💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4414.gmi captured on 2022-06-04 at 01:02:34. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2023-01-29)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Evidence is mounting that moderate minimum wages can do more good than harm

Free exchange - The argument in the floor

Nov 24th 2012 | from the print edition

MINIMUM-WAGE laws have a long history and enduring political appeal. New

Zealand pioneered the first national pay floor in 1894. America s federal

minimum wage dates from 1938. Most countries now have a statutory pay floor and

the ranks are still swelling. Even Germany, one of the few big countries

without, may at last introduce a national one. And in an era of budget

austerity and widening inequality, the political temptation to prop up wages at

the bottom by fiat may well grow.

Economists have tended to oppose minimum wages on the grounds that they reduce

employment, hurting many of those they are supposed to help. Milton Friedman

called them a form of discrimination against low-skilled workers. In standard

models of competitive markets, anything that artificially raises the price of

labour will curb demand for it, and the first to lose their jobs will be the

least-skilled workers.

Yet economic theory allows for the possibility that wage floors can boost both

employment and pay. If employers have monopsony power as buyers of labour and

are able to set wages, for instance, they can keep pay below its competitive

rate. Academic supporters of wage floors, mainly economists on the left,

appealed to this logic. But most of their colleagues disagreed; and until about

1990, most empirical studies found that higher minimum wages cost jobs,

particularly among young workers.

Then a pioneering case study by two noted labour economists, David Card and

Alan Krueger, examined the response of fast-food restaurants to a rise in New

Jersey s state minimum wage. It found that this had actually increased

employment. The paper spawned a flood of similar case-study research, a

flurry of revisionist thinking and a heated academic debate. The most prominent

critics of the new research were David Neumark of the University of California

at Irvine and William Wascher of the Federal Reserve. They disputed Messrs Card

and Krueger s findings for New Jersey and argued that a comparison of different

states over time showed that higher minimum wages hurt jobs.

Almost two decades later, the minimum-wage debate has matured, not least

because policy changes have brought heaps of new evidence to analyse. Britain

introduced a national minimum wage in 1999. America s states saw numerous

adjustments in their minimum wages, and the federal floor was raised by 40%

between 2007 and 2009.

America s academics still do not agree on the employment effects. But both

sides have honed their methods and, in some ways, the gap between them has

shrunk. Messrs Card and Krueger moved on to other work, but Arindrajit Dube at

the University of Massachusetts-Amherst and Michael Reich of the University of

California at Berkeley have generalised the case-study approach, comparing

restaurant employment across all contiguous counties with different

minimum-wage levels between 1990 and 2006. They found no adverse effects on

employment from a higher minimum wage. They also argue that if research showed

such effects, these mostly reflected other differences between American states

and had nothing to do with the minimum wage.

Messrs Neumark and Wascher still demur. They have published stacks of studies

(and a book) purporting to show that minimum wages hit jobs. In a forthcoming

paper they defend their methods and argue that the evidence still favours their

view. But even they are no longer blanket opponents. In a 2011 paper they

pointed out that a higher minimum wage along with the Earned Income Tax Credit

(which tops up income for poor workers in America) boosted both employment and

earnings for single women with children (though it cost less-skilled, minority

men jobs).

Britain s experience offers another set of insights. The country s national

minimum wage was introduced at 46% of the median wage, slightly higher than

America s. A lower floor applied to young people. Both are adjusted annually on

the advice of the Low Pay Commission. Before the law took effect, worries about

potential damage to employment were widespread. Yet today the consensus is that

Britain s minimum wage has done little or no harm.

The most striking impact of Britain s minimum wage has been on the spread of

wages. Not only has it pushed up pay for the bottom 5% of workers, but it also

seems to have boosted earnings further up the income scale and thus reduced

wage inequality. Wage gaps in the bottom half of Britain s pay scale have

shrunk sharply since the late 1990s. A new study by a trio of British

labour-market economists (including one at the Low Pay Commission) attributes

much of that contraction to the minimum wage. Wage inequality fell more for

women (a higher proportion of whom are on the minimum wage) than for men and

the effect was most pronounced in low-wage parts of Britain.

The British way versus the American way

This new evidence leaves economists with lots of unanswered questions. What

exactly is going on in labour markets if minimum wages do not hurt employment

but reduce wage gaps? Are firms cutting costs by squeezing wages elsewhere? Are

they improving the productivity of the lowest-wage workers? Some of the newest

studies suggest firms employ a variety of strategies to deal with a higher

minimum wage, from modestly raising prices to saving money from lower turnover.

Policymakers face practical issues. Bastions of orthodoxy, such as the OECD, a

rich-country think-tank, and the International Monetary Fund, now assert that a

moderate minimum wage probably does not do much harm and may do some good.

Their definition of moderate is 30-40% of the median wage. Britain s experience

suggests it might even be a bit higher. The success of the Low Pay Commission

points to the importance of technocrats rather than politicians setting wage

floors. Britain s small, regular changes may be easier for firms to absorb than

America s infrequent but hefty minimum-wage increases. Whatever their flaws,

minimum wages are here to stay.

Sources

"Minimum wage channels of adjustment", by Barry T. Hirsch, Bruce E. Kaufman and

Tetyana Zelenska, IZA Discussion Paper No 6132, November 2011

"Minimum wages and wage inequality: Some theory and an application to the UK",

by Tim Butcher, Richard Dickens and Alan Manning, October 2012

"Why has the British national minimum wage had little or no impact on

employment?", by David Metcalf, CEP Discussion Paper No 781, April 2007

"Minimum wage effects across state borders: estimates using contiguous

counties", by Arindrajit Dube, T. William Lester and Michael Reich, The Review

of Economics and Statistics, November 2010

"Minimum wage: Maximum impact", by Alan Manning, Resolution Foundation, April

2012

"Revising the minimum wage-employment debate: Throwing out the baby with the

bathwater?", by David Neumark, J.M. Ian Salas and William Wascher, forthcoming

"Do minimum wages really reduce teen employment? Accounting for heterogeneity

and selectivity in state panel data", by Sylvia A. Allegretto, Arindrajit Dube

and Michael Reich, Industrial Relations, April 2011

http://www.Economist.com/blogs/freeexchange

from the print edition | Finance and economics