💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 6474.gmi captured on 2021-12-05 at 23:47:19. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)

➡️ Next capture (2023-01-29)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Richard Thaler wins the Nobel prize for economic sciences

An economist who recognises that human behaviour is not always strictly

rational

THE credit-card bill arrives. You have enough money in a savings account to pay

it off the sensible thing to do, arithmetically speaking, since the interest

rate on the credit-card balance far exceeds that earned on the savings. Yet you

leave the savings untouched, and pay only as much of the bill as your

current-account balance allows. What looks a daft choice to most economists

made perfect sense to Richard Thaler, who on October 9th was awarded the Nobel

prize for economics for his work in behavioural economics. Mr Thaler helped

demonstrate how human reasoning diverges from that of the perfectly rational

homo economicus used in most economic modelling. The world, and the field of

economics, is better for his contributions.

Economists mostly recognise that normal people their friends and family fall

short of omniscience and perfect rationality in making day-to-day decisions.

Economic modelling requires simplification, however, and economists generally

suppose that theories assuming people are well-informed and rational offer the

best available description of economic activity. Over time, however, scholars

have built up an imposing list of the ways in which humans systematically

refuse to behave as the models predict. Economists such as Herb Simon (who won

the Nobel in 1978), Daniel Kahneman (2002) and Robert Shiller (2013) are

celebrated for their contributions to this effort. But perhaps more than any

other scholar, Mr Thaler lifted behavioural economics to prominence, and helped

put its lessons into practice.

Mr Thaler, an American born in New Jersey in 1945, spent most of his early

career at Cornell University before moving to the University of Chicago in

1995. Unusually for an economist, he is known for the clarity of his ideas and

the quality of his writing. His academic and popular articles alike are

accessible and entertaining. Nudge , a book co-written with Cass Sunstein, is

both an extraordinarily influential work and a best-seller. Its lessons have

been adopted by governments across the world; nudge units in America and

Britain studied how to boost saving and taxpaying, encourage healthy behaviour

and reduce energy usage.

Nudge drew on years of work by Mr Thaler and co-authors identifying oddities

in human behaviour. Setting out to explore why people feel losses more keenly

than gains, he helped uncover the endowment effect: a tendency to value

something more highly just because one owns it. To detect it, he distributed

coffee mugs at random to half of a group of test subjects, who were then

invited to sell the mugs, if they wished, to the other, mugless half. Theory

would predict that those with and without mugs should value them the same, on

average, and so about half of the mugs should change hands. In fact, those with

mugs valued them more than those without. Offers to buy the mugs by the

have-nots were usually too low to convince the haves to sell, and relatively

few transactions took place. This finding, since replicated many times,

suggested that the context of an economic choice matters. That, in turn, means

that the way choices are framed, by firms or governments, can influence how

people respond.

The importance of context also arose in Mr Thaler s work on mental accounting

. In thinking about money, people tend to compartmentalise, grouping certain

types of spending or income together. In some cases this might amount to a

strategy for managing imperfect self-control (as in the credit-card debt

example). More broadly, it reflects the human tendency to tackle cognitive

problems in pieces, rather than as a whole. When petrol prices fall, for

example, drivers sometimes switch from regular grade petrol to premium (rather

than use savings out of the petrol category somewhere else). Because of this

mental pigeonholing, taxi drivers who aim to earn a certain amount each day may

stop work early on busy days and later on slow ones, though the opposite

approach would maximise earnings per hour.

Mr Thaler, with his colleague Hersh Shefrin, understood choices as battles

between two competing cognitive forces: a doer part of the brain focused on

short-term rewards, and a planner focused on the long-term. Willpower can

help suppress the doer s urges but exercising restraint is costly. This

internal struggle is continuous, so individual preferences are not constant

over time (whether one has another beer may depend on the state of the brain at

a given moment). It also means that presenting people with a choice

architecture which favours the planner over the doer can have big effects on

behaviour. That insight became the basis for nudging . Making enrolment in

pension plans the default for new employees (ie, they must decide to opt out

rather than opt in) dramatically increases the share of employees saving

through such programmes, for example.

Mr Thaler, with Mr Kahneman and Jack Knetsch, also worked to understand the

role of fairness in judging economic outcomes. They conducted experiments in

which a student chosen at random was asked to divide $20 between himself and

another subject. Only rarely would the student keep most of the money, as pure

rationality suggests he should. Similarly, the authors used surveys to show

that people find practices like price gouging in the wake of disasters unfair.

In some multi-round experiments players chose to punish participants who acted

selfishly in early rounds, even if that meant accepting a lower payout

themselves.

Best laid plans

These insights that people care about fairness, find self-control hard and hate

losing what they already have might seem trivial outside of the strange world

of economics. In fact, behavioural economics greatest contribution may have

been to nudge the field away from attempts to extrapolate grand economic

theories from basic rules of individual behaviour. Today ambitious economists

are quite likely to immerse themselves in empirical work focused on specific

policy questions. That is a legacy worth treasuring, however one does the

mental accounting.