💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 2558.gmi captured on 2022-06-11 at 23:41:41. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2023-01-29)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Beyond Bretton Woods 2

Is there a better way to organise the world s currencies?

Nov 4th 2010 | WASHINGTON, DC

WHEN the leaders of the Group of Twenty (G20) countries meet in Seoul on

November 11th and 12th, there will be plenty of backstage finger-pointing about

the world s currency tensions. American officials blame China s refusal to

allow the yuan to rise faster. The Chinese retort that the biggest source of

distortion in the global economy is America s ultra-loose monetary policy

reinforced by the Federal Reserve s decision on November 3rd to restart

quantitative easing , or printing money to buy government bonds (see article).

Other emerging economies cry that they are innocent victims, as their

currencies are forced up by foreign capital flooding into their markets and

away from low yields elsewhere.

These quarrels signify a problem that is more than superficial. The underlying

truth is that no one is happy with today s international monetary system the

set of rules, norms and institutions that govern the world s currencies and the

flow of capital across borders.

There are three broad complaints. The first concerns the dominance of the

dollar as a reserve currency and America s management of it. The bulk of

foreign-exchange transactions and reserves are in dollars, even though the

United States accounts for only 24% of global GDP (see chart 1). A

disproportionate share of world trade is conducted in dollars. To many people

the supremacy of the greenback in commerce, commodity pricing and official

reserves cannot be sensible. Not only does it fail to reflect the realities of

the world economy; it leaves others vulnerable to America s domestic monetary

policy.

The second criticism is that the system has fostered the creation of vast

foreign-exchange reserves, particularly by emerging economies. Global reserves

have risen from $1.3 trillion (5% of world GDP) in 1995 to $8.4 trillion (14%)

today. Emerging economies hold two-thirds of the total. Most of their hoard has

been accumulated in the past ten years (see chart 2).

These huge reserves offend economic logic, since they mean poor countries,

which should have abundant investment opportunities of their own, are lending

cheaply to richer ones, mainly America. Such lending helped precipitate the

financial crisis by pushing down America s long-term interest rates. Today,

with Americans saving rather than spending, they represent additional thrift at

a time when the world needs more demand.

The third complaint is about the scale and volatility of capital flows.

Financial crises have become more frequent in the past three decades. Many

politicians argue that a financial system in which emerging economies can

suffer floods of foreign capital (as now) or sudden droughts (as in 1997-98 and

2008) cannot be the best basis for long-term growth.

France, which assumes the chairmanship of the G20 after the Seoul summit,

thinks the world can do better. Nicolas Sarkozy, the country s president, wants

to put international monetary reform at the top of the group s agenda for the

next year. He wants a debate without taboos on how to improve an outdated

system.

Such a debate has in fact been going on sporadically for decades. Ever since

the post-war Bretton Woods system of fixed but adjustable exchange rates fell

apart in the 1970s, academics have offered Utopian blueprints for a new

version. The question is: what improvements are feasible?

The shape of any monetary system is constrained by what is often called the

trilemma of international economics. If capital can flow across borders,

countries must choose between fixing their currencies and controlling their

domestic monetary conditions. They cannot do both. Under the classical

19th-century gold standard, capital flows were mostly unfettered and currencies

were tied to gold. The system collapsed largely because it allowed governments

no domestic monetary flexibility. In the Bretton Woods regime currencies were

pegged to the dollar, which in turn was tied to gold. Capital mobility was

limited, so that countries had control over their own monetary conditions. The

system collapsed in 1971, mainly because America would not subordinate its

domestic policies to the gold link.

Today s system has no tie to gold or any other anchor, and contains a variety

of exchange-rate regimes and capital controls. Most rich countries currencies

float more or less freely although the creation of the euro was plainly a step

in the opposite direction. Capital controls were lifted three decades ago and

financial markets are highly integrated.

Broadly, emerging economies are also seeing a freer flow of capital, thanks to

globalisation as much as to the removal of restrictions. Net private flows to

these economies are likely to reach $340 billion this year, up from $81 billion

a decade ago. On paper, their currency regimes are also becoming more flexible.

About 40% of them officially float their currencies, up from less than 20% 15

years ago. But most of these floats are heavily managed. Countries are loth to

let their currencies move freely. When capital pours in, central banks buy

foreign exchange to stem their rise.

They do this in part because governments do not want their exchange rates to

soar suddenly, crippling exporters. Many of them are worried about level as

well as speed: they want export-led growth and an undervalued currency to

encourage it.

Just as important are the scars left by the financial crises of the late 1990s.

Foreign money fled, setting off deep recessions. Governments in many emerging

economies concluded that in an era of financial globalisation safety lay in

piling up huge reserves. That logic was reinforced in the crisis of 2008, when

countries with lots of reserves, such as China or Brazil, fared better than

those with less in hand. Even with reserves worth 25% of GDP, South Korea had

to turn to the Fed for an emergency liquidity line of dollars.

This experience is forcing a rethink of what makes a safe level of reserves.

Economists used to argue that developing countries needed foreign exchange

mainly for emergency imports and short-term debt payments. A popular rule of

thumb in the 1990s was that countries should be able to cover a year s worth of

debt obligations. Today s total far exceeds that.

Among emerging economies, China plays by far the most influential role in the

global monetary system. It is the biggest of them, and its currency is in

effect tied to the dollar. The yuan is widely held to be undervalued, though it

has risen faster in real than in nominal terms (see article). And because China

limits capital flows more extensively and successfully than others, it has been

able to keep the yuan cheap without stoking consumer-price inflation.

China alone explains a large fraction of the global build-up of reserves (see

chart 3). Its behaviour also affects others. Many other emerging economies,

especially in Asia, are reluctant to risk their competitiveness by letting

their currencies rise by much. As a result many of the world s most vibrant

economies in effect shadow the dollar, in an arrangement that has been dubbed

Bretton Woods 2 .

History lessons

The similarities between this quasi-dollar standard and the original Bretton

Woods system mean that many of today s problems have historical parallels.

Barry Eichengreen of the University of California, Berkeley, explores these in

Exorbitant Privilege , a forthcoming book about the past and future of the

international monetary system.

Consider, for instance, the tension between emerging economies demand for

reserves and their fear that the main reserve currency, the dollar, may lose

value a dilemma first noted in 1947 by Robert Triffin, a Belgian economist.

When the world relies on a single reserve currency, Triffin argued, that

currency s home country must issue lots of assets (usually government bonds) to

lubricate global commerce and meet the demand for reserves. But the more bonds

it issues, the less likely it will be to honour its debts. In the end, the

world s insatiable demand for the risk-free reserve asset will make that

asset anything but risk-free. As an illustration of the modern thirst for

dollars, the IMF reckons that at the current rate of accumulation global

reserves would rise from 60% of American GDP today to 200% in 2020 and nearly

700% in 2035.

If those reserves were, as today, held largely in Treasury bonds, America would

struggle to sustain the burden. Unless it offset its Treasury liabilities to

the rest of the world by acquiring foreign assets, it would find itself ever

deeper in debt to foreigners. Triffin s suggested solution was to create an

artificial reserve asset, tied to a basket of commodities. John Maynard Keynes

had made a similar proposal a few years before, calling his asset Bancor .

Keynes s idea was squashed by the Americans, who stood to lose from it. Triffin

s was also ignored for 20 years.

But in 1969, as the strains between America s budget deficit and the dollar s

gold peg emerged, an artificial reserve asset was created: the Special Drawing

Right (SDR), run by the IMF. An SDR s value is based on a basket of the dollar,

euro, pound and yen. The IMF s members agree on periodic allocations of SDRs,

which countries can convert into other currencies if need be. However, use of

SDRs has never really taken off. They make up less than 5% of global reserves

and there are no private securities in SDRs.

Some would like that to change. Zhou Xiaochuan, the governor of China s central

bank, caused a stir in March 2009 when he argued that the SDR should become a

true global reserve asset to replace the dollar. Mr Sarkozy seems to think

similarly, calling for a multilateral approach to the monetary system. If

commodities were priced in SDRs, the argument goes, their prices would be less

volatile. And if countries held their reserves in SDRs, they would escape the

Triffin dilemma.

For SDRs to play this role, however, they would have to be much more plentiful.

The IMF agreed on a $250 billion allocation among measures to fight the

financial crisis, but global reserves are rising by about $700 billion a year.

Even if there were lots more SDRs it is not clear why governments would want to

hold them. The appeal of the dollar is that it is supported by the most liquid

capital markets in the world. Few countries are likely to use SDRs much until

there are deep private markets in SDR-denominated assets.

Only if the IMF evolved into a global central bank able to issue them at speed

could SDRs truly become a central reserve asset. This is highly unlikely. As Mr

Eichengreen writes: No global government means no global central bank, which

means no global currency. Full stop.

Nor is it clear that the SDR is really needed as an alternative to the dollar.

The euro is a better candidate. This year s fiscal crises notwithstanding,

countries could shift more reserves into euros if America mismanaged its

finances or if they feared it would. This could happen fast. Mr Eichengreen

points out that the dollar had no international role in 1914 but had overtaken

sterling in governments reserves by 1925.

Alternatively, China could create a rival to the dollar if it let the yuan be

used in transactions abroad. China has taken some baby steps in this direction,

for instance by allowing firms to issue yuan-denominated bonds in Hong Kong.

However, an international currency would demand far bigger changes. Some

observers argue that China s championing of the SDR is a means to this end: if

the yuan, for instance, became part of the SDR basket, foreigners could have

exposure to yuan assets.

More likely, China is looking for a way to offload some of the currency risk in

its stash of dollars. As the yuan appreciates against the dollar (as it surely

will) those reserves will be worth less. If China could swap dollars for SDRs,

some exchange-rate risk would be shifted to the other members of the IMF. A

similar idea in the 1970s foundered because the IMF s members could not agree

on who would bear the currency risk. America refused then and surely would now.

Rather than try to create a global reserve asset, reformers might achieve more

by reducing the demand for reserves. This could be done by improving countries

access to funds in a crisis. Here the G20 has made a lot of progress under

South Korea s leadership. The IMF s lending facilities have been overhauled, so

that well-governed countries can get unlimited funds for two years.

Overcome your reserve

So far only a few emerging economies, such as Mexico and Poland, have signed

up, not least because of the stigma attached to any hint of a loan from the

IMF. Perhaps others could be persuaded to join (best of all, in a large group).

Reviving and institutionalising the swap arrangements between the Fed and

emerging economies set up temporarily during the financial crisis might also

reduce the demand for reserves as insurance. Also, regional efforts to pool

reserves could be strengthened.

However, even if they have access to emergency money, governments will still

want to hoard reserves if they are determined to hold their currencies down.

That is why many reformers think the international monetary system needs

sanctions, imposed by the IMF or the World Trade Organisation (WTO), against

countries that manipulate their currencies or run persistent surpluses.

This is another idea with a history. Along with Bancor, Keynes wanted countries

with excessive surpluses to be fined, not least because of what happened during

the Depression, when currency wars and gold-hoarding made the world s troubles

worse. The idea went nowhere because America, then a surplus economy, called

the shots at the Bretton Woods conference in 1944. The same forces are evident

today except that America, as a deficit country, is on the other side of the

argument. Like America in the 1940s, China would never agree to reforms that

penalised surplus countries.

Such rules would probably be unenforceable anyway. Harsh penalties in

international economic agreements are rarely effective: remember Europe s

Stability and Growth Pact? Modest co-operation has better prospects. Just as

the Plaza Accord in 1985 was designed to weaken the dollar and narrow America s

current-account deficit, so the G20 could develop a plan for rebalancing the

world economy, perhaps with target ranges for current-account balances and real

exchange rates. These would be supported by peer pressure rather than explicit

sanctions.

A rebalancing plan, which included faster real appreciation of the yuan, would

remove many of the tensions in the monetary system. But shifting the resources

of China and other surplus countries from exports to consumption will take

time.

Meanwhile, capital flows into emerging markets are likely to surge much faster.

This is partly due to America s quantitative easing: cheap money will encourage

investors to seek higher yields where they can find them. It is also partly due

to the growth gap between vibrant emerging economies and stagnant rich ones.

And it reflects the under-representation of emerging-market assets in investors

portfolios.

For the past decade emerging economies have responded to these surges largely

by amassing reserves. They need other options. One, adopted by Brazil, South

Korea, Thailand and others, and endorsed by the IMF, is to impose or increase

taxes and regulations to slow down inflows. Some academics have suggested

drawing up a list of permissible devices, much as the WTO has a list of

legitimate trade barriers.

This is a sensible plan, but it has its limits. Capital-inflow controls can

temporarily stem a flood of foreign cash. However, experience, notably Chile s

in the 1990s, suggests that controls alter the composition but not the amount

of foreign capital; and they do not work indefinitely. As trade links become

stronger, finance will surely become more integrated too.

Other tools are available. Tighter fiscal policy in emerging economies, for

instance, could lessen the chance of overheating. Stricter domestic financial

regulation would reduce the chances of a credit binge. Countries from Singapore

to Israel have been adding, or tightening, prudential rules such as maximum

loan-to-value ratios on mortgages.

But greater currency flexibility will also be needed. The trilemma of

international economics dictates it: if capital is mobile, currency rigidity

will eventually lead to asset bubbles and inflation. Unless countries are

willing to live with such booms and the busts that follow Bretton Woods 2 will

have to evolve into a system that mirrors the rich world s, with integrated

capital markets and floating currencies.

Although the direction is clear, the pace is not. The pressure of capital flows

will depend on the prospects for rich economies, particularly America s, as

well as the actions of the Fed. Emerging economies willingness to allow their

currencies to move will depend on what China does and China, because its

capital controls are more extensive and effective than others , can last with a

currency peg for longest.

If America s economy recovers and its medium-term fiscal outlook improves, the

pace at which capital shifts to the emerging world will slow. If China makes

its currency more flexible and its capital account more open in good time, the

international monetary system will be better able to cope with continued

financial globalisation and a wide growth gap between rich and emerging

markets. But if the world s biggest economy stagnates and the second-biggest

keeps its currency cheap and its capital account closed, a rigid monetary

system will eventually buckle.