💾 Archived View for tanelorn.city › ~vidak › old-blog › value-price-and-profit-summarised.gemini captured on 2020-09-24 at 01:41:41. Gemini links have been rewritten to link to archived content

View Raw

More Information

-=-=-=-=-=-=-

---

generator: pandoc

title: 'Marx''s Value Price and Profit Summarised'

viewport: 'width=device-width, initial-scale=1.0, user-scalable=yes'

---

2018-04-08T14:47:34+10:00

In an attempt to raise the level of consciousness of my comrades here in

Sydney, I decided to simplify Value, Price, and Profit from 60 pages

down to about 12 pages. If you would like the text of this article, feel

free to email me.

![Gold Bullion](/value-price-profit/00_bullions.png)

VI. VALUE AND LABOUR

====================

A. THE LABOUR THEORY OF VALUE

-----------------------------

We need to begin our investigation by asking "what is economic value?"

Bourgeois economists don't have a good answer to this question, but

Marxists do.

Everyday we become involved in acts of economic exchange. Transactions

that you make at the cash register are acts of exchange. We exchange the

commodity of money for other commodities, like clothes, TVs, milk, fruit

and vegetables, etc.

Marx points out that a single commodity is exchangeable for countless

other quantities of other commodities. The ratios of commodities

required for a successful exchange change depending on the commodity,

but the value of the commodities always remains the same.

The value of the commodities is the mysterious third thing that makes

the exchange of commodities possible. This third thing common to all

commodities in exchange, value, is able to be separated out of the

equation and analysed separately on its own. We are able to express this

identical measure of commodities independently of their physical

existence.

The value of commodities when they are exchanged is a social function of

commodities. It has nothing to do with a commodity's physical existence.

Value is the "social substance" of a commodity, and this "social

substance" is Labour. Marx says: "To produce a commodity a certain

amount of labour must be bestowed upon it, or worked up in it" (Marx:

1960, 71).

This labour is not the individual labour of a single person, but Social

Labour. Marx says:

A \[person\] who produces an article for their own immediate use, to
consume it themselves, creates a product, but not a commodity. As a
self-sustaining producer they have nothing to do with society. But to
produce a commodity, a person must not only produce an article
satisfying some social want, but their labour itself must form part
and parcel of the total sum of labour expended in society (Marx: 1960,
ibid).

Crucially, this labour must be integrated into the Division of Labour in

society. In order for a commodity to be a commodity, and for it to have

value so it can be exchanged, the labour expended on it must be

performed as part of the social process of capitalism.

![Worker 00](/value-price-profit/02_worker.jpg)

The value in commodities is therefore crystalised labour. It is fixed

inside the commodity. The only way the value of a commodity can change

is if more labour is worked upon it. The more labour a commodity has

bestowed upon it, the more value it will have.

How do you measure the quantity of labour in a commodity, in order to

work out its value? Marx answers this question. The time that the labour

lasts. The amount of labour in hours, minutes, seconds. Perhaps even

months, or years.

It might be pointed out that this theory might not get us any closer to

understanding value. Don't people work at different paces, and at

different levels of skill? The lazier worker would bestow much more

labour on a commodity, and would therefore make it worth more than

someone who worked harder. In the same way wouldn't someone clumsy make

a commodity worth the same, or even more than someone with great skill?

Marx has an answer for this:

This, however, would be a sad mistake. You will recollect that I used
the world 'Social labour', and many points are involved in this
qualification of 'Social'. In saying that the value of a commodity is
determined by the quantity of labour worked up or crystallised in it,
we mean the quantity of labour necessary for its production in a given
state in society, under certain social average conditions of
production, with a given social average intensity, and average skill
of the labour employed (Marx, 1960: 74).

Marx gives an example on this point. The introduction of the power loom

into England in the industrial revolution appeared to make workers work

even more. They went from working nine or ten hours daily to working

seventeen to eighteen hours a day. But the value of the cloth that

weaver dropped by half. This was because it now took only half the time

using the new machines to weave the same amount of cloth out of yarn.

The product of twenty hours labour now had the same value of what used

to take ten hours.

The name for this concept is called Socially Necessary Labour Time. It

is easy to work out the average value of labour time in this way. The

average of the overall skill, intensity, and productivity of labour, the

"aggregate" ratios of all these factors, can be taken from statistics

about global or national economic output.

If the amount of time it took to make the same amount of commodities

stayed the same, the value of those commodities would stay the same. But

the productive powers of society are constantly changing. Labour

productivity goes up and down all the time. In the short term, labour

might be less productive, and create less product per hour, minute,

second. But in the long term, since the industrial revolution, labour

has become continuously more productive. It is simple to find graphs on

the increasing productivity of labour. It is a law of capitalism that

the greater the productive powers of labour, the less value will be

bestowed upon the commodities created. The less productive labour is,

the more values individual commodities will have. This is because there

will be less labour bestowed upon more productively made commodities,

and vice versa.

The productivity of labour also depends on other factors. Apart from the

skill and intensity of labour, the productive powers of labour depend

on:

First. The natural conditions of labour, such as fertility of soil,
mines, and so forth.
Second. Upon the progressive improvement of the Social Powers of
Labour, such as are derived from production on a grand scale,
concentration of capital and combination of labour, subdivision of
labour, machinery, improved methods, appliance of chemical and other
natural agencies, shorting of time and space by means of communication
and transport, and every other contrivance by which science presses
natural agencies into the service of labour, any by which the social
or cooperative character of labour is developed (Marx, 1960: 75).

B. VALUE AND PRICE

------------------

None of the above theory applies to the price of a commodity. It only

applies to a commodity's value.

Price is a particular form that value assumes in the capitalist system.

Price is the monetary expression of value. Price is the form of value in

money form. This can be put another way. Price is the value of money.

![Gold Coins](/value-price-profit/01_gold_coins.jpg)

The price of money used to be the value of gold. This was called the

"gold standard". Working out the value of money in this way was easy.

The pound or the dollar would be set to a specific weight of gold. The

amount of socially necessary labour time that it took to produce that

specific quantity of gold was the value of the British pound or the

American dollar.

The international gold standard for the US dollar was abolished by

Richard Nixon in 1971. All major currencies are now "free floating".

This means that the price of money is now self-referential. The value of

money now changes every millisecond. The value of money is now

determined by speculation, by the rapid exchange of money for other

commodities on the global market.

This doesn't contradict the Marxist labour theory of value in any way at

all. Money is a commodity like any other. Because money is a commodity,

it is exchangeable in definite ratios with other commodities. The only

difference is that now, money is now a "claim" on value, instead of

actually having intrinsic value.

Money is the universal equivalent commodity. It is the commodity that

every other commodity uses to express its value in order to be

exchangeable on the market. Money is the appearance of value, where

socially necessary labour time is the essence of value.

Under normal, stable conditions, the price of a commodity will coincide

with its value. This means that the price of a commodity will exactly

express the amount of socially necessary labour time crystallised in it.

This means that identical commodities produced under different concrete

regional conditions will have the same price.

The market is a dynamic system, and the price of money and of

commodities is constantly changing. Market prices may coincide with the

values of commodities, but that is not always the case. Contrary to the

slander levelled against the Marxist labour theory of value, Marx holds

a place for the market forces of supply and demand in his economics.

Marx follows Adam Smith in holding that two different concepts explain

the reason why prices have the quantities they do. The first concept is

market price. The market price of a commodity is determined by the laws

of supply and demand. The second concept is the natural price. The

natural price of the commodity is the price a commodity should have, and

to which all market forces are tending the price to become under

equilibrium. Under normal, stable conditions, conditions of equilibrium,

a commodity will have its natural price. A commodity's natural price

expresses its value exactly.

All of what has been said above assumes that the capitalist system being

discussed is a perfectly free market. Contrary to what the enemies of

Marxist economics say, Marx assumes in his model of capitalism that it

is a perfectly free market. The existence of monopolies under capitalism

will distort market forces, and will cause commodities to avoid having

their natural price. But that is not our concern here.

The power of Marxist economics, with its labour theory of value, is that

it is able to explain the existence of profit in capitalism. Bourgeois

economics assumes that in a free market, under equilibrium conditions,

all firms will sell commodities at cost, and make no profit. This model

of the global capitalist system has no bearing on reality. Firms are

reaping in billions of dollars of profit globally every year. The

Marxist labour theory of value is able to show how commodities, sold at

their value, are able to realise profit. This is an immense improvement

on bourgeois economics.

VII. LABOURING POWER

====================

Marxist economics distinguishes between the Value of Labour, and the

Value of Labouring Power. The secret of how bosses makes profit lies in

this distinction.

Without the distinction between Labour and Labour Power, we would be

left with a paradox about how to determine the value of labour. The only

way we would be able to determine the value of labour would be by

referring to the duration of its expenditure. What is the value of ten

hours' labour? Ten hours. For this reason it is a great discovery by

Marx that what a worker sells to the boss when they go to work is not

directly their labour, but their labour power.

What we want to know when unravelling the secret of profit under

capitalism, therefore, is the value of labour power. Labour power is a

commodity like any other. It can be bought and sold on the market.

Workers are distinguished from the bourgeoisie because the only

commodity that workers have to sell on the market is their own body,

their labouring power. The value of labour power, like any commodity, is

the amount of labour required to produce it and maintain it. We can

quote Marx on this point:

A certain mass of necessaries must be consumed by a person to grow up
and maintain their life. But the person, like the machine, will wear
out, and must be replaced by another person. Besides the mass of
necessaries required for their own maintenance, they want another
amount of necessaries to bring up a certain quota of children that are
to replace them on the labour market and to perpetuate the race of
labourers. Moreover, to develop their labouring power, and acquire a
given skill, another amount of values must be spent (Marx, 1960:
79-80).
So the value of labour power is the total value (remember: socially
necessary labour time) of the necessaries required to develop and
produce labour to a state ready for a worker to sell on the market.
All the training, the housing, the food, the clothing, the necessaries
for children and guardianship---the total value of all the labour
required to make a worker able to work.

![Worker 01](/value-price-profit/03_worker.jpg)

Marx points out this explains why workers are paid different amounts in

a free market. Different workers have had more or less intensive and

lengthy training, and live in areas with more or less expensive

necessaries.

VIII. PRODUCTION OF SURPLUS VALUE

=================================

The secret of profit under capitalism lies in the distinction between

labour and labour power. What the capitalist buys on the market in order

to produce commodities is labour power. The capitalist buys labour power

and pays the worker for it at the market rate. The exchange is formally

fair. The worker gets the full value of the only commodity they have to

sell.

What the capitalist buys is labour power, but what they get in the

workplace is labour. Labour power put to work is actual labour. What the

worker does in the workplace is produce commodities, values. It is not

long before the worker produces enough value to repay the capitalist for

the value of the means of production, the instruments of production, and

the cost of their labour power. Let us assume that the average working

day is twelve hours. The minimum wage specifies a working week of 38 to

40 hours (8 hours a day), but it is not uncommon for people to work

twelve hours a day now. Despite the working day of twelve hours, the

worker might produce enough value to replace the daily costs of

production in six hours. There lies the secret to profit under

capitalism. Marx writes that while a worker might cover the costs of

production after six hours of daily work,

... this does not disable the worker from working ten or twelve hours
or more hours a day. But by paying the daily or weekly value of the
worker's labouring power the capitalist has acquired the right of
using that labouring power during the whole day or week. The
capitalist will, therefore, make the worker work say, daily, twelve
hours. Over and above the six hours required to replace the value of
their labouring power, the worker will have to work six other hours,
which I shall call the hours of surplus labour, which surplus labour
will realise itself in a surplus value and a surplus produce (Marx,
1960: 81-82).

The capitalist advances the value of six hours labour, but receives back

the value of twelve. The capitalist pays for labour power, but gets

labour. Capitalism is therefore the systematic theft of bosses from

their employees. A portion of your working day is necessarily unpaid.

When you go to work to stack shelves, answer phones, heal people in

hospital, you are being systematically stolen from. The value that you

help produce in the workplace is being stolen from you and appropriated

by people who do not do the work.

![Crazy Clock](/value-price-profit/04_clock.jpg)

The rate of surplus value, the ratio between paid and unpaid work, is

directly related to the length of the working day. The boss wants to

increase the ratio of unpaid to paid labour. This means directly

extending the time of the working day that workers work unpaid.

Capitalism is all about a struggle over time. Bosses want to say in

control of your time, and stay in control of you. This means reducing

your hours when you're not profitable, and extending your hours when you

are. The boss only wants you when it is convenient to them. This is the

truth of the corporate jargon word of "flexibility"--the boss wants to

be completely flexible, and you to be pliant to their whims.

IX. VALUE OF LABOUR

===================

The system of receiving wages for work under capitalism obscures the

relationship of theft in the workplace. Wages are the value of a

worker's labour power expressed in money. The value produced by the

worker in the workplace are concealed by the price value of their labour

power. Because the worker receives their wages after they have performed

their work, and because they receive the value of their labour power in

money, it seems as if they have received the full value of their labour.

Marx points out that two consequences flows from the concealing effect

of wages:

First. The value or price of the labouring power takes the semblance
of the price or value of labour itself, although, strictly, value and
price of labour are senseless terms.
Secondly. Although one part only of the worker's daily labour is paid,
while the other part is unpaid, and while that unpaid or surplus
labour constitutes exactly the fund out of which surplus value or
profit is formed, it seems as if the aggregate labour was paid labour
(Marx, 1960: 83).

The fact that wages make systematic theft under capitalism a secret is

something new to human civilisation under this mode of production. Under

feudalism is was easy to see what was being produced for oneself, and

what was not. Under feudalism, the peasantry was not separated from the

means of production, and the value of one's labour was not obscured.

Peasants had to give a proportion of their produce as tithe to their

lord. Peasants also sold their surplus product personally. The rest of

their produce was kept for themselves and did not become a commodity.

This mode of production made the source of value in production easy to

recognise.

Wage labour is therefore called wage-slavery by communists. Wages are a

method of tricking the worker into thinking they have been paid the full

amount of their work. The reality is that all workers under capitalism

are being stolen from.

X. PROFIT IS MADE BY SELLING A COMMODITY AT ITS VALUE

=====================================================

The capitalist only cheats at the point of production. Because the

worker creates surplus product at the point of production, the

capitalist is furnished with an amount of commodities for which they did

not pay any equivalent. It is for this reason that the capitalist mode

of production is a system of theft.

The capitalist does not sell any of the commodities produced by the

worker above their value. The capitalist sells them at their market

value. In the realm of exchange, the realm of the market, equivalent is

always exchanged for equivalent. The capitalist will get the full value

of their commodities, and nothing more.

XI. THE DIFFERENT PARTS INTO WHICH SURPLUS VALUE IS DECOMPOSED

==============================================================

Surplus value realised in money form is called Profit.

The commodity-producing capitalist doesn't realise all the profit in the

global capitalist system. Monopoly on land allows the landlord to

realise part of the surplus value produced by the worker as Rent. The

banks and the investment firms who lend money to the commodity-producing

capitalist also realise a portion of the total surplus value as

Interest. The portion of the realised surplus value left over after all

the deductions for Rent, Interest etc., have been made is the profit of

the commodity-producing capitalist: Industrial or Commercial Profit.

Money lending and owning land do not produce surplus value. Money

lending and land-owning are parasitic on production, and they draw a

portion of the surplus value produced at the point of production away

from the commodity-producing capitalist.

The value transferred to a commodity through labour from the wear and

tear of machinery, and the consumption of raw materials, in other words

the value of the means of production used up in making a commodity, does

not produce surplus value, and does not contribute to realising profit.

The value transferred into a commodity by using up the means of

production only replaces capital, it doesn't generate an expansion of

capital.

Doing this subtraction, we perform another subtraction. After

subtracting the value of labour power, we have left surplus value,

which, when realised, becomes profit.

Profit is decomposed out of surplus value that issues out of the point

of production. Surplus value is not determined by adding up the various

component profits that moneylenders, landlords, and industrial

capitalists receive. It is only by determining the total surplus value

produced that one can then determine what profit each section of the

capitalist class receives.

From this calculation we can work out the rate of profit, and the rate

of exploitation. The rate of exploitation is the ratio of the value of

labour power to surplus value. The rate of profit is the rate of wages

to overall profit.

The rate of exploitation and rate of profit does not involve any value

of the capital that is replaced by using up the means of production, and

paying the value of labour power. Marx points out why this is so:

Suppose \$100 to be the capital advanced in wages. If the surplus
value created is also \$100---and this would show us that half the
working day of the labourer consists of unpaid labour---and if we
measured this profit by the value of the capital advanced in wages, we
should say that the rate of profit amounted to 100 per cent., because
the value advanced would be 100 and the value realised would be 200.
If, on the other hand, we should not only consider the capital
advanced in wages, but the total capital advanced, say, for example,
\$500, of which \$400 represented the value of raw materials,
machinery, and so forth, we should say that the rate of profit
amounted only to twenty per cent., because the profit of one hundred
would be but the fifth part of the total capital advanced.
The first mode of expressing the rate of profit is the only one which
shows you the real ratio between paid and unpaid labour, the real
degree of exploitation of labour. The other mode of expression is that
in common use, and is, indeed, appropriate for certain purposes. At
all events, it is very useful for concealing the degree in which the
capital extracts gratuitous labour from the worker (Marx, 1960: 87).

XII. GENERAL RELATION OF PROFITS, WAGES, AND PRICES

===================================================

The labour worked up into the raw materials used to make a commodity is

dead labour. So too is all the labour worked up into the instruments of

production used up to make that commodity. It is "dead labour" because

it doesn't create any new value when these two factors of production are

used up to make commodities.

Only the fresh labour worked up into a commodity can create new value.

This fresh labour is where the worker's wages and capitalist's profits

come from.

Because the value from fresh labour is shared between two classes

opposing of people, there is a struggle over how much the worker gets,

and how much the capitalist gets out of this share of fresh value.

Therefore, there is an inverse relationship between wages and profits.

If wages increase, profits will necessarily decrease. If the share to

the capitalist increases, wages will necessarily fall.

The values of commodities are therefore completely independent of the

share of the value of the sale of commodities that goes to either

workers or capitalists. There is no relationship between the value of a

commodity, and how much profit is made, or how high wages are.

The law that governs the values of commodities is solely the total

amount of labour worked up into those commodities. The total amount of

labour worked up into a commodity is directly related to the productive

powers of labour. Say the socially necessarily labour time of one hour

of labour was one dollar. Further assume that highly productive labour

produced one pound of yarn in one hour. Assume that labour of low

productivity could only produce a pound of yarn every six hours. In the

former case, one pound of yarn would cost \$1. In the latter case, it

would cost \$6. It is entirely possible that the former case could have

high wages and low profit, whereas the latter case could have low wages

and high profit. The share of the value of the sale of commodities is

independent of the actual value of commodities. It is the productivity

of labour that determines the price of commodities.

XIII. MAIN CASES OF ATTEMPTS AT RAISING WAGES OR RESISTING THEIR FALL

=====================================================================

A. DECREASED OR INCREASED PRODUCTIVITY OF LABOUR

------------------------------------------------

We have seen that the value of labour power is determined by the value

of the necessities required to reproduce the vital force of the worker.

Assume that six hour's labour amounts to the average value of the total

amount of necessaries that a worker needs to replace their vital force.

Further assume that the value of these necessaries is \$300.

If the whole working day was 12 hours, the capitalist would pay the

worker \$300. Half the working day would be unpaid labour, and the rate

of profit would be 100%.

Now assume that there is a total decrease in productivity in the world

economy, and there now needs to be more labour expended in order to

produce the total amount of necessaries required to keep a worker alive

and in good health. The average amount of daily necessaries now costs

\$400.

In this case, the value of the average worker's labour power would now

increase by 33.3%. Labour power would now be more expensive. Eight hours

of the working day would now be needed to sustain a worker's vital

forces.

There is only one outcome from this event in order to make sure the

worker's living conditions do not deteriorate. Wages would have to rise,

and the rate of profit would have to decrease. If the rate of profit

were to decrease, the amount of unpaid labour a worker did would have to

decrease, and in this case it would decrease from six hours to four

hours. Eight hours would now be spent working up the value the worker

needed to buy their necessities.

If wages do not rise, and the unpaid working hours decrease, the worker

will now be paid less than the value of their labour, and their living

conditions would deteriorate. They would starve, or become homeless.

A change in the productivity of labour power might happen in the

opposite direction. The necessaries required to keep a worker alive and

healthy might now cost only \$200, whereas before it was \$300.

The length of the working day the worker now works unpaid increases, and

the rate of profit would increase from 100% to 200%, because the worker

now only needs to work four out of twelve hours to work up the value of

their labour power.

The boss, the capitalist, now cuts the worker's wages, because they

don't need to pay the worker as much. The value of their labour has

dropped.

Although the worker's living conditions remain the same, there is now

much greater inequality in the global capitalist system, because the

capitalist has now increased their share of the value of the sale of

commodities.

B. DECREASE OR INCREASE IN THE ABSOLUTE LIMITS OF THE WORKING DAY

=================================================================

We have up until now assumed that the average length of the working day

is constant---twelve hours. But there is in fact no constant limit to

the working day. It is in the interest of capitalists to make the worker

work as long as they physically can, to increase the amount of unpaid

labour that the worker does. An increase in the amount of unpaid labour

means a direct increase in the rate of profit.

The capitalist assumes that the worker, the human, is like a machine. A

machine will transfer value faster into greater amounts of commodities

for sale the longer and harder it will work. But in the case of workers,

the health and the happiness of workers decreases with the increase of

the absolute length of the working day.

Please see Chapter Ten of Das Kapital for a study of the horrific

conditions that workers have had to endure for the sake of increasing

the rate of profit by lengthening the working day.

If something is not done to keep the working day within certain limits,

people will literally work themselves to a premature death to make sure

capitalists can get very, very rich.

XIV. THE STRUGGLE BETWEEN CAPITAL AND LABOUR, AND ITS RESULTS

=============================================================

Capitalists are constantly attempting to increase the limits of profit

accumulation during the working day. But there is an absolute physical

limit to how much profit can be made under capitalism. This is because

the organic supply of labour will literally be killed off if capital

accumulation is pushed beyond the physical limits of the working

capacity of humans.

There is, however, no real maximum limit to the value of an average

worker's wage. It is only bounded by the total value of the sale of

commodities.

There is, however, a minimum limit to the value of wages that a worker

can receive in order to keep living. This is the minimum average value

of the necessaries required to renew the vital forces of a worker.

![Workers On Strike](/value-price-profit/05_strike.jpg)

Generally speaking, there is therefore a law governing the limits of

capital accumulation under capitalism. Maximum profits will coincide

with the minimum physical amount of wages.

Between the minimum amount of wages, and the maximum amount of profit

possible under a capitalist society, there is therefore a lot of room to

move between these limits.

This explains the inherent antagonism between working class and

capitalist class people. Working class people insist on being paid more,

in order to not live like animals. Capitalists insist on workers being

paid less, in order to increase the rate of profit.

There is also another foundation to the antagonism between workers and

bosses. There is a progressive change in the composition of capital as

capitalism develops and history moves forward.

The part of capital that is composed of fixed capital, machinery, raw

materials, means of production in all possible forms, progressively

increases as compared with the other part of capital, which is laid out

in wages or in the purchase of labour.

It is possible that the proportion of fixed to variable capital was once

1:1. It is a law of capitalism, however, that if the capitalist mode of

production continues to develop successfully, that ratio will become

5:1, 10:1, and so on. The share of variable capital can only decrease

under capitalism. Marx writes:

If of a total capital of 600, 300 is laid out in instruments, raw
materials, and so forth, and 300 in wages, the total capital wants
only to be doubled to create a demand for 600 workers instead of for
300. But if of a capital of 600, 500 is laid out for machinery,
materials, and so forth, and 100 only in wages, the same capital must
increase from 600 to 3,600 in order to create a demand for 600 workmen
instead of 300. In the progress of industry the demand for labour
keeps, therefore, no pace with the accumulation of capital. It will
increase, but increase in a constantly diminishing ratio as compared
with the increase of capital (Marx, 1960:100).

It is therefore a law of capitalism that inequality must increase.

XV. REFERENCES

==============

Karl Marx, "Value Price and Profit" in *The Essential Left: Four Classic

Texts on the Principles of Socialism* (Allen & Unwin, 1960) 49-102.