💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 4779.gmi captured on 2021-12-05 at 23:47:19. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content
⬅️ Previous capture (2021-12-03)
-=-=-=-=-=-=-
Governments should make more use of property taxes
Jun 29th 2013 |From the print edition
TAXES on property go back a long way. Ancient civilisations from Greece to
China had levies on land. In 11th-century England the Domesday Book, a record
of who owned what land, documented William the Conqueror s tax base. Britain
had a window tax in the late 17th century, well before it introduced an income
tax. In America local governments have raised money from property taxes since
the colonial era; the federal income tax has been in place only since 1913.
But property taxes are much less prominent than they once were. To fund rising
government spending, far more cash is raised from other sources, particularly
income taxes, payroll taxes and value-added taxes (see left-hand chart). A new
study by John Norregaard of the International Monetary Fund suggests that the
average rich country, including all levels of government, raises under 5% of
total tax revenue from annual levies on land or the buildings on it. The norm
in middle-income emerging economies is lower still, at around 2% of all tax
revenue (see right-hand chart). Including property-transaction taxes like stamp
duty raises the total a bit but not by much.
These averages mask big differences. Property taxes loom largest in Anglo-Saxon
economies. In America they still account for 17% of all government revenue; in
Britain and Canada the figure is around 12%. Only 2% of revenues come from
annual property taxes in Germany and Italy; in Switzerland it is a mere 0.4%. A
small share of national tax revenue can belie the importance of property taxes
for the local governments that tend to levy them. In Australia and Britain
taxes based on property are the only source of local-government tax revenue.
America s local authorities get around 70% of their revenue from property
taxes. But, overall, property taxation plays a relatively small role.
That s a pity. Taxing land and property is one of the most efficient and least
distorting ways for governments to raise money. A pure land tax, one without
regard to how land is used or what is built on it, is the best sort. Since the
amount of land is fixed, taxing it cannot distort supply in the way that taxing
work or saving might discourage effort or thrift. Instead a land tax encourages
efficient land use. Property developers, for instance, would be less inclined
to hoard undeveloped land if they had to pay an annual levy on it. Property
taxes that include the value of buildings on land are less efficient, since
they are, in effect, a tax on the investment in that property. Even so, they
are less likely to affect people s behaviour than income or employment taxes. A
study by the OECD suggests that taxes on immovable property are the most
growth-friendly of all major taxes. That is even truer of urbanising emerging
economies with large informal sectors.
Property taxes are a stable source of revenue in a globalised world where firms
and skilled people can easily move. They are also less prone to cyclical
swings. In the financial bust America s state and local governments saw smaller
declines in property taxes than other forms of revenue, largely because the
valuations on which tax assessments are based were adjusted more slowly and
less dramatically than actual prices. Property taxes may even restrain housing
booms by making it more expensive to buy homes for purely speculative purposes.
Given these advantages, why don t governments raise more money from property? A
few are trying to. Mr Norregaard cites almost 20 countries that have recently
introduced new property taxes, or are considering doing so. Namibia recently
introduced a land tax on agricultural land; Ireland is reintroducing a tax on
residential property that was abolished in 1997. Britain s opposition Labour
Party has suggested taxing developers who sit on land and don t build on it.
But given the scale of the fiscal crunch, surprisingly few governments have
gone down this route.
Like it or lump it
One explanation is that many governments lack the information to exploit these
sorts of taxes. Lots of emerging economies (and some supposedly emerged ones
such as Greece) do not have the modern equivalent of the Domesday Book, a clear
cadastre of who owns what. But the big reason is that these taxes are wildly
unpopular, often spawning opposition quite out of proportion to their scale.
Mario Monti, Italy s former technocrat prime minister, lost the election
earlier this year for many reasons but his much-loathed decision to raise a tax
on property played a substantial part. Asked in surveys what is the worst or
least fair tax, Americans consistently cite property taxes.
Economists are more divided about the fairness of property taxes than they
are about their efficiency. For a long time the prevailing consensus was that
property taxes were regressive because the burden would be passed on to tenants
and workers. Today another school of thought is more popular. It argues that in
an efficient capital market the burden of property taxes is borne by owners of
capital across the economy; and since capital owners tend to be richer, the tax
is likely to be progressive.
Nuanced judgments about progressivity are not what drive political opposition
to these taxes. Voters hate property taxes because they are what economists
call salient : the burden is obvious, easy to calculate and hard to avoid. An
intriguing new paper by Marika Cabral and Caroline Hoxby at Stanford University
shows what a difference this makes. Most American homeowners pay their property
taxes in one or two lump sums during the year. Around a third (mainly those
with mortgages) have their tax payments bundled in with monthly mortgage
payments. The economists find that how people pay their property taxes affects
their tolerance for them. The more people pay in lump sums, the lower property
taxes are likely to be. For property taxes to become a much bigger source of
revenue, governments must apparently ensure people don t realise how much they
are paying.
Sources
Taxing Immovable Property. Revenue Potential and Implementation Challenges ,
by John Norregaard. IMF Working Paper WP/13/129. May 2013
The Hated Property Tax: Salience, Tax Rates, and Tax Revolts , by Marika
Cabral and Caroline Hoxby. November 2012
Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth . OECD. November 2010.