💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4684.gmi captured on 2022-06-11 at 22:31:22. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2023-01-29)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Free exchange - The debt to pleasure

A Nobel prizewinner argues for an overhaul of the theory of consumer choice

Apr 27th 2013 |From the print edition

SOVEREIGN in tastes, steely-eyed and point-on in perception of risk, and

relentless in maximisation of happiness. This was Daniel McFadden s memorable

summation, in 2006, of the idea of Everyman held by economists. That this

description is unlike any real person was Mr McFadden s point. The Nobel

prizewinning economist at the University of California, Berkeley, wryly termed

homo economicus a rare species . In his latest paper* he outlines a new

science of pleasure , in which he argues that economics should draw much more

heavily on fields such as psychology, neuroscience and anthropology. He wants

economists to accept that evidence from other disciplines does not just explain

those bits of behaviour that do not fit the standard models. Rather, what

economists consider anomalous is the norm. Homo economicus, not his fallible

counterpart, is the oddity.

To take one example, the people in economic models have fixed preferences,

which are taken as given. Yet a large body of research from cognitive

psychology shows that preferences are in fact rather fluid. People value

mundane things much more highly when they think of them as somehow their own :

they insist on a much higher price for a coffee cup they think of as theirs,

for instance, than for an identical one that isn t. This endowment effect

means that people hold on to shares well past the point where it makes sense to

sell them. Cognitive scientists have also found that people dislike losing

something much more than they like gaining the same amount. Such loss aversion

can explain why people often pick insurance policies with lower deductible

charges even when they are more expensive. At the moment of an accident a

deductible feels like a loss, whereas all those premium payments are part of

the status quo.

Another area where orthodox economics finds itself at sea is the role of memory

and experience in determining choices. Recollection of a painful or pleasurable

experience is dominated by how people felt at the peak and the end of the

episode. In a 1996 experiment Donald Redelmeier and Daniel Kahneman, two

psychologists, showed that deliberately adding a burst of pain at the end of a

colonoscopy that was of lower intensity than the peak made patients think back

on the experience more favourably. Unlike homo economicus, real people are

strongly influenced by such things as the order in which they see options and

what happened right before they made a choice. Incorporating these findings

into models of consumer behaviour should improve their power to predict

everything from which loans people choose to which colleges they apply for.

Trust is something economists already incorporate into their models. But trust

turns out to be not just a function of history and interactions, as dismal

scientists tend to think, but also a product of brain chemistry. Pumping people

with oxytocin, the so-called love hormone , has been found to make them much

more generous in games where they have to decide how much of their money to

entrust to another person who has no real incentive to return any of it.

Sovereign, indeed.

Much of this may be alien to modern-day economists, but it is in line with the

conception that other disciplines have of human decision-making. Psychologists

have long known that people s choices and preferences are influenced by others.

Biologists have a much clearer understanding of altruism and kindness, whether

to kin or strangers, than economists, who typically emphasise the dogged

pursuit of self-interest. This way of thinking would also have been

recognisable to their intellectual forefathers. Adam Smith wrote extensively

about the central role of altruism and regard for others as motivators of human

behaviour. The idea of loss aversion would have made sense to Jeremy Bentham,

the founder of utilitarianism: he spoke of increased pleasure and reduced pain

as two distinct sources of happiness.

Mr McFadden believes that economists need to do things differently if they are

truly to understand how people make decisions. Manipulating brain activity is

one way of delving into where economic choices really come from. Analysing the

information people get through social networks would help them understand the

role of influence and identity in decision-making.

Such tools have implications for policy. Plenty of poor people in America are

wary of programmes like the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) because the idea of

getting a handout from the government reinforces a sense of helplessness.

Dignity is not something mainstream economics has much truck with. But creating

a sense of dignity turns out to be a powerful way of affecting decisions. One

study by Crystal Hall, Jiaying Zhao and Eldar Shafir, a trio of psychologists,

found that getting poor people in a soup kitchen to recall a time when they

felt successful and proud made them almost twice as likely to accept leaflets

that told them how to get an EITC refund than members of another group who were

merely asked about the last meal they had eaten.

A nudge and a think

Taking the path Mr McFadden urges might also lead economists to reassess some

articles of faith. Economists tend to think that more choice is good. Yet

people with many options sometimes fail to make any choice at all: think of

workers who prefer their employers to put them by default into pension plans

at preset contribution rates. Explicitly modelling the process of making a

choice might prompt economists to take a more ambiguous view of an abundance of

choices. It might also make them more sceptical of revealed preference , the

idea that a person s valuation of different options can be deduced from his

actions. This is undoubtedly messier than standard economics. So is real life.