowd of

others in a rush to get in or out of the market. [2]

Some followers of the technical analysis school of investing see the herding

behaviour of investors as an example of extreme market sentiment.[3] The

academic study of behavioral finance has identified herding in the collective

irrationality of investors, particularly the work of Robert Shiller,[4] and

Nobel laureates Vernon Smith, Amos Tversky, and Daniel Kahneman.

Hey and Morone (2004) analysed a model of herd behaviour in a market context.

Their work is related to at least two important strands of literature. The

first of these strands is that on herd behaviour in a non-market context. The

seminal references are Banerjee (1992) and Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer and Welch

(1992), both of which showed that herd behaviour may result from private

information not publicly shared. More specifically, both of these papers showed

that individuals, acting sequentially on the basis of private information and

public knowledge about the behaviour of others, may end up choosing the

socially undesirable option. The second of the strands of literature motivating

this paper is that of information aggregation in market contexts. A very early

reference is the classic paper by Grossman and Stiglitz (1976) that showed that

uninformed traders in a market context can become informed through the price in

such a way that private information is aggregated correctly and efficiently. A

summary of the progress of this strand of literature can be found in the paper

by Plott (2000). Hey and Morone (2004) showed that it is possible to observe

herd-type behaviour in a market context. Their result is even more interesting

since it refers to a market with a well-defined fundamental value. Even if herd

behaviour might only be observed rarely, this has important consequences for a

whole range of real markets most particularly foreign exchange markets.

[edit] Behavior in crowds

Crowds that gather on behalf of a grievance can involve herding behavior that

turns violent, particularly when confronted by an opposing ethnic or racial

group. The Los Angeles riots of 1992, New York Draft Riots and Tulsa Race Riot

are notorious in U.S. history, but those episodes are dwarfed by the scale of

violence and death during the Partition of India. Population exchanges between

India and Pakistan brought millions of migrating Hindus and Muslims into

proximity; the ensuing violence produced an estimated death toll of between

200,000 and one million. The idea of a "group mind" or "mob behavior" was put

forward by the French social psychologists Gabriel Tarde and Gustave Le Bon.

Sporting events can also produce violent episodes of herd behaviour. The most

violent single riot in history may be the sixth-century Nika riots in

Constantinople, precipitated by partisan factions attending the chariot races.

The football hooliganism of the 1980s was a well-publicized, latter-day example

of sports violence.

[edit] Everyday decision-making

Benign herding behaviors may be frequent in everyday decisions based on

learning from the information of others, as when a person on the street decides

which of two restaurants to dine in. Suppose that both look appealing, but both

are empty because it is early evening; so at random, this person chooses

restaurant A. Soon a couple walks down the same street in search of a place to

eat. They see that restaurant A has customers while B is empty, and choose A on

the assumption that having customers makes it the better choice. And so on with

other passersby into the evening, with restaurant A doing more business that

night than B. This phenomenon is also referred as an information cascade. [5]

[6]