💾 Archived View for gmi.noulin.net › mobileNews › 538.gmi captured on 2021-12-05 at 23:47:19. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

➡️ Next capture (2023-01-29)

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

Parable of the broken window

The parable describes a shopkeeper whose window is broken by a little boy.

Everyone sympathizes with the man whose window was broken, but pretty soon they

start to suggest that the broken window makes work for the glazier, who will

then buy bread, benefiting the baker, who will then buy shoes, benefiting the

cobbler, etc. Finally, the onlookers conclude that the little boy was not

guilty of vandalism; instead he was a public benefactor, creating economic

benefits for everyone in town.

Bastiat's original parable of the broken window went like this:

Have you ever witnessed the anger of the good shopkeeper, James Goodfellow,

when his careless son happened to break a square of glass? If you have been

present at such a scene, you will most assuredly bear witness to the fact, that

every one of the spectators, were there even thirty of them, by common consent

apparently, offered the unfortunate owner this invariable consolation "It is an

ill wind that blows nobody good. Everybody must live, and what would become of

the glaziers if panes of glass were never broken?"

Now, this form of condolence contains an entire theory, which it will be well

to show up in this simple case, seeing that it is precisely the same as that

which, unhappily, regulates the greater part of our economical institutions.

Suppose it cost six francs to repair the damage, and you say that the accident

brings six francs to the glazier's trade that it encourages that trade to the

amount of six francs I grant it; I have not a word to say against it; you

reason justly. The glazier comes, performs his task, receives his six francs,

rubs his hands, and, in his heart, blesses the careless child. All this is that

which is seen.

But if, on the other hand, you come to the conclusion, as is too often the

case, that it is a good thing to break windows, that it causes money to

circulate, and that the encouragement of industry in general will be the result

of it, you will oblige me to call out, "Stop there! Your theory is confined to

that which is seen; it takes no account of that which is not seen."

It is not seen that as our shopkeeper has spent six francs upon one thing, he

cannot spend them upon another. It is not seen that if he had not had a window

to replace, he would, perhaps, have replaced his old shoes, or added another

book to his library. In short, he would have employed his six francs in some

way, which this accident has prevented.

[edit] Fallacy of the argument

The fallacy of the onlookers' argument is that they considered only the

positive benefits of purchasing a new window, but they ignored the cost to the

shopkeeper. As the shopkeeper was forced to spend his money on a new window, he

obviously could not have spent it on something else. For example, the

shopkeeper may have spent the money on bread and shoes for himself, but now

cannot so enrich the baker and cobbler because he must fix his window.

Thus, the child did not bring any net benefit to the town. Instead, he made the

town poorer by at least the value of one window, if not more.

[edit] Differing interpretations

Keynesians argue that in some circumstances the little boy may actually be a

benefactor, though not the best possible one. Facing severely underutilized

resources (as in the Great Depression), John Maynard Keynes argued that it may

make economic sense to build totally useless pyramids in order to stimulate the

economy, raise aggregate demand, and encourage full employment.

Austrian economists, and Bastiat himself, apply the parable of the broken

window in a more subtle way. If we consider the parable again, we notice that

the little boy is seen as a public benefactor. Suppose it was discovered that

the little boy was actually hired by the glazier, and paid a franc for every

window he broke. Suddenly the same act would be regarded as theft: the glazier

was breaking windows in order to force people to hire his services. Yet the

facts observed by the onlookers remain true: the glazier benefits from the

business at the expense of the baker, the cobbler, and so on. Bastiat

demonstrates that people actually do endorse activities which are morally

equivalent to the glazier hiring a boy to break windows for him.

A common interpretation of the gross domestic product is that increased GDP

means the economy is healthier. Some would say that this interprets the

proverbial "broken window" as a positive, and that some form of Genuine

Progress Indicator would be a more realistic indicator of economic health.

Another interpretation is that (in a more modern society) the money wouldn't go

to the carpenter or the cobbler, if the shopkeeper was doing well enough for

that money to go into a vault that wouldn't be used for a long time.

Both of those interpretations can be seen as flawed: in a modern economy, the

window owner's money (if the window was still intact) would either be spent on

consumption, or saved for future consumption as an investment in the economy

(in today's world, perhaps via a bank or brokerage account). Both of these

options serve to increase GDP at a higher level of economic efficiency and

utility than if the window is broken.

[edit] Application

Economists of the Austrian School and libertarians argue that the "broken

window fallacy" is extremely common in popular thinking. Examples include:

[edit] War

This article does not cite any references or sources. (March 2008)

Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources.

Unverifiable material may be challenged and removed.

Some claim that war is a benefactor, since historically it often has focused

the use of resources and triggered advances in technology and other areas. The

increased production and employment associated with war often leads some to

claim that "war is good for the economy." Others claim that this is an example

of the broken window fallacy. The money spent on the war effort, for example,

is money that can't be spent on food, clothing, health care, consumer

electronics or other areas. The stimulus felt in one sector of the economy

comes at a direct but hidden cost to other sectors.

More importantly, war destroys property and lives. The economic stimulus to the

defense sector is offset not only by immediate opportunity costs, but also by

the costs of the damage and devastation of war. This forms the basis of a

second application of the broken window fallacy: rebuilding what war destroys

stimulates the economy, particularly the construction sector. However, immense

resources are spent merely to restore pre-war conditions. After a war, there is

only a rebuilt city. Without a war, there are opportunities for the same

resources to be applied to more fruitful purposes. Instead of rebuilding a

destroyed city, the resources could be used to build a second city or add

improvements.

Another set of costs of war are the many projects postponed or not started

until after the end of the Second World War in America. The pent-up demand for

roads, bridges, houses, cars, and even radios led to massive inflation in the

late 1940s. The war delayed the commercial introduction of television, among

other things, and the resources sent overseas to rebuild the rest of the world

after the war were not available to directly benefit the American people.

Destroying property is wasteful unless there is a compelling reason to replace

what exists. Destroying lives is never beneficial. War stimulates some portions

of the economy, but drains others, leading to stalled or wasteful work. On

balance, war is not a good economic stimulator.

[edit] Special interests and government

Bastiat, Hazlitt, and others equated the glazier with special interests, and

the little boy with government. Special interests request money from the

government (in the form of subsidies, grants, etc.), and the government then

forces the taxpayer to provide the funds. The recipients certainly do benefit,

so the government action is often regarded by the people as benefitting

everyone. But the people are failing to consider the hidden costs: the

taxpayers are now poorer by exactly that much money. The food, clothing or

other items they might have purchased with that money will now not be purchased

but since there is no way to count "non-purchases," this is a hidden cost,

sometimes called opportunity cost. Bastiat referred to this in his essay as

"what is not seen". Because the costs are hidden, there is an illusion that the

benefits cost nothing. Hazlitt summarized the principle by saying, "Everything

we get, outside the free gifts of nature, must in some way be paid for." Robert

A. Heinlein popularized a summarization/acronym of the concept called

"TANSTAAFL" (There Ain't No Such Thing As A Free Lunch).

Common examples of special interest groups practicing the broken window fallacy

might be:

o Arguments against reduction of ineffective tax-paid positions, such as in

government administration;

o Arguments for protectionist measures such as tariffs, subsidies and/or other

regulations at the tax payers' and/or other businesses' expense;

o Arguments for overriding public opposition to industry practices and

enterprises, such as environmental pollution and casinos;

to the theater or to a concert they also go to restaurants etc. and stimulate

the economy.

[edit] Terrorism

Economist Walter E. Williams, and commentators Jonah Goldberg[1] and Robert

Tracinski,[2] accused economist Paul Krugman of committing the broken-window

fallacy soon after the September 11, 2001 attacks. Krugman wrote:

"Ghastly as it may seem to say this, the terror attack like the original "day

of infamy" which brought an end to the Great Depression could even do some

economic good. [...] the driving force behind the economic slowdown has been a

plunge in business investment. Now, all of a sudden, we need some new office

buildings. As I've already indicated, the destruction isn't big compared with

the economy, but rebuilding will generate at least some increase in business

spending."[3]

While Krugman made no direct claim that the terrorist attacks would lead to

overall economic gain, Williams inferred that Krugman was talking about a net

economic good for the United States, and in response wrote:

"Would there have been even greater 'economic good' had the terrorists

succeeded in destroying buildings in Los Angeles, San Francisco, Chicago,

Philadelphia, Boston and all other major cities? Of course, you and I know that

is utter nonsense. Property destruction always lowers the wealth of a nation."

[4]